Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T05:55:16.023Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Golden Rice: no progress to be seen. Do we still need it?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 November 2016

Justus Wesseler
Affiliation:
Social Science Department, Wageningen University, Hollandseweg 1, 6706KN Wageningen, The Netherlands. E-mail: [email protected]
David Zilberman
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, USA. E-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In the December 2014 issue of Environment and Development Economics, we published the article, ‘The economic power of the Golden Rice opposition’ by Wesseler and Zilberman. The paper generated substantial interest, not only in academia but also among civil society groups. In this note, we address some of the concerns that have been raised about our results. Our main conclusion remains that misguided regulations in the case of Golden Rice have cost millions of healthy life years and billions of dollars.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

In the December 2014 issue of this journal we published the article, ‘The economic power of the Golden Rice opposition’ (Wesseler and Zilberman, Reference Wesseler and Zilberman2014). The paper generated substantial interest, not only in academia but also among civil society groups. Since its publication, the paper has become the most downloaded paper in Environment and Development Economics. The paper has an Altmetric (2016) score of 392, which measures the wider social impacts of publication, and is among the top 5 per cent of all papers published and in the 99th percentile of publications of the same vintage. Responses in some social media outlets have been rather critical.

Let us first summarize the paper, which applies the real option approach to develop a methodology to assess the monetary cost of delaying the permission to introduce a technology in order to resolve some of the uncertainty about the technology's social impact. It applies the model to compute the expected cost of delay of the introduction of Golden Rice in India. We computed both the annual expected costs and accumulative cost, both in dollars and disability-adjusted life years. These costs are very high (billions of dollars and millions of disability-adjusted life years) and raise the question as to whether the option value of the extra caution that was behind the regulation is worth the cost of the delay.

In this note, we address two main concerns that have been raised about the paper. First, we assumed that Golden Rice would have been available for utilization in 2002, but it has not yet been commercialized (e.g. Stone, Reference Stone2015; Philpott, Reference Philpott2016). We used 2002 as the starting point based on the expectations by experienced rice breeders and experts in genetic engineering (Enserink, Reference Enserink2008). However, the regulatory system delayed the introduction of the technology, and these delays are discussed in detail by Potrykus (Reference Potrykus2010), Dubock (Reference Dubock2014) and Stone (Reference Stone2015). In 2005, Bradford et al. (Reference Bradford, Van Deynze, Gutterson, Parrott and Strauss2005: 442) warned about the drawbacks of the regulation, saying:

Release of Golden Rice awaits deregulation of a single event and backcrossing into locally adapted varieties, rather than simultaneously transforming the required genes into a range of varieties. Thus, restrictive event-specific regulatory policies act to reduce biological diversity by forcing backcrossing of single events rather than use of diverse genetic backgrounds.

The probability of success would have been higher if, instead of a sequential approach, a parallel approach had been used, thereby accelerating the process, but this would have been very costly due to regulation (Dubock, Reference Dubock2014) – an issue that is not only relevant for Golden Rice, but for genetically modified (GM) crops in general (Strauss and Sax, Reference Strauss and Sax2016).

An important related point is that our analysis was applied to India, where the severity of Vitamin A deficiency is likely to be the greatest and where no solution is close to fruition. The technology is not considered in India due to heavy domestic opposition, despite the country's significant indigenous capacity in plant breeding and agricultural biotechnology. Furthermore, India recently rejected the introduction of GM eggplant (Herring, Reference Herring2014).

The second concern raised is that ‘Golden Rice’ is not needed because alternative solutions exist that could address the problem (e.g., Philpott, Reference Philpott2016). The claim that our argument is weakened by the availability of alternative approaches to the Vitamin A deficiency issue is in fact discussed in our paper. We pointed out that if affordable alternatives exist worldwide, then Golden Rice is unnecessary. But despite reducing Vitamin A deficiency in parts of the world, such as the Philippines, there are still important parts of the world where it prevails, namely in South Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa (Stevens et al., Reference Stevens, Bennett and Hennocq2015). This is the reason why our option value calculation was based on the Indian case study where we anticipated that the problem would last longer. But even if Vitamin A deficiency can be reduced using alternative means, the alternatives can be expected to be expensive, and Golden Rice can be an important cost-effective part of the solution (Stein et al., Reference Stein, Sachdev and Qaim2008).

