Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T05:23:21.388Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Strike Insurance: The Labor Question and the Limits of Insurance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 October 2024

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Turn-of-the-century America witnessed many forgotten risk-making experiments that probed the limits of insurability by stepping beyond the familiar fields of life, fire, and marine insurance. One attempted to underwrite firms’ lost profits during strikes.

The ensuing debates on strike insurance’s practicability revealed scientistic expectations of never-ending actuarial progress that united an otherwise-divided business community. Yet attempting to realize strike insurance quickly meant grappling with the limits of insurability. Labor strife’s fuzzy causality involving human agency forestalled the homogenous classification that underlay actuaries’ averaging. Thus, strike underwriters sidestepped actuarial ratemaking to offer uniform premiums to those deemed acceptable risks. This solution not only left them susceptible to adverse selection and moral hazard but also highlighted the limits of insurers’ ability to transform uncertainty into commoditized risk, more broadly.

Recognizing these limits has important historiographical implications. Based largely on studies of life insurance—the gold standard of insurability—the rise of financial risk management has claimed a central place in the history of American capitalism. This literature thus threatens to obscure the ongoing significance of unclassifiable, unquantifiable uncertainty. Uncovering forgotten risk-making projects like attempts to establish strike insurance, where Americans grappled with the limits of insurability, is thus a crucial corrective.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Business History Conference

Six years after transatlantic cables had carried news of Bismarck’s welfare programs, word of a different German innovation in political economy reached American shores in February 1890. Now, readers of America’s business-oriented publications learned of German businessmen’s effort to secure themselves against labor activism. The Westphalian Mine Owners Association had voted unanimously to establish an antistrike insurance union. This scheme to compensate firms for lost production during work stoppages was a relatively minor affair in itself. Nevertheless, it sparked speculation on the practicability and value of strike insurance in anxious business circles across the Atlantic.Footnote 1 These discussions would soon smolder out. But a decade later, news from the German-speaking world would kindle efforts to underwrite strike risk on an actuarial basis—an instructive example of the many forgotten risk-making projects where turn-of-the-century Americans moved beyond the well-studied field of life insurance and probed the limits of insurability.Footnote 2

When news of Viennese and Saxon strike insurance schemes arrived in late 1900, it found a receptive audience in the American business community. Reflecting decades of effort by life insurers, Americans had enthusiastically embraced insurance as a tool to meet capitalism’s freaks of fortune and expected underwriters’ risk-making project to conquer new fields of uncertainty. Labor conflict appeared one such area of growing uncertainty. Against a backdrop of strengthening labor activism, progressive reformers and liberal-individualist employers both turned to strike insurance as a potential panacea. Despite their differing ideologies and class interests, both initially built these hopes on a naive if understandable faith in actuarial science. Nevertheless, their attempts to realize strike insurance quickly meant replacing the actuary with the insurance agent as the pivotal risk-making figure. This realization has significant historiographical implications.

Both actuaries and insurance agents have claimed an increasingly central place in American history as scholars have examined how modern, expert-dominated risk management—headlined by life insurance—supplanted the nation’s vernacular risk culture.Footnote 3 Though Hannah Farber has compellingly argued that marine underwriters played a key role shaping the early republic, historians have recognized Jacksonian Era advances in life insurance as a major break.Footnote 4 Marine underwriting depended on experienced merchants using customary knowledge while exercising individual judgment about the hazards of specific journeys. Life insurers, however, made an ideal of abstraction while helping individuals manage the risks that came with an increasingly anonymous, market-dependent society.Footnote 5 Although Sharon Murphy has stressed how antebellum life insurers’ marketing overstated their progress, these firms nevertheless reflected broader trends of professionalization by embracing the era’s vogue for numeracy and statistical thinking to develop techniques to calculate objective mortality risks.Footnote 6 Gilded Age life insurers could thus justifiably boast that their industry stood at the cutting edge of actuarial science—identifying individuals’ mortality risks probabilistically based on a few key characteristics.Footnote 7 As Dan Bouk has shown, this process depended upon a productive tension between averaging away individual particularity to leverage the law of large numbers and classing individual risks into sufficiently homogenous groups to make these averages useful.Footnote 8 Stressing the judgments involved in the latter, Bouk and Caley Horan have denaturalized insurers’ risk classifications to offer prehistories of big data and questions of algorithmic justice, underscoring the insurance industry’s ongoing influence on the development of America’s political economy.Footnote 9

Yet after the Jacksonian Era, this literature has focused overwhelmingly on life insurance—the gold standard of insurability.Footnote 10 Doing so provides a distorted historical lens that magnifies the power of financial risk management. While largely critical of businessmen’s, policymakers’, and economists’ attempts to reduce life to probabilistically predictable patterns, this literature thus ironically threatens to recreate Ken Arrow’s and Armen Alchian’s influential reduction of uncertainty to stochastic risk.Footnote 11 That is, to collapse unclassifiable, unquantifiable uncertainty into calculable, insurable risk by treating the clearest example of the latter—life insurance—as normative.

Emboldened by life insurers’ success and the allure of big data’s analog grandfather,Footnote 12 turn-of-the-century Americans faced a similar temptation. Amid accelerating scientific and industrial progress, they now routinely deferred to professional authority in fields from medicine to scientific management where practitioners—like insurers—promised to solve some of modern life’s most vexing problems by combining practical empiricism with technical expertise.Footnote 13 And, New York Life’s John A. McCall could boast in 1898 of his industry’s “uninterrupted progress” since the 1880s. Its three-fold expansion was marred by “but one failure of importance.”Footnote 14 Likewise, the old—if historically unreliable—field of fire insurance had worked toward stability by diversifying their risk portfolios and embracing interfirm cooperation to develop an actuarial ratemaking system.Footnote 15 These successes inspired a raft of experimentation. By 1902, the many novel hazards insurers attempted to underwrite prompted the Insurance Press’s Franklin Webster to remark with some bewilderment that

It is not too much to say that the insurance idea is all pervasive. Life insurance, fire insurance, accident insurance, health insurance, various kinds of liability insurance, marine insurance, burglary insurance, credit insurance, steam boiler insurance, plate glass insurance—all these are heard of every day. There is talk of strike insurance.Footnote 16

Not just a reflection of the insurance idea’s triumph across America’s economic culture, attempts to underwrite new hazards like strike risk left turn-of-the-century businessmen probing the limits of actuarial science—and, with it, the boundary between insurable risk and uninsurable uncertainty. Uncovering these forgotten risk-making projects thus represents an important corrective for a historiography that has treated the rise of financial risk management founded on probabilistic risk calculation as a dominant theme in the development of modern American capitalism.

Arguments for strike insurance initially showed an outsized appreciation for the power of quantification and actuarial science. They did not, however, imply that strike insurance’s manufacturing enthusiasts fully understood insurance. The handful of manufacturers who set out to realize it necessarily entered a crash course in underwriting that quickly disabused them of their actuarial dreams. Information problems founded in the limited quantifiability and complex causality of the human action behind labor conflict forestalled any attempt to generate actuarially scientific rates based on averages for sufficiently homogenous classes of hazards. Rather, they would rely entirely on insurance agents’ and nonactuarial experts’ risk assessments. Dan Bouk has compellingly noted that these judgments existed in productive tension with actuarial smoothing to underlay all successful risk-making projects, but strike insurers’ efforts saw them set aside actuarial science and classing completely to establish a “preferred risk system,” where all policyholders deemed acceptable risks paid a uniform premium rate—erasing both risks’ particularities and the classing on which actuarial averaging depended.Footnote 17 But, beyond these interested few, manufacturers’ arguments for strike insurance revealed a continuing ignorance of—and disinterest toward—how insurers underwrote the policies on which they increasingly relied. All that mattered to them was offloading their labor uncertainty. Making it work was the actuaries’ job—or, as an interested few learned, the insurance agents’ job.

Either way, this was an important job because “the labor question” preoccupied turn-of-the-century Americans of all stripes.Footnote 18 Of course, businessmen coveted the ability to hedge against uncertainties brought about by labor conflict. But arguments for strike insurance also revealed that progressive reformers and liberal-individualist businessmen held further ambitions for the project: viewing labor organization and corporate scale as faits accomplis, the former hoped strike insurance would align incentives to conciliate between capital and labor. Small- and medium-sized employers, however, were worried about their place in an economy increasingly dominated by the visible hands of large corporations and organized labor. They hoped strike insurance would restore liberal-individualist markets by checking not only unions’ power but also corporate consolidations’ competitive advantage managing labor uncertainties via scale.

This article joins turn-of-the-century Americans in moving beyond the familiar field of life underwriting to probe the limits of insurability. Examining manufacturers’ forgotten experiment in strike insurance across four sections, it thus highlights the ongoing significance of unquantifiable, uninsurable uncertainty even after the arrival of modern financial risk management. First, it traces the idea’s arrival in the context of rising economic uncertainty mitigated partially by businessmen’s growing faith in the promise of commercial underwriting on an actuarial basis—a faith belied by the insurance press’s initial skepticism rooted in problems classifying strike risk. Next, it explores the ambitions of strike insurance’s loudest and most active advocates: small- and medium-sized manufacturers. They hoped it would counter unions’ collective action and allow their establishments to compete with new corporate rivals that could manage labor uncertainties via scale, but these hopes rested on an actuarial scientism projecting insurers’ risk-making successes across ever more fields. Analyzing two competing attempts to realize strike insurance, this paper’s third section highlights their shared realization of the classification problems involved and their retreat from actuarial ambitions to rely instead on insurance agents’ and nonactuarial experts’ judgements about hazards. Finally, it concludes by showing how these challenges nevertheless overwhelmed the era’s only American company to issue strike policies, highlighting the limits of insurers’ risk-making project, even as America’s experiment in strike insurance was quickly forgotten. Recognizing these limits represents a crucial corrective for a literature that has treated life insurers’ exceptionally “close approximation to objective probability” as normative.Footnote 19

Strike Insurance’s Atlantic Crossing

In October 1900, America’s consul in Trieste, Frederick Hossfeld, dispatched a missive from the then-Austrian port that would rekindle the American discourse on strike insurance. Hossfeld reported, “A number of Austrian manufacturers have recently formed an association for insurance against strikes.” Outlining the Viennese plan, the consul noted similar developments in Leipzig.Footnote 20

Hossfeld’s cable arrived at a moment of heightened uncertainty for many American businessmen. The nation was midway through a rapid economic restructuring, a transformation in regulatory policy, and the flowering of a powerful labor movement. The swift growth of capital-intensive firms engaged in mass production combined with the deep, deflationary depression beginning in 1893 to set off a wave of horizontal integration unmatched before or since, climaxing with 63 mergers in 1899—the year before Hossfeld’s report crossed the Atlantic. By then, policymakers and the public alike feared these newly consolidated firms’ substantial market power. Together, they manifested their concerns in a new federal regulatory regime—which, ironically, fell harder on smaller firms in more competitive industries than the monopolies and oligopolies it ostensibly targeted.Footnote 21 Businessmen whose firms had not been transformed by the great merger movement or Chandlerian vertical integration were left uncertain of their position vis-à-vis both this new regulatory regime and the economic behemoths that inspired it.Footnote 22 At the same time, they faced spiking labor activism. Nationwide union membership nearly doubled from 614 thousand in 1896 to 1.17 million in 1900. Over the same period, the number of work stoppages climbed from 1,066 to 1,839. These trends would crescendo alongside calls for strike insurance in the years following Hossfeld’s letter. The number of work stoppages would peak at 3,648 in 1903, while union membership would peak at 2.38 million in 1904—the years that American businessmen would organize their first strike insurance companies and issue their first policies, respectively.Footnote 23 In this environment, any plan promising to reduce uncertainties about labor activism to predictable, insurable risks had an understandable appeal.

The Austrian scheme, as Hossfeld explained it, formed the rough outline for most subsequent American strike insurance proposals. Under it, members of a mutual company would “pay a weekly premium equal to…3 to 4 per cent of…[their] payroll” with the proceeds furnishing the “indemnity to be paid to” the affected firm “in the case of a strike.” Tentatively, this indemnity would equal “50 per cent of the wages paid…for the week…preceding the suspension of work.” With slight modifications—like different premium rates and using fixed costs or profit as a basis for indemnification—these elements proved a common denominator between nearly all attempts to offer strike insurance commercially.Footnote 24

A final aspect of the Viennese scheme the consul highlighted would prove equally central and controversial among its would-be American imitators. Its policy held that “no indemnity shall be paid if…the association shall…find the strike a justifiable one.” This, Hossfeld noted, “recognize[d] in principle the justness of strikes, which is…an important concession to labor.”Footnote 25 Hossfeld was not alone in commenting on this recognition. Though the Arbeiter-Zeitung—the party organ of Austria’s Socialists—classified arguments for strike insurance as “childish lies about the workers’ organizations,” it opined “That the principle in the charter recognizing justifiable strikes is likely to spread shines a bright enough light on” the plan to welcome it. Indeed, the Viennese scheme’s acolytes expressly conceded that, “In principle, the right to strike could not be disputed.”Footnote 26

Although Hossfeld’s report rapidly received nationwide press,Footnote 27 insurance journals’ coverage ranged from cursory to flippantly dismissive.Footnote 28 Insurance journals may have adopted this stance because the practical objections to strike insurance appeared too obvious to merit comment. Indeed, many objections had already been aired in 1890 following news of Westphalia’s strike insurance scheme. Prospective insurers of strike risk faced particularly deep information asymmetries and quantification issues. Thus, adverse selection and moral hazard represented abnormally large challenges to them. Moreover, the subtle heterogeneity of employment conditions and impossibility of calculating lost profits with any certainty called into question strike hazard’s quantifiability and, thus, insurability.

In 1903, the Commercial and Financial Chronicle declared bluntly but with good reason that “The element of moral hazard is…insurmountable.”Footnote 29 The same incentives that might drive holders of fire policies to negligence or arson applied to strike insurance. But, unlike fires, strikes left no permanent damage. And determining contributory negligence in provoking them was inherently fuzzy. Even some favorable assessments of strike insurance’s prospects drew attention to these factors that made moral hazard especially challenging for its potential underwriters. In 1890 Britain’s self-consciously bourgeois Guardian did just that when it declared that the Westphalian scheme’s success would “doubtless[ly be] facilitated by the rapid rate at which the collieries of Western Germany [were] being concentrated in few hands.” This market concentration lowered the cost of cooperation—among a group that already possessed deep associational bonds—and meant that proprietors faced relatively little incentive to “wantonly enter into conflict with their men” as they stood to internalize a large portion of any strike’s cost.Footnote 30 Subsequent schemes did not boast similar advantages in overcoming moral hazard or its sister problem—adverse selection. Indeed, the Insurance Times could only respond with sarcasm at the thought of a member of the Viennese scheme finding itself the innocent victim of a strike.Footnote 31

The same market concentration that recommended the Westphalian plan to the Guardian underlay an equally valid critique the Chicago Tribune levelled against it. The Tribune admitted that “the insurance plan might work well” but only “[i]n the case of a struggle at one or a few mines.” It cautioned, however, that “organization…among the employés is not likely to limit its aggressiveness to a small area”—with the scheme’s concentration in a single industry boasting few firms exacerbating the chance that a single strike might overpower the insurance plan.Footnote 32 A deeper point lies at the heart of this critique—there must be a sufficient quantity of comparable firms within a class for a risk to be reliably calculable and, therefore, insurable. Frank Knight would make this point in his canonical 1921 book, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, which established classification and, thus, calculability as the still-prevailing delineation between insurable risk and uninsurable uncertainty in economic theory.Footnote 33

The Commercial and Financial Chronicle presaged Knight in perhaps the most incisive critique of the strike insurance project. It declared “we find ourselves quite at sea as to strike insurance…when we consider the problem of average—which means such a scattering of risks over a broad area, and such a recorded knowledge of the number and aggregate of losses, as will furnish a basis for premium rates.” There was the “temporary difficulty” of sparse data. But classification problems were not going away. Establishments “in some kinds…are deficient in number” to generate meaningful averages, while some subtle yet crucial differences between firms remained immeasurable. These manifold dimensions of subtle interfirm heterogeneity would be a permanent challenge. More metaphysically, the question remained, “how could strike damage be determined after its occurrence?” The Commercial and Financial Chronicle concluded that there was no satisfactory answer to this question—unlike other subjects of insurance, it inherently attempted to “determine the amount of something which as yet is non-existent” as “Profit is constructive.”Footnote 34

With prospective purveyors of strike insurance facing these especially deep problems of quantification—involving both the probability and amount of damage—in addition to potentially insurmountable challenges of moral hazard and adverse selection, it is easy to see why insurance journals initially dismissed the practicability of strike insurance. They would only begin to take strike insurance proposals seriously as the Viennese plan seemed poised to begin operation and received significant favorable attention in the United States.

September 4, 1902, marked a major turning point. That day a leading American insurance journal reported, “The Vienna Manufacturers Strike Insurance Company is being organized and will begin operations.”Footnote 35 The same day, one of America’s leading reformist journals, The Nation, published an editorial drawing on a French article to laud the plan’s ability to overcome the manifold obstacles to success in the field. Most notably, it would defray losses only partially, for a limited period to mitigate moral hazard. More interestingly, the editorial touted its potential to mediate labor strife: “the Austrian plan may have far-reaching social effects” because “the indemnity is paid only in cases the company judges the strike to be unjustifiable” and it “has every motive for impartiality.” Specifically, “It can no more afford to deplete the company chest to support a stupid or stubborn member, than it can safely desert a member in…need.” Though “the sympathies of the committee are sure to be with a fellow-manufacturer,” The Nation reasoned, “its interests are very largely with the strikers” meaning it would “push employers to the limits of possible concession.” Due to the committee’s perceived impartiality, “The moral value of such a verdict…will be tremendous” and it would function as “a permanent arbitration board” between capital and labor.Footnote 36 Thus, The Nation presented an alluring and distinctly modern vision of interest-balanced-against-interest to mediate class conflict—reflecting insurers’ growing ambition to not only predict the future but also change it.Footnote 37

The Nation’s vision of a strike insurance scheme that “would have straightened out the tangle into which the coal-strike negotiations immediately fell” proved seductive in fall 1902, as the United Mine Workers’ famous Pennsylvania strike entered its fifth month.Footnote 38 Numerous publications endorsed this vision. “In this balance of interests,” the Chicago Tribune found “some hope that the company will be not only an insurance enterprise but a kind of unofficial arbitrator and conciliator.”Footnote 39 A St. Louis–based periodical for the iron and machine tools trade responded with optimistic incredulity, unconvinced by The Nation’s reasoning yet swept up with its promise all the same.Footnote 40 They agreed with the Viennese plan’s most vocal Austrian advocate that “The best strike insurance is not that which compensates the economic damage of work stoppages, but that which works towards a reduction in the number of strikes.”Footnote 41 Other trade and general interest publications paraphrased The Nation or reprinted its editorial in full.Footnote 42

These arguments depended on an actuarial scientism The Nation joined with this new public attention to reconfigure the insurance trade press’s attitude toward underwriting strike hazards. In addition to arguing that the Viennese scheme properly balanced interests to make strike insurance practicable, The Nation also drew on the insurance industry’s impressive run of actuarial innovation to argue that the probability of strikes was calculable and, therefore, an insurable risk.Footnote 43

This was a hubristically inflated faith in the power of “big data” and actuarial science. But, following the insurance industry’s recent colonization of numerous new sectors of life and business, it was an understandably inflated faith. This faith reflected more than just actuarial progress. It required overcoming a challenge posed by mutual aid societies offering assessment-based benefits that mushroomed beginning in the 1870s. As fraternalist challengers captured over half of the rapidly growing life-insurance market over the following three decades, commercial underwriters trained a well-funded counterattack on them, alleging that their benefits funded by postmortem assessments were actuarially unsound.Footnote 44 Though the fraternals’ ideology mingling solidarity with self-help would leave legacies in America’s welfare politics,Footnote 45 their histories seemed to confirm the commercial underwriters’ claims. By the mid-1890s, a raft of fraudulent or failed fraternals helped inspire surviving societies’ turn toward actuarial risk management strategies even as commercial life insurers began reclaiming market share.Footnote 46 In the process, life underwriters had increasingly sold the public and regulators on the power of actuarial science—helping inspire many new risk-making projects from plate glass insurance to credit insurance.Footnote 47 “At a time when we are adding to actuarial estimates of marine, fire, and death-risks reliable percentages for accident and sickness insurance,” The Nation could thus confidently assure its readers, “it will not seem strange that the strike-risk should be very closely computed.”Footnote 48

Such appeals to actuarial progress particularly affected previously dismissive insurance-industry voices. Over a year after last offering half-hearted coverage to the plan, the Insurance Press responded to The Nation by declaring, “The Vienna experiment in ‘strike insurance’ will be worth watching” and sounded positive notes about its feasibility.Footnote 49 Another leading insurance periodical, The Spectator, was more sanguine. “The insurance system is extremely elastic, and has been made to cover most of the contingences that arise in the course of business,” it explained. After all, “Valuable statistics have been gathered…during the past few years…upon which to construct a scientific basis for strike insurance.”Footnote 50 It was far from alone in extrapolating “this constant extension of the principles of insurance to new business requirements” to strike insurance. In terms already familiar to readers of “The Central Organ of Austrian Employers,” The Insurance Monitor effused, “another half century may see its application to fields which to-day seem wholly beyond its range.”Footnote 51

