Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T17:54:39.962Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Environmental Economics: Can Economics Help Mother Earth?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 August 2009

W. Douglass Shaw
Affiliation:
Senior Associate, Environment and Science Policy Division, RCG/Hagler, Bailly & Co. Inc., PO Drawer 0, Boulder, Colorado 80306, USA.

Extract

Ecologists and environmentalists have long been at odds with economists over whether economic theory and practice helps or hinders environmental protection and improvement. This paper suggests that the specific field of environmental economics has contributed a great deal to the potential for environmental improvement, particularly with recent improvements in techniques which attempt to value environmental goods. The basic tenets of environmental economics are reviewed, including the tradable emissions-permits approach, and then specific recent applications of the permit system in the United States of America are presented.

The two basic valuation techniques, travel cost and the contingent valuation method (CVM), are briefly discussed, along with the shortcoming of the travel cost approach in obtaining ‘intrinsic’ values for environmental goods. This paper describes results from experimental economics which support the use of the CVM in estimating intrinsic values for environmental resources. In a new study, subjects in a laboratory experiment pay to prevent the destruction of a plant. This finding should appeal to the environmentalist and ecologist. Lastly, recent developments in macroeconomics and general equilibrium models which incorporate pollution and resource degradation variables, are shown to contribute positively to the goal of global environmental improvement.

Type
Main Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Foundation for Environmental Conservation 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Boyce, Rebecca R, Brown, Tom C., McClelland, Gary D., Peterson, George L., Schulze, William D. (1990). An Experimental Examination of Instrinsic Environmental Values. Working paper, Department of Economics, University of Colorado, Boulder, Colorado, USA: 31 pp. (mimeogr.)Google Scholar
Brown, Lester R., Flavin, Christopher & Postel, Sandra (1989). The State of the World. The Worldwatch Institute & W.W. Norton, New York, NY, USA: xvi + 256 pp.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1960). The problem of social cost. J. of Law and Economics, 3, pp. 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coursey, Don, Hovis, Jon & Schulze, William D. (1987). On the supposed disparity between willingness to accept and willingness to pay measures of value. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, pp. 679–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cummings, Ronald, Brookshire, David S. & Schulze, William D. (Eds) (1986). Valuing Environmental Goods: An Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method. Rowman & Allanheid, Towata, New Jersey, USA: xiii + 270 pp.Google Scholar
Daly, Herman E. (1987). The economic growth debate: what some economists have learned but many have not. J. of Environmental Economics and Management, 14, pp. 323–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, Paul R. (1981). An economist in wonderland. Social Science Quarterly, 62(1), pp. 45–9.Google Scholar
Holl, Karen, Daily, Gretchen & Ehrlich, Paul R. (1990). Integrated pest management in Latin America. Environmental Conservation, 17(4), pp. 241–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kneese, Allen V., Ayres, Robert U. & D'Arge, Ralph C. (1970). Economics and the Environment: A Materials Balance Approach. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, USA: x + 119 pp.Google Scholar
Markusen, James, Morey, Edward R. & Olewiler, Nancy (1990). Environmental Policy When Market Structure and Plant Locations are Endogenous. Presented at the meetings of the American Association of Agricultural Economics, Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada, August 1990. (Available as Discussion Paper, Department of Economics, University of Colorado, Boulder, Colorado, USA: 28 pp., mimeogr.).Google Scholar
Mitchell, Robert & Carson, Richard (1989). Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent Valuation Method. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, USA: xix + 463 pp.Google Scholar
Morey, Edward & Shaw, W. Douglass (1990). The impact of acid rain: a characteristic approach to estimating the demand for and benefits from recreational fishing. Pp. 195216 in Advances in Applied Microeconomics, Vol. 5, Link, A. & Smith, V.K. (Eds) JAI Press, Greenwich, Connecticut, USA: xi + 235 pp.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D. & Tobin, J. (1972). Is growth obsolete. Pp. 417 in National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Economic Growth, Fiftieth Anniversary Colloquium, New York, NY, USA, Vol. 5.Google Scholar
Parker, Ian & Graham, A. (1989). Elephant decline: downward trends in African Elephant distribution and numbers. International J. of Environmental Studies, 35, pp. 1326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearce, David, Markandya, Anil & Barbier, Edward B. (1989). Blueprint for a Green Economy. Earthscan Publications, London, England, UK: [not available for checking].Google Scholar
Ransdell, Eric (1990). The Leakey offensive. Outside Magazine, 01, pp. 3741 and 80–1, illustr.Google Scholar
Simon, Julian L. (1981). Environmental disruption or environmental improvement. Social Science Quarterly, 62(1), pp. 3045.Google Scholar
Tietenberg, Thomas H. (1991). Managing the transition: the potential role for economic policies. Pp. 187226 in Preserving the Global Environment (Ed. Mathews, Jessica T.). W.W. Norton, New York, NY, USA: 362 pp.Google Scholar