In summary, the main contribution of our paper is to introduce a methodology to compute the option value of delay in the introduction of a technology. We used Golden Rice as a numerical example to illustrate the concept and generate some real-world insights. There is clear evidence that the introduction of Golden Rice is delayed by regulation, and in India this is mainly induced by opposition to the technology. If there is a sense of urgency to save healthy life-years of individuals who suffer from Vitamin A deficiency, parallel testing of multiple events should be done. Furthermore, regulatory frameworks can be streamlined to accelerate finding the solution to various diseases. Golden Rice is a ‘medical application’ for the millions of sufferers in India (and elsewhere). The required time frame of testing can be shortened (Chaturvedi et al., Reference Chaturvedi, Srinivas, Joseph and Singh2012). Our main conclusion remains that misguided regulations in the case of Golden Rice have cost millions of healthy life-years and billions of dollars, a claim that has recently been supported by more than 100 Nobel Prize Laureates (Achenbach, Reference Achenbach2016).

References

Achenbach, J. (2016), ‘107 Nobel laureates sign letter blasting Greenpeace over GMOs’, Washington Post, 30 June, [Available at] https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/speaking-of-science/wp/2016/06/29/more-than-100-nobel-laureates-take-on-greenpeace-over-gmo-stance/.Google Scholar
Altmetric (2016), ‘The economic power of the Golden Rice opposition’, [Available at] https://cambridgejournals.altmetric.com/details/2067705.Google Scholar
Bradford, K., Van Deynze, A., Gutterson, N., Parrott, W., and Strauss, S. (2005), ‘Regulating transgenic crops sensibly: lessons from plant breeding, biotechnology and genomics’, Nature Biotechnology 23(4): 439444.Google Scholar
Chaturvedi, S., Srinivas, K.R., Joseph, R., and Singh, P. (2012), ‘Approval of GM crops’, Economic & Political Weekly 47(23): 5361.Google Scholar
Dubock, A. (2014), ‘The politics of Golden Rice’, GM Crops & Food 5(3): 210222.Google Scholar
Enserink, M. (2008), ‘Tough lessons from Golden Rice’, Science 320: 69471.Google Scholar
Herring, R. (2014), ‘State science, risk and agricultural biotechnology: Bt cotton to Bt Brinjal in India’, Journal of Peasant Studies 42(1): 159186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Philpott, T. (2016), ‘WTF happened to Golden Rice’, Mother Jones, [Available at] http://www.motherjones.com/tom-philpott/2016/02/golden-rice-still-showing-promise-still-not-field-ready.Google Scholar
Potrykus, I. (2010), ‘Lessons from the “Humanitarian Golden Rice” project: regulation prevents development of public good genetically engineered crop products’, New Biotechnology 27: 466472.Google Scholar
Stein, A., Sachdev, H., and Qaim, M. (2008), ‘Genetic engineering for the poor: Golden Rice and public health in India’, World Development 36(1): 144158.Google Scholar
Stevens, G.A., Bennett, J.E., Hennocq, Q., et al. (2015), ‘Trends and mortality effects of vitamin A deficiency in children in 138 low-income and middle-income countries between 1991 and 2013: a pooled analysis of population-based surveys’, Lancet Global Health 3(9): e528e536.Google Scholar
Stone, G. (2015), ‘Bringing a superfood down to Earth’, Blog, [Available at] https://publichealth.wustl.edu/bringing-a-superfood-down-to-earth/.Google Scholar
Strauss, S. and Sax, J.K. (2016), ‘Ending event-based regulation of GMO crops’, Nature Biotechnology 34(5): 474477.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wesseler, J. and Zilberman, D. (2014), ‘The economic power of the Golden Rice opposition’, Environment and Development Economics 19(6): 724742.Google Scholar