Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T03:45:58.066Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Characterising Corruption by Adopting a Systemic Risk Perspective: Importing Macro Prudential Financial Regulation into the Policy Debate

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 March 2020

Andrea MINTO*
Affiliation:
Jean Monnet Professor in Law and Economics at Ca’ Foscari University of Venice; Visiting Professor at the University of Southern Denmark; email: [email protected]

Abstract

This article aims to theorise corruption from a “macro” perspective. It elaborates upon a range of social sciences literatures, notably from criminology and political sciences, that have discussed various “macro”-level factors contributing to corruption, including market characteristics. Its most distinct contribution to the literature is in importing the concept of “systemic risk” – thus far chiefly examined in the financial regulation literature – to the analysis of corruption. It draws on the financial literature on systemic risk and macro-prudential regulation and supervision. In so doing, it elaborates upon concepts such as “network” and “contagion” as to theorise the effects of corruption on resource allocation. This is supplemented by reference to the legal canon of literature on market regulation.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

The financial support provided by the SIEMENS Integrity Initiative is gratefully acknowledged.

References

1 For a detailed analysis of the economic theories of regulation see, for example, J den Hertog, “Review of Economic Theories of Regulation” (2010) Utrecht School of Economics Tjalling C. Koopman Research Institute Discussion Paper Series 10-18 <www.uu.nl/sites/default/files/rebo_use_dp_2010_10-18.pdf> (last accessed 20 January 2020). See also Acemoglu, D and Verdier, T, “The Choice Between Market Failures and Corruption” (2000) 90 Am Econ Rev 194CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Williamson, OE, “Review of Markets or Governments: Choosing Between Imperfect Alternatives” (1989) 27 J Econ Lit 92Google Scholar.

2 That markets are far away from producing either economically optimal or socially desirable outcomes has been elaborated in a well-known and voluminous literature. The main justification for public policy intervention lies hence in the inadequacies of markets as measured against the criteria of “efficiency” and “distributional equity”. See, eg, Bator, FM, “The Anatomy of Market Failure” (1958) 72 Q J Econ 351CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Aranson, PH, “Theories of Economic Regulation: From Clarity to Confusion” (1990) 6 J Law Politics 247Google Scholar; Baron, DP, “Regulation and Legislative Choice” (1988) 19 RAND J Econ 467CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Barzel, Y, “Measurement Cost and the Organisation of Markets” (1982) 25 J Law Econ 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Vickers, J, “Government Regulatory Policy” (1991) 7 Ox Rev Econ Policy 13CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Market outcomes can be termed efficient if the same level of total benefits which they generate cannot be obtained at a lower cost (productive efficiency) or, alternatively, if greater benefits cannot be generated at the same level of costs. Either way, the resulting total benefits must exceed total costs if the outcomes are to be deemed efficient. Distributional equity is a yardstick by which to examine the formulation, evaluation, and implementation of alternative public policies. The central question relates to the standard against which to evaluate distributional equity. In fact, answers can be different depending on how equity is interpreted (in the sense of equality of outcome or equality of opportunity, “horizontal” versus “vertical” equity, etc).

4 Particularly informative in that respect is the data collected by the World Bank. See, eg, World Bank, Governance and Development (World Bank 1992)Google Scholar; World Bank, Anticorruption in Transition: A Contribution to the Policy Debate (World Bank 2000)Google Scholar; World Bank, News and Broadcast: The Costs of Corruption (World Bank 2004)Google Scholar.

5 Becker, GS and Stigler, GJ, “Law Enforcement, Malfeasance, and Compensation of Enforcers” (1974) 3 J Leg Stud 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Among those who tried to point out the difficulties associated with gauging corruption, see, eg, Shleifer, A and Vishny, RW, “Politicians and Firms” (1994) 109 Q J Econ 995CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stiglitz, JE, Globalization and its Discontents (Penguin 2002)Google Scholar; Transparency International, About Corruption (2006); Tullock, G, “Controlling Corruption” (1989) 27 J Econ Lit 658Google Scholar.

7 Fitzsimons, VG, “Economic Models of Corruption” in Bracking, S (ed), Corruption and Development: The Anti-corruption Campaigns (Palgrave 2007) p 87Google Scholar.