The growing confidence The Nation, The Spectator, and others expressed that actuarial science would conquer ever more fields of hazard reflected a triumph of actuarial insurance in the wider American culture that even leading insurance journalists found striking. The still-novel idea of strike insurance’s sudden prominence prompted reflections on this development. Lecturing an underwriters’ conference on “The Insurance Age” soon after The Nation’s editorial, the Insurance Press’s Franklin Webster saw “talk of strike insurance” denaturalizing “the insurance idea.” Truly, Webster remarked, “the underwriting idea is everywhere.”Footnote 52

Manufacturing a Case for Strike Insurance

Even with insurance journalists’ newfound enthusiasm for the concept, the impetus behind strike insurance initiatives would come from manufacturers, who introduced a few related, well-publicized attempts to realize the concept in 1903.Footnote 53 That April the vehemently open shop and sometimes explicitly antiunion National Association of Manufacturers (NAM) passed a resolution at its annual convention calling its leadership “to formulate a plan for an organization…to insure…manufacturers against…losses resulting from strikes.”Footnote 54

In his study of strike insurance, Harold Foster characterized NAM’s move as part of the “crusade against unionism in general” that Selig Perlman and Philip Taft depicted employers undertaking from 1903 to 1908.Footnote 55 This characterization has much truth to it. NAM president David Parry decried arbitration in near-apocalyptic terms at the same conference. It was “only putting off the day of reckoning” with labor unions that were antithetical to freedom and the natural law of the market—lessons he would soon dramatize across a 400-page dystopian novel. Yet, NAM members voted for a resolution endorsing a strike insurance appendage “formed in part…for the purpose of negotiation…with employes on the subject of wages.” This reflected at least some faith in The Nation’s vision of strike insurance mediating shopfloor conflict. And that is how it was widely read. Fearing that such mediation would undermine managerial prerogatives, a consistent Parry promoted a peculiarly limited interpretation of his organization’s strike insurance proposal excluding any mediation provisions.Footnote 56 By generally embracing these provisions, however, NAM’s membership highlighted the tension between the liberal-individualist commitments Parry voiced and the methods they endorsed to mitigate the uncertainty labor activism brought.

After NAM’s resolution, three strike insurance plans appeared in rapid succession across the East. There was the Mutual Security Company, chartered in May in Waterbury, Connecticut.Footnote 57 Another group of businessmen carried the idea back from NAM’s New Orleans convention and rushed to establish a strike insurance concern in Louisville. Before NAM’s strike insurance committee had the chance to consider different plans, these Louisville manufacturers had organized the Employers’ Underwriters at Reciprocal Exchange. By November, one of the latter’s leaders could lament that its “policies…have been available…for several months” without securing “applications in sufficient volume…to establish the business successfully.”Footnote 58 Nevertheless, NAM’s committee soon joined the action, mooting a scheme of trade association cooperation that made up for its deviation from strict insurance principles with its ambitious scale. Contemporary reports evinced a frustrating but understandable tendency to conflate the different strike insurance schemes. They all drew from similar constituencies and even shared some leaders.Footnote 59 And this conflation soon proved prophetic as the Louisville concern folded by mid-November, with its Waterbury counterpart absorbing the bulk of it and NAM’s strike insurance energy.Footnote 60

The managers of the 150 firms that rushed to sign strike insurance policies with Waterbury’s Mutual Security Company and allowed it to commence operations in late 1903 shared a common background with the three schemes’ leaders. They came from a world of independent proprietorship, of small- and medium-sized manufacturers who increasingly felt uncertain of their place in the economy.Footnote 61 They ran relatively small firms competing in sectors newly dominated by trusts or relatively large firms in sectors whose largest firms were dwarfed by these new corporate colossuses—a pattern that also prevailed in Austria and Germany.Footnote 62

The Mutual Security Company’s director and treasurer Robert Foote Griggs was typical of strike insurance’s manufacturing backers. Just months before the Mutual received its charter in May 1903, he had cashed out from one of Waterbury’s “smaller brass companies.” There he had watched a streetcar strike plunge the city into chaos that not only created financial fears but also inspired anxiety about impending mob rule. Indeed, most journalists covering the event offered some variation on the Springfield Republican’s story that “the Mutual security company…grew out of the recent strike at Waterbury.”Footnote 63 Griggs had also witnessed the great merger movement transform a rapidly growing brass industry. After nearly a decade of false starts, three of the sector’s largest firms rung in the new century by forming a trust—the American Brass Company—that would soon employ half of the nation’s 10,000 brass workers. And another of the city’s largest brassware manufacturers bought out Griggs’s old firm in May 1903—just three months after he had left it and the same month Connecticut chartered the Mutual Security Company.Footnote 64

Strike insurance apologists’ arguments would demonstrate just how telling their background as employers rather than insurers was. While founders of strike insurance schemes necessarily made quick studies of the insurance trade when forming their business plans, the bulk of manufacturers interested in these schemes wore their ignorance of insurance as a badge of honor—or, at least, self-deprecating humor.

As Louisville businessmen launched their strike insurance concern in June 1903, Railway Age, an eloquent mouthpiece of railroads and industrial employers generally, repeated The Nation’s case for strike insurance, adding that it would help “disunited, often rival, employers” overcome commitment problems to “get the benefit of co-operation.” The strength of cooperating employers could overcome any strike, it reasoned. “The mere existence of such a company…would undoubtedly be a powerful preventive to hasty and unreasonable strike making.” Thus, Railway Age placed an iron fist in The Nation’s velvet glove.Footnote 65

Manufacturers—struck by the promise of actuarial insurance and wishing to unload their labor uncertainties—offered only a cursory case for its potential profitability. For example, one Chicago manufacturer endorsing the idea as “tend[ing] to produce industrial peace” admitted that “incorporating an insurance-against-strikes company…would have to be considered from the standpoint of an insurance company.” Yet he offered no suggestion for its profitable management. And one of the leading forces behind the Louisville scheme essentially repeated Railway Age’s argument—merely adding an explicit reliance on “the competent insurance expert” as a deus ex machina who would ensure that “the technicalities now in the way are wiped out” and make “strike insurance…a most remunerative investment.”Footnote 66

In their remarks on strike insurance, manufacturers often paired this indifference to the practical business of insurance with an abject ignorance of it. In an indicative scene, one manufacturer drew sympathetic laughter at NAM’s conference by prefacing his comments with the admission, “I do not understand anything about insurance except…what I have to pay.”Footnote 67 While manufacturers’ embrace of strike insurance proposals reflected the insurance idea’s triumph in American business culture, their mingled indifference to and ignorance of how they might profitably be put into practice highlights the startling degree to which underwriting remained a black box beyond the understanding of even much of the business class.Footnote 68

Chicago typewriter manufacturer C.N. Fay offered the most eloquent articulation of the logic behind liberal-individualist manufacturers’ understanding of strike insurance at NAM’s annual convention in 1904. Leading a company through a strike had led him to the realization

that strike insurance, if it could become as universal as fire insurance, would go very far, very far, to strengthen the weak [employers] and remove from the strong and selfish [employers] the temptation to take advantage of their weakness; that it would equalize conditions and reduce desertions [from employers’ stance against organized labor], and make each man independent alike of unions and competitors, to settle his own difficulties with his own employes without thereby complicating the settlements of others. As it would be national and common to all employers, it would be founded on the broadest financial basis and become adequate to the most widely extended strike…. Before very long the hopelessness of striking against an insured employer would become so evident that, unlike fire or death, which are not frightened away by policies, trades unionism would…shrink from its destruction of capital, of progress, and…of the welfare of its own devotees.Footnote 69

Here, Fay argued that strike insurance would “protect the small man and the average manufacturer” by freeing firms from the various external pressures that led them to submit to labor’s demands.Footnote 70 Namely, the compensation it promised would remove weak firms’ compulsion to surrender to union demands to secure revenues needed to meet fixed costs and stronger firms’ incentive to exploit rivals’ incapacitation for a quick profit by cooperating with the union—empowering the union in its efforts against other firms.Footnote 71 As such, Fay concluded, strike insurance would check unions’ coercive power, while freeing firms from the consequences of rival firms’ decisions. This hope reflected a common sentiment, voiced by America’s leading marginalist John Bates Clark, that insurance gave “independent business…a greatly improved chance of holding their own…against corporations” whose scale enabled them to self-insure against risks like strike hazard.Footnote 72 Thus, Fay embodied manufacturers’ view that interfirm cooperation in the form of strike insurance could reinvigorate individual freedom that had been checked by the coercion of organized labor.

An idiosyncratic view of organized labor that suffused much of the writing on strike insurance stood at the heart of Fay’s account. In it, unions represented a coercive, illiberal obstacle preventing the natural law of the market from functioning properly. Unions’ power and illiberality both stemmed from the way they brought individual laborers into a collective that undertook unified action, including monetary support to striking workers. This prompted many to observe that “unions are essentially great insurance organizations” making “good the loss of work” for strikers.Footnote 73 This understanding had been current for decades and was pervasive enough that journalists had felt the need to specify that “The insurance proposed in Vienna is for the benefit of the employer, not the employed.”Footnote 74 Thus, even before employers’ strike insurance claimed a place in the public discourse, businessmen and workers alike framed unions’ support for striking members as a form of insurance. Consequently, businessmen viewed strike insurance efforts as merely “a basis of resistance to the great national organizations of the unions.”Footnote 75

Oddly, the expansive application of the insurance terms to labor union efforts did not extend to trade associations. Occasionally during strike insurance discussions someone would “call…attention to the fact that there are practically such institutions in existence” with the National Founders’ Association’s former president writing that his group was “practically an insurance organization.” Its constitution mandated that members contribute to a reserve fund for members affected by strikes. So did the National Metal Trades Association, whose May 1901 declaration of principles marked the key turning point from the National Civic Federation’s attempted accord between capital and labor toward 1903’s open shop drive in David Montgomery’s classic narrative.Footnote 76 NAM flirted with this strategy as well.Footnote 77 Nevertheless, experience from American trade associations’ mutual strike aid remained marginal to the discourse. Rather, theoretical speculation and experiential evidence from the German-speaking world continued to dominate these discussions—despite their Teutonic tutors tracing a course far closer to trade association strike aid than Americans realized.

Aside from a strategic choice to keep their efforts quiet,Footnote 78 this reluctance to recognize trade associations’ existing strike insurance provisions perhaps reflected SME proprietors’ discomfort with scale. Explicit interfirm cooperation might undermine the ideological role liberal-individualist businessmen assigned to strike insurance: leveraging advances in actuarial science to counterbalance trade unionism and restore liberal-individualist labor relations. By functioning as a firm selling a service, commercially organized strike insurance allowed them to disguise their cooperation and hide the paradox of them attacking scale via scale.

Therein lay the main difference between their liberal-individualist understanding of strike insurance and The Nation’s progressive vision of impartial mediation. The former was ill at ease with scale generally and hoped that strike insurance would help them check it, cancelling out labor combination to restore individual contract’s reign. The latter recognized the legitimacy of great combinations of capital and labor, seeking a model of collective bargaining that might alleviate labor uncertainty and class conflict. This recognition also led to tensions within the drive to establish strike insurance. The progressive vision of arbitration had little problem conceding the legitimacy of some strikes. The liberal-individualist manufacturers, however, did not like recognizing any strike as legitimate or natural. But even halfhearted attempts to grapple with the problems of insuring against them forced the Louisville and Waterbury schemes to admit that employers might provoke strikes—a concession that raised hackles amongst much of their potential constituency and, some argued, kept their membership unsustainably small.

Despite this concession, the greatest overlap between the two flavors of strike insurance advocacy may have been their general disregard for the economics of insurance. No less than The Nation, liberal-individualist manufacturers like the Louisville scheme’s leaders simply turned to “the competent insurance expert” to ensure that “strike insurance will be a most remunerative investment.”Footnote 79 C.N. Fay spoke for them all when he bluntly intoned that he had “no intention of being, personally interested in any strike insurance company…except as one of the insured.” Rather, Fay advocated strike insurance due to “the immediate importance of the thing itself” as a way to reestablish individual liberty that he believed labor organization had threatened. Another manufacturer announced his support with the non sequitur, “I say this Association needs to oppose the tyranny of organized labor, and therefore strike insurance is practicable.”Footnote 80 All that mattered to them was offloading their labor uncertainty and restoring individualist labor markets. Making it work was the actuaries’—or, some would soon learn, insurance agents’—jobs.

Realizing Strike Insurance (and Its Limits)

Despite their shared constituency, press coverage, and fate, the rival strike insurance schemes’ founders engaged in a bitter fall 1903 debate over how to realize their shared ambition. This debate came after the schemes’ founders undertook crash courses in underwriting principles and arrived at different judgments about not only the prudent legal form for strike insurance but also the proper response to a shared acknowledgement of the impracticability of actuarial ratemaking in its early years.

It began when Louisville’s William Nones published a front-page editorial in the September 1 edition of NAM’s mouthpiece, American Industries. His argument for strike insurance’s necessity was unremarkable.Footnote 81 Two weeks later, however, Nones sparked controversy when he explained his scheme’s business model. He immediately discounted the stock company or Lloyds models. Premiums “must be placed quite high…to cover the contingencies of a new business” and any surplus, “after payment of losses and expenses, would go to the underwriters.” Rather, Nones found himself weighing an incorporated mutual company against a reciprocal underwriting plan. Both shared two key benefits. “Neither…requires any capital stock.” Thus, strike insurance promoters could sidestep still skeptical insurance men and financiers. And, “Under either…the premium fund left after…expenses and losses is returned to the policy holders, who thus obtain…insurance at its actual cost.”Footnote 82

The key differences between the two lay in their legal forms. Mutuals derived their existence from state charters. Reciprocals need not be incorporated, deriving their existence “from an agreement and power of attorney” executed by each policyholder. Nones saw two differences determining in the latter’s favor. Unlike mutuals, reciprocals limited expenses to a fixed percentage of premiums. And they allowed flexibility “to make changes” “as experience is gained.”Footnote 83

Finally, Nones explained an innovation introduced to account for the limits of scientific ratemaking in experimental fields. Each policyholder would be assigned to a group of twenty-six hazards of similar risk. Each group’s members would reciprocally insure equal parts of each other’s hazards. Though Nones placed great faith in actuaries’ long-term ability to derive scientific rates for strike risk, this plan recognized that the dearth of experience in experimental fields made it “impossible to determine just how much more or less the premium rate ought to be for one…risk than another.” Despite this skepticism about actuaries’ short-run ability to generate meaningful averages for classes of hazards, Nones believed it was “not very difficult to determine that certain risks…are practically of the same degree.”Footnote 84 Assuming he could, thus, class strike hazards, the Louisville scheme’s group feature would alleviate the need to set rates for them. Casualty rates within each group would determine each group’s net premiums.

Writing in the next issue of American Industries, Waterbury’s Louis van Keuren agreed with Nones “that the necessity for such insurance exists, and that all the conditions which make…insurance…practicable are to be found.” But he objected to the Louisville scheme’s business model, including a blistering attack on “the most novel feature of [Nones’s] plan:” its group feature.Footnote 85

Van Keuren noted how reciprocals’ legal informality posed dangers to policyholders who enjoyed none of the state regulations that “guarded…all reliable life and fire insurance companies.” And reciprocal policyholders only shared connections with their hazard groups and the scheme’s attorney-manager—depriving policyholders of legal recourse in the event of most foul play. Van Keuren also saw a flaw in the Louisville reciprocal’s most inflexible feature. He could not agree with Nones’s claim that it would “provide insurance at its actual cost.” It would “take out of each premium a fixed…twenty per cent” for expenses and managerial compensation, though “Experience has proved” that incorporated mutuals “take…much less.”Footnote 86

But van Keuren’s knockout blows targeted Nones’s innovation “of dividing the applicants…into groups of twenty-six each.” Van Keuren counseled that “It hardly seems prudent to adopt a novel and untried plan of insurance when…another…has been found safe and practicable.” But his core objection to Nones’s group feature was not this prudential conservatism. Instead, it lay in a recognition that “All insurance is based on average.” Where an insurer underwriting 100,000 lives could “determine to a fraction of 1 per cent how many will die each year,” the same would not be the case “if they should divide these lives into groups of twenty-five.” The law of large numbers would not apply in these small samples. Instead, random variation would make “each group…show a different average, some being entirely exterminated and others not losing a single member.” This made “the group plan…much like a wager policy.”Footnote 87

Then there was the question of group composition. The Connecticuter questioned whether the Kentucky carriage maker—or his advisory committee of fellow manufacturers—had any more ability to assign policyholders to hazard groups than actuaries had to assign them scientific rates. While many strike insurance advocates looked to fire insurance as a source of optimism, van Keuren found the comparison sobering. “In fire insurance, after years of experience, it has not been possible to establish a system of rates that are absolutely satisfactory,” van Keuren wrote—before adding that fire underwriters “have only physical conditions to deal with.” Strike underwriters would have no such luxury. Listing “some of the conditions that should influence a differential in rate,” van Keuren enumerated “location, strength of the unions, kind of business, intelligence of the employes, their nationality, their wages as compared with those paid to others in a similar business, the character and popularity of the employer and each of his foremen, and many others, some of even a more trivial nature.” Altogether, he joined Nones and many strike insurance critics in acknowledging that the ambiguous, often qualitative factors affecting hazard in the field rendered ratemaking a daunting—perhaps impossible—task.Footnote 88

Admitting that actuarial ratemaking would “take years of experience, if it can ever be done,” van Keuren—like Nones—thus turned to a strategy of screening hazards holistically. But, unlike the Louisvillian, the Connecticuter recognized that “the larger the number of risks, the more nearly to the correct average will be obtained.” His Mutual Security Company thus did away with different classes and premium rates altogether. Instead, it drew on the model of New England’s factory–mutual fire underwriters to establish a “preferred risk system,” which offered a uniform premium rate to all would-be policyholders who passed its screening mechanism.Footnote 89

While discounting some of the trade and financial press’s strike insurance critiques, both schemes’ promoters attempted to craft business models that accounted for these potential roadblocks. In both cases, this meant an extreme response to the limits on actuarial ratemaking in a new field hampered by a dearth of data and many ambiguous confounding variables. As Dan Bouk has highlighted, actuaries’ celebrated alchemy depended upon the underappreciated efforts of insurance agents and other nonactuarial experts accounting for particularity even as actuaries’ averages abstracted it.Footnote 90 After all, smoothing observations into meaningful averages required sufficiently homogenous classes. The Louisville and Waterbury schemes’ business models both reflected a realization that this would be impossible. Strike risks’ complex causality involving many questionably quantifiable variables would confound attempts to class them into groups homogenous enough for actuaries to calculate scientific premium rates. Ironically, Nones responded to this limitation by doubling down on classing—proposing a group insurance model where the schemes’ agents assigned risks to groups whose realized losses would ultimately determine net premiums. This limitation also drove the Mutual Security Company to abandon actuarial ratemaking; however, van Keuren and his colleagues recognized that average remained the central feature of insurance and thus offered a single premium rate to a “preferred” class of policyholders.

The promoters of both strike insurance schemes thus probed the limits of actuarial ratemaking while attempting to realize their risk-making projects. Turning from the actuary to the insurance agent as the key risk-making figure, they nonetheless remained sanguine about strike hazard’s insurability—an optimism that experience would soon test.

Information Problems and the Failure of Strike Insurance

Though periodicals continued to publish on the topic and someone would occasionally propose a new strike insurance scheme, most novel points in America’s strike insurance discourse had already been aired by the end of NAM’s annual conference in 1904.Footnote 91 By the late aughts, little had changed. The Waterbury firm remained small, never insuring against more than $3,447,635 in strike losses at a time.Footnote 92 It also remained the only American concern offering strike insurance, despite continued calls for others to do so.Footnote 93 Even that would not last.

As the twentieth century’s first decade drew to a close, so did the Mutual Security Company’s life as a going concern. Its last policies expired in 1909 as the firm slowly wound down—a victim of the very challenges that early critics like the Commercial and Financial Chronicle had forecast would plague strike insurance.Footnote 94 The many questionably measurable interfirm heterogeneities that made grouping firms’ strike risks into sufficiently homogenous classes for actuarial ratemaking impossible also drove problems of adverse selection and moral hazard which led to predictably high loss ratios.

The Mutual had begun life confident that it could keep loss ratios manageable. Its policyholders paid 1-percent premiums with “liability to assessments up to five times the premium;” but they expected dividends not assessments.Footnote 95 They had heard its secretary’s regular boasts that “all statistics indicate that we will be able to return…at least eighty-five percent of this premium.”Footnote 96 A December 1904 report by NAM’s Strike Insurance Committee captured the logic behind these optimistic declarations. With minor adjustments committee-chairman C.N. Fay recreated the Mutual’s calculations, which reflected the information problems plaguing strike insurance efforts generally. Eschewing any further explanatory variables, they simply calculated a loss ratio from lightly adjusted strike and employment aggregates as in Equation (1):

(1) $$ Loss\ ratio=\frac{Mean\ establishments\ struck, 1881\;\mathrm{to}\;1900}{Mean\ establishments, 1881\;\mathrm{to}\;1900}\times \frac{Mean\ strike\ duration, 1881\;\mathrm{to}\;1900}{300\; Working\ days} $$
$$ Loss\ ratio=\frac{\mathrm{4,980}}{\mathrm{286,983}}\times \frac{23.8}{300}=0.00137 $$

Given this calculated loss ratio of 0.137 percent, NAM’s committee concluded, “it should be…possible…to do business at an actual cost of one-fourth of one percent for losses and expenses and to return to policyholders three-fourths of the premium paid.”Footnote 97

At first, this optimism seemed justified. Through 1906, the Mutual had paid only $3,685 in losses while receiving $95,532 in premiums (see Table 1), allowing it to return 35.4 percent of the latter to policyholders—a ratio that improves to 50.8 percent if excluding the first year’s data, which included startup costs but no time to refund end-of-year surpluses to policyholders. Though it had not returned Secretary Brown’s predicted 85 percent of premiums, these numbers seemed to confirm that the Mutual had guarded successful against adverse selection and moral hazard—especially given predictions “thatthere would be…a higher loss ratio” since “policies would probably be taken out by firms…of high strike hazard.”Footnote 98 But this sanguine outlook would not last.

Table 1. The Mutual Security Company’s balance sheet, 1904-1917

Note: The above-listed net balances are not always equal to the income items net expenses, due to interest on the company’s deposits.

Source: Adapted from the various reports of Connecticut’s state insurance commissioner: Connecticut, Fortieth Annual Report, Part II, through Connecticut, Fifty-Third Annual Report, Part II.

In July 1908, Massachusetts’s Fitchburg Sentinel carried a story about the Simonds Manufacturing Company receiving “full settlement…for…the strike in their…shops.” Though this press coverage was exceptional, the machine shop’s “very substantial” settlement was not.Footnote 99 In 1907 the Mutual ran an $18,735 deficit as the company paid $14,754 in excess premium dividends before loss payments jumped to $23,623 from $1,813 the previous year. This deficit would shrink in 1908—but only as the Mutual’s policyholders experienced their first excess loss assessments. Faced with higher payments—and questions about the Mutual’s stability—policyholders fled, sending the company into a death spiral.

A large legal judgment provided a telling coup de grâce in 1910. Four years earlier, a Mutual Security Company agent had called on the Buffalo Forge Company. There, he found a willing customer and “the application for the policy…was executed April 9th, 1906.” This application included a “schedule of warranties” about potential risk factors—the sole basis of the Waterbury company’s underwriting decisions. It understandably asked, “Are you a union shop and, if so, how many unions do you recognize?” The ungrammatical applicant answered, “Only so far as the National Foundrymen’s Association and National Metal Trades Association.” These “were not ‘unions’ of workingmen,” Connecticut’s Justice Silas Robinson would later explain, “but organizations of manufacturers created for the purpose…of dealing with trade unions.”Footnote 100 The Mutual knew this. Its secretary Frederick Brown had represented it at the NMTA’s 1905 convention.Footnote 101 If its officials had consulted publications like Railway Age or the Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, they would have also learned that the National Founders’ Association maintained a reserve fund for strike losses and that its Buffalo affiliate had entered a formal agreement with the city’s molders union in 1902.Footnote 102 This agreement covered the Buffalo Forge Company—and the manufacturer’s answer to another of the schedule’s questions implied as much.Footnote 103

Yet the Mutual issued it a policy, effective May 1. Perhaps the Buffalo company’s answer to another question had been reassuring. It did not have “any existing dispute with or demand made by employees.” By the time the Mutual issued its policy, this was no longer true. On April 21, Buffalo’s molders and coremakers issued demands for a modest wage increase effective May 1—a demand thirty-six employers including the Buffalo Forge Company’s Henry Wendt refused, denouncing uniform wage rates in principle. Wendt’s company would receive its strike insurance policy the following day—“shortly after the moulders…had gone on strike.” It immediately “mailed its check for $500…as the premium…, with a letter acknowledging the receipt of the policy and…that the moulders had just gone…on a strike.” It would be June 29 before the Buffalo company’s “molders returned to work…without asking or receiving any agreement of any kind.” Wendt and the National Founders’ Association would trumpet this as an open shop victory.Footnote 104

Wendt must have further celebrated that this victory would come at no cost: his company’s strike losses had been insured. It filed a claim for $26,000 in fixed costs and lost profits, but the Mutual refused payment—contending the Buffalo company’s application had concealed union activity at its shop. In 1908, the erstwhile policyholder sued for reimbursement, contending that it had answered accurately and, anyway, it was underwriters’ duty to verify their interpretation of any ambiguities before cashing any premiums. Eventually, the Connecticut Supreme Court agreed and approved a judgment of $29,499.49 in July 1910. By then, the Mutual’s last policies had lapsed and it “sent out a call to its members for an assessment.”Footnote 105

This judgment also effectively ruled against the practicability of commercial strike insurance. It—not unreasonably—deemed the insurer responsible for clearing up any ambiguities about prospective policyholders’ risk factors before accepting any premiums. This was not a new precedent, and it meant the Mutual’s eagerness to deposit the Buffalo company’s check “must be treated as a waiver” rendering any disputes “quite immaterial.”Footnote 106 Yet this court defeat reflected more than one clerical blunder—however colossal.

It also exposed the Waterbury company’s complete dependence on policy applicants’ answers to its schedule of warranties when assessing risks. The Mutual might have eliminated any ambiguities in the Buffalo company’s application had it combed newspapers, the trade press, and Bureau of Labor reports for answers. This independent perspective might also have taught them that Wendt had already provoked a strike in 1898 by demanding employees work longer hours for the same pay—all while operating three machines rather than one.Footnote 107 But it was not mere underwriting negligence that left the Mutual dependent upon policy applicants’ word. It had no other practical option. Its model of commercial strike insurance distinguished itself from trade association strike aid largely by underwriting hazards across industry and locality. This universality recommended it to strike insurance advocates from NAM to The Nation, who hoped it could answer the labor question generally, but it came with a cost. It meant companies like the Mutual—facing information problems that prompted them to eschew grouping risks into classes paying actuarial premiums—needed, nevertheless, to screen whether applicants of any industry or locality fit within their “preferred” class of policyholders. The same information problems applied to this question, and there was a reason the preceding six decades had witnessed the rise of credit-reporting agencies. Obtaining local information about far-flung potential counterparties was costly.Footnote 108 Independently investigating each applicant would be prohibitively expensive without the economies of scale attending an organization befitting strike insurance advocates’ grandest ambitions. Depending on policy applicants’ answers to its schedule of warranties freed it of this burden—giving the strategy an appeal despite depriving the Mutual of local knowledge.Footnote 109

This strategy, however, left it prone to adverse selection and moral hazard, as it offered no insight about firms’ labor relations reputations. The Buffalo Forge Company was hardly the only firm with a history of labor fights labelled “matters of principle” to pass screening based on the Mutual’s schedule of warranties. After all, C.N. Fay had lauded Simonds Manufacturing as a principled compatriot making “headway against the unions” in his call to arms for strike insurance at NAM’s 1904 convention, and other policyholders regularly declared their labor fights matters of principle.Footnote 110 All told, it is less surprising that adverse selection and moral hazard contributed to the Mutual’s collapse than that it took so long.

For nearly a decade, unfinished legal business and unpaid debts kept the Mutual Security Company’s ghost haunting former policyholders with assessments to meet its outstanding liabilities—a nagging reminder of the challenges standing in the way of attempts to insure strike hazards.Footnote 111 Others, however, found the Mutual’s experiences easier to forget.

