Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T08:22:27.390Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Free trade and the greening of domestic industry

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 May 2014

Sumeet Gulati
Affiliation:
Food and Resource Economics, University of British Columbia, #341-2357, Main Mall, Vancouver, BC, CanadaV6T 1Z1. Tel: (604) 822-2144. E-mail: [email protected]
Devesh Roy
Affiliation:
International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC, USA. E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

In this paper we present an example where a domestic import-competing industry can benefit from a pollution tax borne by its consumers. We show that this pollution tax can be similar to a traditional trade barrier (such as a tariff) and can raise the price received by the domestic industry. Given an open economy, we highlight conditions under which domestic producers prefer a higher consumption-based pollution tax than is socially optimal. In contrast, when the economy is closed, we find that producers prefer a pollution tax that is lower than socially optimal. Domestic producers turn ‘green’ only when faced with import competition.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aidt, T.S. (1998), ‘Political internalization of economic externalities and environmental policy’, Journal of Public Economics 69(1): 116.Google Scholar
Copeland, B. (2001), ‘Trade and the environment: product standards in a national treatment regime’, Mimeo, University of British Columbia.Google Scholar
Copeland, B. and Gulati, S. (2006), ‘Trade and the environment in developing countries’, in Lopez, R.E. and Toman, M. (eds), Economic Development and Environmental Sustainability: New Policy Options, Initiative for Policy Dialogue Series, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Copeland, B. and Taylor, M.S. (1995), ‘Trade and the environment: a partial synthesis’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77: 765771.Google Scholar
Copeland, B. and Taylor, M.S. (2004), ‘Trade, growth and the environment’, Journal of Economic Literature 42(1): 771.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeSombre, E.R. (1995), ‘Baptists and bootleggers for the environment: the origins of United States unilateral sanctions’, Journal of Environment and Development 4(1).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeSombre, E.R. (2000), Domestic Sources of International Environmental Policy: Industry, Environmentalists and U.S. Power, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diewert, W.E. (1974), ‘Applications of duality theory’, in Intriligator, M. and Kendrick, D. (eds), Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, Vol. II, Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 106171.Google Scholar
Fischer, R. and Serra, P. (2000), ‘Standards and protection’, Journal of International Economics 52: 377400.Google Scholar
Foletti, L. (2012), ‘Trade effects of SPS measures: the case of Maximum Residue Levels’, Conference Presentation at University of Geneva.Google Scholar
Fredriksson, P.G. (1997), ‘The political economy of pollution taxes in a small open economy’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 33(1): 4458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1994), ‘Protection for sale’, American Economic Review 84(4): 833850.Google Scholar
Gulati, S. (2008), ‘Free trade and the burden of domestic policy’, Canadian Journal of Economics 41(3): 813837.Google Scholar
Hammar, H., Löfgren, A., and Sterner, T. (2004), ‘Political economy obstacles to fuel taxation’, Energy Journal 25(3): 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hillman, A.L. (1982), ‘Declining industries and political-support protectionist motives’, American Economic Review 72: 11801187.Google Scholar
Innes, R. and Bial, J. (2002), ‘Inducing innovation in the environmental technology of oligopolistic firms’, Journal of Industrial Economics 50: 263285.Google Scholar
Krutilla, K. (1991), ‘Environmental regulation in an open economy’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 20: 127142.Google Scholar
Li, Y. and Beghin, J.C. (2012), ‘Protectionism indices for non-tariff measures: an application to maximum residue levels’, Staff General Research Paper No. 35276, Iowa State University, Department of Economics.Google Scholar
Lyon, T.P. and Maxwell, J.W. (2004), Corporate Environmentalism and Public Policy, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McAusland, C. (2003), ‘Voting for pollution policy: the importance of income inequality and openness to trade’, Journal of International Economics 61(2): 425451.Google Scholar
McAusland, C. (2004), ‘Environmental regulation as export promotion: product standards for dirty intermediate goods’, Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 3(2).Google Scholar
McAusland, C. (2005), ‘Harmonizing tailpipe policy in symmetric countries: improve the environment, improve welfare?’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 50(2): 229251.Google Scholar
McAusland, C. (2008), ‘Trade, politics and the environment: tailpipe vs. smokestack’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 155(1): 5271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oye, K. and Maxwell, J. (1994), ‘Self interest and environmental management’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 6(4): 593624.Google Scholar
Rauscher, M. (1997), International Trade, Factor Movements, and the Environment, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Salop, S.C. and Scheffman, D.T. (1983), ‘Raising rivals' costs’, American Economic Review 73: 267271.Google Scholar
Schreurs, M.A. and Economy, E. (1997), ‘Domestic and international linkages in environmental politics’, in Scheurs, M.A. and Economy, E. (eds), The Internationalization of Environmental Protection, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Swinnen, J., Van Herck, K., and Vandemoortele, T. (2012), ‘The experience economy as the future for European agriculture and food?’, LICOS Discussion Paper, No. 313.Google Scholar
UNEP (2009), Trade and Climate Change. World Trade Organization. United Nations Environment Programme, [Available at] http://unep.org/.Google Scholar
UNEP (2013), Green Economy and Trade Trends, Challenges and Opportunities, [Available at] http://www.unep.org/greeneconomy/GreenEconomyandTrade.Google Scholar
Vogel, D. (1995), Trading Up: Consumer and Environmental Regulation in a Global Economy, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Vogel, D. (1998), ‘Social regulations as trade barriers: how regulatory reform can also help liberalize trade’, The Brookings Review 16(1): 3336, [Available at] http://www.brookings.edu/press/review/winter98/vogel.htm.Google Scholar
Vogel, D. (2000), ‘Environmental regulation and economic integration’, Journal of International Economic Law, 3(2): 265279.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Gulati and Roy Supplementary Material

Appendix

Download Gulati and Roy Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 206.8 KB