8 Cressey, D, Other People’s Money: A Study in the Social Psychology of Embezzlement (Free Press 1953)Google Scholar; Mauro, P, “Corruption and Growth” (1995) 110 Q J Econ 681CrossRefGoogle Scholar; McChesney, FS, “Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of Regulation” (1987) 16 J Leg Stud 101CrossRefGoogle Scholar; North, DC, “Beyond the New Economic History” (1974) 34 J Econ Hist 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar; North, DC, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge University Press 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 For some introduction to the issue of defining corruption see, eg, Philp, M, “Defining Political Corruption” (1997) 45 Political Stud 436CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gardiner, J, “Defining Corruption” in Punch, M et al (eds), Coping with Corruption in a Borderless World (Kluwer 1993) p 21Google Scholar; Kurer, O, “Definitions of Corruption” in Heywood, PM (ed), Routledge Handbook of Political Corruption (Routledge 2014) p 83Google Scholar ff.

10 See, eg, C Brown et al, “Political Corruption and Firm Value in the US” (2018) J Bus Ethics <ssrn.com/abstract=3147385> (last accessed 20 January 2020); Dimant, E and Tosato, G, “Causes and Effects of Corruption: What Has Past Decade’s Empirical Research Taught Us? A Survey” (2017) 32 J Econ Surv 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 For its annual Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI), Transparency International referred to corruption as “the abuse of public office for private gains”. This notion is the same as that used by other agencies and organisations such as the World Bank. In other contexts, however, Transparency International used a more general definition, qualifying corruption as “the abuse of entrusted power for private gain”. In 2012, however, the definition for the purposes of the CPI has been changed and unified to the latter. Corruption refers to “the abuse of entrusted power for private gain. Corruption can be classified as grand, petty and political, depending on the amounts of money lost and the sector where it occurs”. See UNDP, Human Development Report: Deepening Democracy in a Fragmented World (OUP/UNDP 2002)Google Scholar; UNODCCP Global Dynamics of Corruption, the Role of the United Nations Helping Member States Build Integrity to Curb Corruption (Global Programme against Corruption Conferences, Vienna 2002)Google Scholar.

12 Shleifer, A and Vishny, RW, “Corruption” (1993) 108 Q J Econ 599CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

13 Jain, AK, “Corruption: A Review” (2001) 15 J Econ Surv 71CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Pellegrini, L, “Economic Analysis of Corruption” in Pellegrini, L (ed), Corruption, Development and the Environment (Springer 2011) p 78CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

15 Reinikka, R and Svensson, J, “Measuring and Understanding Corruption at the Micro Level” in Della Porta, D and Rose-Ackerman, S (eds), Corrupt Exchanges: Empirical Themes in the Politics and Political Economy of Corruption (Nomos Verlagsgesellshaft 2002)Google Scholar. See also, eg, S Gupta, H Davoodi and R Alonso-Terme, “Does Corruption Affect Income Inequality and Poverty?” (1998) IMF Working Paper 76; Husted, BW, “Wealth, Culture, and Corruption” (1999) 30 J Int Bus Stud 339CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Paldam, M, “The Cross-Country Pattern of Corruption: Economics, Culture, and the Seesaw Dynamics” (2002) 18 Eur J Political Econ 215CrossRefGoogle Scholar; You, J-S and Khagram, S, “A Comparative Study of Inequality and Corruption” (2005) 70 Am Sociol Rev 136Google Scholar; Shen, C and Williamson, JB, “Corruption, Democracy, Economic Freedom, and State Strength: A Cross-national Analysis” (2005) 46 Int J Comp Sociol 327CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 Reinikka, R and Smith, N, Public Expenditure Tracking Surveys in Education (UNESCO International Institute for Educational Planning 2004) p 15Google Scholar. These measures of perceived corruption are subject to the bias of members of the sample, which might give partial explanation for the remarkably good performance of OECD countries despite the evidence that many of the highest value acts of fraud and corruption in fact occur in OECD countries.

17 Eskeland, GS and Thiele, H, Corruption Under Moral Hazard (Mimeo, World Bank 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 ibid; Prendergast, C, Investigating Corruption (Mimeo, World Bank 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; D Dreyer Lassen and JE Alt, “The Political Economy of Institutions and Corruption in American States” (2002) University of Copenhagen, Economic Policy Research Unit, Working Paper No 02-16.

19 See, eg, Stigler, GJ, “The Theory of Economic Regulation” (1971) 2 The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20 Regulatory capture is a broad phenomenon referring to the situation where the State privileges commercial or political concerns of special interest groups that dominate the industry or sector over the public interest. Capture may be caused subtly through the provision of information, or so called “information capture”. The information imbalance between regulators and private actors, and the consequent dependency of the former on the latter, empowers industry to influence rules and standards, and tilts the outcome toward industry interests. Thus, as policy becomes more complex, and regulators become more dependent on industry, there is a higher likelihood that rules will be biased towards industry preferences. On the other hand, “representational capture” occurs when there is an imbalance in the representation of the competing interests, such as between commercial and public interests. In such cases, a regulator is at higher risk of adopting an industry-friendly point of view if the only people that it hears from, or primarily hears from, are industry members. For further elaboration upon regulatory capture, see eg Carpenter, D and Moss, DA, “New Conceptions of Capture – Mechanisms and Outcomes” in Carpenter, D and Moss, DA (eds), Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit It (Cambridge University Press 2014)Google Scholar; N McCarty, “Complexity, Capacity, and Capture” in Carpenter and Moss (eds), ibid.

21 This is commonly known as the public interest theory of regulation. See eg Prosser, T, Nationalised Industries and Public Control (Blackwell 1986)Google Scholar; Croley, SP, “Theories of Regulation: Incorporating the Administrative Process” (1998) 1 Columbia Law Rev 56Google Scholar; James, O, “Regulation Inside Governments: Public Interest Justifications and Regulatory Failures” (2000) 78 Public Adm 327CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Krueger, AO, “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society” (1974) 64 Am Econ Rev 291Google Scholar, at p 296.

23 Cool, P and Kirkpatrick, C (eds), Privatisation in Less Developed Countries (Wheatsheaf 1988)Google Scholar; Vickers, J and Yarrow, G, Privatization: An Economic Analysis (MIT Press 1988)Google Scholar; Shapiro, C and Willig, RD, “Economic Rationales for the Scope of Privatization” in Suleiman, EN and Waterbury, J (eds), The Political Economy of Public Sector Reform and Privatization (Westview Press 1990)Google Scholar; Boycko, M et al, “A Theory of Privatisation” (1996) 106 Econ J 309CrossRefGoogle Scholar; D Lal, The Poverty of “Development Economics (IEA Hobart Paperback No 16, 1997); World Bank, Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and Politics of Government Ownership (Oxford University Press 1995)Google Scholar.

24 Acemoglu, D and Verdier, T, “The Choice between Market Failures and Corruption” (2000) 90 Am Econ Rev 194CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 See Wolf, C Jr, Markets or Governments: Choosing Between Imperfect Alternatives (MIT Press 1989)Google Scholar.

26 In the literature the same concepts are referred to as “state failure”, “government failure” or “non-market failure”. See, eg, Arrow, KJ, The Limits to Organization (Norton 1974)Google Scholar; Weisbrod, BA, “Problems of Enhancing in the Public Interest: Towards a Model of Government Failure” in Weisbrod, BA et al (eds), Public Interest Law: An Economic and Institutional Analysis (University of California Press 1978) pp 3041CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Parker, D, “Economic Regulation: A Review of Issues” (2002) 73 Ann Public Coop Econ 493CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dollery, BE and Worthington, AC, “The Evaluation of Public Policy: Normative Economic Theories of Government Failure” (1996) 7 J Interdiscip Econ 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Johansson, P-O, The Economic Theory and Measurement of Environmental Benefits (Cambridge University Press 1987)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Le Grand, J, “The Theory of Government Failure” (1991) 21 Br J Politic Sci 423CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Vining, AR and Weimer, DL, “Government Supply and Government Production Failure: A Framework Based on Contestability” (1991) 10 J Public Policy 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Williamson, OE, “Review of Markets or Governments: Choosing Between Imperfect Alternatives” (1989) 27 J Econ Lit 92Google Scholar.

27 Wolf, C Jr, “A Theory of Nonmarket Failure: Framework for Implementation Analysis” (1979) 22 J Law Econ 107CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wolf, C Jr, “A Theory of Non-Market Failures” (1979) 55 Public InterestGoogle Scholar; Wolf, C Jr, “‘Non-market Failure Revisited’: The Anatomy and Physiology of Government Deficiencies” in Hanusch, H (ed), Anatomy of Government Deficiencies (Springer-Verlag 1983) pp 2742CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wolf, C Jr, “Market and Non-Market Failures: Comparison and Assessment” (1987) 7 J Public Policy 43CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Wells, JT, “Why Employees Commit Fraud” (2001) 191(2) J Accountancy 89Google Scholar.

29 Arnone, M and Borlini, LS, Corruption: Economic Analysis and International Law (Edward Elgar 2014) p 20Google Scholar.

30 Reinikka and Svensson, supra, note 15; Reinikka and Smith, supra, note 16; F Allen et al, “Corruption and Competition” (2015) <dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2685219> (last accessed 20 January 2020).

31 See, eg Mauro, supra, note 8; P Mauro, “The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Government Expenditure” (1998) IMF Working Paper 96/98; S-J Wei, “Why is Corruption So Much More Taxing Than Tax? Arbitrariness Kills” (1997) NBER Working Paper No 6255; Wei, S-J, Corruption in Economic Transition and Development: Grease or Sand? (UNECE Spring Seminar, Geneva 1999)Google Scholar <www.unece.org/fileadmin/DAM/ead/sem/sem2001/papers/Wei.pdf> (last accessed 20 January 2020); Edgardo Campos, J et al, “The Impact of Corruption on Investment” (1999) 27 World Dev 1059CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kaufmann, D, “Corruption: The Facts” (1997) 107 Foreign Policy 114CrossRefGoogle Scholar; V Tanzi, “Corruption Around the World: Causes, Consequences, Scope, and Cures” (1998) IMF Staff Papers 45/4; V Tanzi and HR Davoodi, “Corruption, Public Investment, and Growth” (1997) IMF Working Paper No 97/139; D Kaufmann and S-J Wei, “Does ‘Grease Money’ Speed up the Wheels of Commerce?” (2000) IMF Working Papers No 64; Wei, S-J and Sievers, S, “The Cost of Crony Capitalism” in The Asian Competitiveness Report (World Economic Forum 1999)Google Scholar; Johnson, S et al, “Regulatory Discretion and the Unofficial Economy” (1998) 88 Am Econ Rev 387Google Scholar; S Johnson et al, “Corruption, Public Finances, and the Unofficial Economy” (1999) World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 2169 <ssrn.com/abstract=192569> accessed 2018; Gupta et al, supra, note 15; Anderson, JE and Marcouiller, D, “Trade, Insecurity, and Home Bias: An Empirical Investigation” (2002) 84 Rev Econ Stat 342CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32 In fact, corruption should not be necessarily accounted for as a social deviation from an optimum. If the optimum had to be Pareto efficiency, in fact, corruption might actually result, at times, in a better allocation of resources. The view that corruption can be efficiency-enhancing has a long tradition in economics, see, eg, Aidt, TS, “Economic Analysis of Corruption: A Survey” (2003) 113 Econ J 632CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33 Shleifer and Vishny, supra, note 6; Shleifer and Vishny, supra, note 12.

34 Boycko, M et al, Privatizing Russia (MIT Press 1995).Google Scholar

35 Akerlof, GA and Shiller, RJ, Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism (Princeton University Press 2009) p 64Google Scholar.

36 Arnone, M and Davigo, P, “Arriva la Crisi Economica? Subito Spunta la Corruzione” (2005) 5 Vita e Pensiero 3Google Scholar.

37 M Arnone and LS Borlini, “Corruption – Economic Analysis and Evolution of the International Law and Institutions” (2011) CeMaFiR Working Paper No 04 - 07.2011, Bocconi Legal Studies Research Paper No 1933460.

38 Treisman, D, “What Have We Learned About the Causes of Corruption from Ten Years of Cross-National Empirical Research” (2007) 10 Annu Rev Political Sci 211CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

39 D Treisman, “What Does Cross-National Empirical Research Reveal about the Causes of Corruption” in Heywood, supra, note 9, pp 95–109.

40 Chen, Y et al, “Factors Influencing the Incidence of Bribery Payouts by Firms: A Cross-Country Analysis” (2008) 77 J Bus Ethics 231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

41 See, eg, Passas, N, “Lawful but Awful: ‘Legal Corporate Crimes’” (2005) 34 J Socio-Econ 771CrossRefGoogle Scholar; A Mungiu-Pippidi, “Contextual Choices in Fighting Corruption: Lessons Learned” (2011) Norwegian Agency for Development Cooperation <ssrn.com/abstract=2042021> (last accessed 20 January 2020); Can Aktan, C, “Political Corruption: An Introductory on Terminology and Typology” (2015) 7 Int J Social Sci and Humanity Stud 1309Google Scholar.

42 Lord, N and Levi, M, “Organizing the Finances for and the Finances from Transnational Corporate Bribery” (2017) 14 Eur J Criminol 365CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43 See eg Kolstad, I and Søreide, T, “Corruption in Natural Resource Management: Implications for Policy Makers” (2009) 34(4) Resource Policy 214CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Williams, DA and Le Billon, P, Corruption, Natural Resources and Development: From Resource Curse to Political Ecology (Edward Elgar 2017)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; OECD, Corruption in the Extractive Value Chain – Typology of Risks, Mitigation Measures and Incentives (OECD 2015)Google Scholar.

44 S Oosterloo and J de Haan, “A Survey of Institutional Frameworks for Financial Stability” (2003) DNB Occasional Studies 104, Netherlands Central Bank, Research Department; Weiß, GNF et al, “What Factors Drive Systemic Risk During International Financial Crises” (2014) 41 J Bank Finance 78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

45 US Department of the Treasury, 2011 Annual Report – Financial Stability Oversight Council (US Department of the Treasury 2011).

46 UK Financial Services Act 2012, Pt 9C.

47 EU Regulation 1092/2010 of the European Parliament and of the Council.

48 Amorello, L, Macroprudential Banking Supervision & Monetary Policy (Palgrave Macmillan 2018)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

49 Benoit, S et al, “Where the Risks Lie: A Survey on Systemic Risk” (2017) 21 Rev Finance 109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

50 P Smaga, “The Concept of Systemic Risk’ (2014) SRC Special Paper No 5.

51 Butzbach, O, “Systemic Risk, Macro-Prudential Regulation and Organizational Diversity in Banking” (2016) 35 Policy Soc 239CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Freixas, X et al, Systemic Risk, Crises, and Macroprudential Regulation (MIT Press 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; FSB, IMF, and BIS, Macroprudential Policy Tools and Frameworks: Technical Report February (2011); IMF, Key Aspects of Macroprudential Policy: Technical Report (2013).

52 Butzbach, supra, note 51.

53 C Borio, “Towards a macroprudential framework for financial supervision and regulation?” (2003) BIS Working Papers No 128, p 5.

54 Schwarcz, SL, “Systemic Risk” (2008) 97 Georget Law J 193Google Scholar, at p 195.

55 For a review of the multitude of systemic risk definitions in the literature, see Smaga, supra, note 50.

56 Schwarcz, supra, note 54, p 199.

57 Borio, supra, note 53, p 7.

58 L Lessig, “Institutional Corruptions” (2013) Edmond J Safra Ctr for Ethics Working Papers No 1, <papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2233582> (last accessed 20 January 2020); Thompson, DF, Ethics in Congress: From Individual to Institutional Corruption (The Brookings Institution 1995)Google Scholar.

59 ibid.

60 Martínez-Jaramillo, S et al, “Systemic Risk, Financial Contagion and Financial Fragility” (2010) 34 J Econ Dyn Control 2358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

61 Smaga, supra, note 50.

62 L Lessig, Code 2.0 (Basic Books 2006).

63 Morgan, B and Yeung, K, An Introduction to Law and Regulation (Cambridge University Press 2007) p 26CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

64 Black, J, “Decentering Regulation: Understanding the Role of Regulation and Self-Regulation in a ‘Post-Regulatory’ World” (2001) 103 Curr Leg Probl 54Google Scholar; Black, J, “Mapping the Contours of Contemporary Financial Services Regulation” (2002) 2 J Corp Law Stud 243CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Black, J, “Critical Reflections on Regulation” (2002) 27 Aust J Leg Philos 1Google Scholar; Black, J, “Enrolling Actors in Regulatory Systems: Examples from UK Financial Services Regulation” (2003) Public Law 63Google Scholar; J Black, “Seeing, Knowing, and Regulating Financial Markets: Moving the Cognitive Framework from the Economic to the Social” (2013) LSE Legal Studies Working Paper No 24 <ssrn.com/abstract=2346098> (last accessed 20 January 2020).

65 IMF, A Fair and Substantial Contribution by the Financial Sector: Final Report to the G20 (2010); E Perotti and J Suarez, “Liquidity Insurance for Systemic Crises” (2009) CEPR Policy Insight No 31; Acharya, VV et al, “Measuring Systemic Risk” (2017) 30 Rev Financ Stud 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Borio, supra, note 53, p 7; Borio, C, “Implementing a Macroprudential Framework: Blending Boldness and Realism” (2011) 6 Capitalism and SocietyCrossRefGoogle Scholar; Borio, C, “The Financial Cycle and Macroeconomics: What Have We Learnt?” (2014) 45 J Bank Finance 182CrossRefGoogle Scholar.