For them, another consular report rung in a third decade with German-accented strike insurance discourse. The New Orleans Picayune was typical. It highlighted the American consul at Brunswick’s “report on this form of insurance which…sooner or later…will be adopted in the United States.” The Picayune explained that strike insurance “has not yet been adopted in the United States” before reciting the same arguments it had while covering the Employers’ Underwriters at Reciprocal Exchange’s rise and fall.Footnote 112 Other American commentators displayed better institutional memory but still discussed strike insurance with eyes trained attentively on Germany.Footnote 113

One need not have focused on the American experience to see cracks appearing in the case for strike insurance. More attentive observers may have encountered hints that the German experience had failed to dissolve class conflict. In 1907, the Eastern Underwriter relayed statistics of “peculiar interest” to strike insurance advocates—American’s consul in Chemnitz had shared data on a flurry of strikes and lockouts in Germany that year.Footnote 114 And, strike insurance was stoking class conflict rather than dissolving it. Confirming the worries of NAM’s Committee on Resolutions chair, the Socialist Labor Party of America used a 1910 consular report’s account of German strike insurance to stoke class consciousness.Footnote 115

Nevertheless, there was a reason many American journalists and businessmen drew optimism from Germany’s experience. There, strike insurers had overcome manifold obstacles to become a notable presence in their nation’s economy. By 1908, German trade journals could report that “Thirteen strike-insurance organizations have become known…. Among them stand two reinsurance institutions,” the members of which “together employ 775,825 workers.” At the time, firms employing hundreds of thousands of additional German workers insured themselves against strike damage through other channels.Footnote 116 These numbers continued their steady growth. By the World War I, 72,121 German employers had purchased insurance against strikes by 3,081,551 workers—63.7 percent of those employed in their sectors.Footnote 117 Unsurprisingly, American manufacturers were not the only businessmen inspired by this. Throughout the decade, commentary from all corners of Europe invoked German experiences with hope that strike insurance might restore liberal-individualist labor markets.Footnote 118

Ironically, Germany’s much-touted strike insurers actually followed a business model much closer to American trade associations’ under-the-radar strike aid than to the Mutual Security Company’s ambitious attempt to offer commercial strike insurance across industry and locality. They bore names like “Corporation of the Westphalian Cigar Manufacturers’ Association for Compensation in the Event of Work Stoppages.” These names reflected close connections to trade associations or local employers’ groups—connections that contemporary commentators contended gave them a “firm backbone,” avoided “the diversity of risks [that] lead to [underwriting] difficulties,” and ensured decisions reflected “sufficient expertise.” One even declared strike insurance “can only emerge from the womb of an employers’ association.”Footnote 119 Underwriting on this limited scale, however, came with constraints. A strike in Crimmitschau lasting from August 1903 to January 1904 saddled the Association of Employers in the Saxon Textile Industry with 1,250,000ℳ in strike insurance payments, dramatizing the possibility that a strike could overwhelm industry- and locality-specific underwriters like an inferno overwhelming a fire underwriter with policyholders concentrated in one city. Within months, this experience had prompted German employers to establish two nationwide organizations that reinsured strike hazard—strengthening the system that sparked American entrepreneurs’ imaginations until the Nazi regime dissolved the nation’s labor unions and trade associations in 1933.Footnote 120

Though two companies would repeat the Mutual Security Company’s failure on a far grander scale around World War I, Germans’ actual experience proved indicative of the direction America’s enduring strike insurance efforts would take.Footnote 121 They quietly offered mutual aid within a single industry. For example, union allegations that the American Newspaper Publishers Association offered strike insurance only received confirmation during an eighty-day strike against the Seattle Times in 1953. The Association, another newspaperman would explain, maintained “a fund…from which each subscriber is entitled to draw benefits” during labor disputes. It held “three different layers” of excess loss reinsurance. Similar schemes operated among California farmers, Hawaiian sugar-planters, and the oligopolistic rubber industry, while heavily regulated transportation industries pursued strike insurance more openly.Footnote 122 Some would take legal forms, involve Bahamian insurance companies, or reinsure through Lloyds, but each represented a trade association’s attempt to provide mutual aid during labor disputes in which actuarial ideals remained secondary concerns. In short, the National Founders’ Association and other trade groups quietly offering mutual strike aid—not the Mutual Security Company—pioneered the path taken by America’s enduring strike insurance projects.

Though America’s early twentieth-century strike insurance discourse yielded few tangible results, it offers a key window into the anxieties of the era’s business community and the toolbox with which it sought to mitigate them. Although surely at least partially self-serving, the argument that strike insurance would merely check organized labor’s growing power reflected unions’ growing role in the labor market. Small- and medium-sized manufacturers, committed by both ideology and self-interest to the idealized natural law of the market, viewed this as a pernicious and coercive encroachment on that ideal. Worse still, they believed this encroachment would benefit the new corporate behemoths whose scale self-insured against labor activism. Commercial strike insurance’s prominence among their proposed solutions—even as they quietly organized trade association mutual aid—is notable. Unlike mutual aid, it framed cooperation as commercial exchange, carrying “No taint of illegal combination” and allowing liberal-individualist employers to escape the paradox of attacking scale via scale.Footnote 123

More fundamentally, calls for strike insurance reflected underwriters’ cultural triumph, placing “Insurance terms…on the lips of men [even] when they are not thinking of the organized business insurance.”Footnote 124 Following decades of effort by life insurers, Americans attributed extraordinary power to quantification and actuarial science—prompting experimental risk-making projects from plate glass insurance to credit insurance. Yet, in the case of strike insurance, this faith stood on shaky ground—leaving interested businessmen grappling with its limits. Though strike insurance’s manufacturer adherents displayed little understanding of the underwriting on which they increasingly depended, those who attempted to realize it necessarily entered crash courses in the field. They quickly discovered that information problems would complicate their efforts—the human action and fuzzy causality behind labor strife would limit their ability to classify strike hazards and quantify risks actuarially. Faced with this classification problem, the Mutual Security Company embraced a “preferred risk system” that set aside actuarial ratemaking to charge all policyholders deemed acceptable risks a uniform premium rate determined by the loss ratio.Footnote 125 Though it sidestepped the ratemaking problem, this solution paradoxically erased the particularities that prompted it, contributing to the Mutual’s collapse under the weight of adverse selection and moral hazard.

This collapse holds wider historiographical significance. It highlights the limits of quantification and actuarial science that dogged would-be underwriters who stepped beyond the well-trod ground of life and fire insurance. Recognizing these limits matters as scholars have increasingly made the rise of financial risk management a major theme in the history of American capitalism—based largely on studies of life insurance, the gold standard of insurability. This emphasis threatens to overstate the power of insurers’ probabilistic risk calculation. Uncovering the forgotten risk-making projects like strike insurance, where Americans grappled with the limits of insurability, thus represents a crucial corrective—recovering the ongoing significance of unclassifiable, unquantifiable uncertainty.

Footnotes

1. Boston Globe, Feb. 17, 1890, 1; Chicago Tribune, Feb. 17, 1890, 5. In the 1880s, American trade associations had quietly introduced mutual aid strike insurance schemes, which would have a substantial effect on labor struggles well into the twentieth century. Yet these small-scale nonactuarial efforts operated quietly and went largely unnoticed. Railway Age, July 3, 1903, 8; Bonnett, Employers’ Associations; Bonnett, History of Employers’ Associations; Wiebe, Search for Order, 78; Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance.” For the Westphalian strike insurance scheme, which ironically paralleled American mutual aid efforts more closely than commercial insurance: Przigoda, “Entwicklung.”

2. Following Dan Bouk, this paper uses “risk-making” to refer to risk’s commoditization by selling insurance policies—not making the world more dangerous. Bouk, How Our Days, xx.

3. Mohun, Risk. For the development of forecasting: Friedman, Fortune Tellers; