Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T09:35:14.101Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Towards an Ecologically-based Economic Philosophy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 August 2009

J. A. Hanson
Affiliation:
Senior Systems Scientist, The Oceanic Institute, Makapuu Point, Waimanalo, Hawaii 96795, U.S.A.

Extract

The present global economic order is one which fails to recognize the finiteness of global resources and the finiteness of the global ecosystem to absorb wastes. Indeed, there may be a great deal of lip-service paid to these truths; but nevertheless the global economic system, as it is functioning today, exhibits little or no awareness that they are at all important to a stable world economy. Superimposed upon this condition is the ‘Autophage Effect’, which points to a continuing acceleration in depletion of raw resources even though the net resource-demands of the world's populations may stabilize.

This is a human predicament which cannot and will not continue indefinitely. The key question is, ‘Will Earth's societies acknowledge the situation early enough to choose alternatives?’ There appear to be only two fundamental alternatives: either the present level of population and material abundance (imperfect as it may be) will crash, or it will be replaced by a world economic order which attends to the finiteness of this planet. Should we be fortunate enough or quick enough to realize the second alternative, I suggest that the basic structure of the new economic order may rather closely resemble the ecologists' ‘trophic’ divisions in natural ecosystems (e.g. Lindeman, 1942). If this comes to pass, conservation of energy and order (negentropy) will very likely emerge as the prime forcing functions in the resulting world socio-economic order.

This exploration has progressed from logical derivation into imagination, but still leaves a plethora of unanswered questions. If one does admit that industrial civilizations must eventually face resource limitations and thereby be driven towards the patterns exposed by the hypothetical society that has been sketched here, how do we get there from our present predicament? Can such a society be capitalistic, with grossly or moderately unequal distribution of resources among its citizens? Or must it be a form of socialistic idealism; and, if so, should it be democratic or autocratic? Can the present momentum of the highconsumption Keynesian theology be redirected? And if so, how—and will there be time? If the seeds offered here have any credibility, they should be nurtured further.

Type
Main Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Foundation for Environmental Conservation 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anon. (1969). Resources & Man (by the Committee on Resources and Man—National Research Council). Freeman, W. H., San Francisco, California: xi + 259 pp., illustr.Google Scholar
Anon. (1972). Webster's Third New International Dictionary of the English Language Unabridged. G. & C. Merriam, Springfield, Massachusetts: 72a + 2662 pp., illustr.Google Scholar
Edsall, J. T. (1974). Hazards of nuclear fission power and the choice of alternatives. Environmental Conservation, 1(1), pp. 2130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edsall, J. T. (1975). Further comments on hazards of nuclear power and the choice of alternatives. Environmental Conservation, 2(3), pp. 205–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enzer, H., Dupree, W. & Miller, S. (1975). Energy Perspectives. U.S. Department of the Interior, Washington, D.C.: 207 pp., illustr.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1971). The Entropy Law and the Economic Process. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts: xv + 457 pp.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Häfele, W. (1975). Second Status Report of the IIASA Project on Energy Systems (RR–76–1). International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria: vi + 249 pp., illustr.Google Scholar
Hanson, J. A. (1974). Open Sea Mariculture. Dowden, Hutchinson & Ross, Stroudsburg, Pennsylvania: xi + 410 pp., illustr.Google Scholar
Heilbroner, R. L. (1969). The Worldly Philosophers (3rd edn). Simon & Schuster, New York, N.Y.: 320 pp.Google Scholar
Kahn, H. & Wiener, A. J. (1967). The Year 2000: A Framework of Speculation on the Next Thirty-three Years. Macmillan, New York, N.Y., and Collier-Macmillan, London: xxviii + 431 pp., illustr.Google Scholar
Lekachman, R. (1966). The Age of Keynes. Random House, New York, N.Y.: vii + 324 pp.Google Scholar
Lindeman, R. L. (1942). The trophic-dynamic aspect of ecology. Ecology, 23, pp. 399418.Google Scholar
Malloy, M. T. (1975). He predicted the oil shortage 19 years ago. National Observer, May 10 issue, pp. 1 and 20.Google Scholar
Odum, H. T. (1971). Environment, Power and Society. Wiley-Interscience, New York & London: ix + 331 pp., illustr.Google Scholar
Packard, V. (1960). The Waste Makers. McKay, New York, N.Y.: 340 pp.Google Scholar
Schumacher, E. F. (1973). Small is Beautiful. Harper & Row (Perennial Library), New York, N. Y.: viii + 305 pp.Google Scholar
Toynbee, A. (1972). A Study of History. Oxford University Press/American Heritage Press, New York, N.Y.: 576 pp., illustr.Google Scholar