Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T10:11:22.175Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Emission taxes when pollution depends on location

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 March 2012

Walid Marrouch
Affiliation:
School of Business, Lebanese American University, Lebanon; and CIRANO. Email: [email protected]
Bernard Sinclair-Desgagné
Affiliation:
HEC Montréal, 3000 Chemin de la Côte-Sainte-Catherine, Montréal (Québec), Canada H3T 2A7; CIRANO and École Polytechnique de Paris. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

It is well known that an efficient pollution taxation scheme should charge each source according to its specific marginal contribution to social damages. Despite significant advances in environmental assessment, geographic information systems and data analysis, this requirement would impose technical, informational and administrative expenses that most regulators – notably in developing countries – seem unable to afford. This paper shows that it can actually be less demanding than it seems. If polluters are price-takers, for instance, in a context where the affected population concentrates at a given location, then the optimal emission tax will disregard a source's location. Otherwise, the adjustment of the optimal tax to location will depend on the extent of a polluter's market power.

Type
Theory and Applications
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Barnett, A.H. (1980), ‘The Pigouvian tax rule under monopoly’, American Economic Review 70(5): 10371041.Google Scholar
Bateman, I., Yang, W., and Boxall, P. (2006), ‘Geographical information systems (GIS) and spatial analysis in resource and environmental economics’, in Folmer, H. and Tietenberg, T. (eds), The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 4392.Google Scholar
Baumol, W.J. and Oates, W.E. (1988), The Theory of Environmental Policy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bockstael, N.E. and Irwin, E.G. (2000), ‘Economics and the land use-environment link’, in Folmer, H. and Tietenberg, T. (eds), The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 154.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J.M. (1969), ‘External diseconomies, corrective taxes, and market structure’, American Economic Review 59(1): 174177.Google Scholar
Geoghegan, J. and Gray, W.B. (2005), ‘Spatial environmental policy’, in Folmer, H. and Tietenberg, T. (eds), The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 5296.Google Scholar
Gerking, S. and List, J. (2001), ‘Spatial economic aspects of the environment and environmental policy’, in Folmer, H., Gabel, H.L., Gerking, S. and Rose, A. (eds), Frontiers of Environmental Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 5784.Google Scholar
Hardie, I.W., Parks, P.J., and van Kooten, G.C. (2004), ‘Land use decisions and policy at the intensive and extensive margin’, in Folmer, H. and Tietenberg, T. (eds), The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 101138.Google Scholar
Henderson, J.V. (1977), ‘Externalities in a spatial context’, Journal of Public Economics 7(1): 89110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hochman, E. and Ofek, H. (1979), ‘A theory of the behavior of municipal governments: the case of internalizing pollution externalities’, Journal of Urban Economics 6(4): 416431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hochman, E., Pines, D., and Zilberman, D. (1977), ‘The effects of pollution taxation on the pattern of resource allocation: the downstream diffusion case’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 91(4): 625638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hogan, M., Caley, K.J., and McGinley, M. (2010), ‘Causes of extinction’, in Cleveland, C.J. (ed.), Encyclopedia of Earth, Washington, DC: Environmental Information Coalition, National Council for Science and the Environment, [Available at] http://www.eoearth.org/article/Causes_of_extinction.Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. (1929), ‘Stability in competition’, Economic Journal 39(153): 4157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, J.-J. and Tirole, J. (1993), A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Magesan, A. and Turner, M.A. (2010), ‘The value of information in regulation’, The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 10(1): Art. 76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muller, N.Z. and Mendelsohn, R. (2009), ‘Efficient pollution regulation: getting the prices right’, American Economic Review 99(5): 17141739.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A.C. (1920), The Economics of Welfare, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Tietenberg, T.H. (1974), ‘On taxation and the control of externalities: comment’, American Economic Review 64(3): 462466.Google Scholar
Uimonen, S. (2001), ‘The insufficiency of Pigouvian taxes in a spatial general equilibrium model’, Annals of Regional Science 35(2): 283298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xepapadeas, A. (1992), ‘Optimal taxes for pollution regulation: dynamic, spatial and stochastic characteristics’, Natural Resource Modeling 6(2): 139170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar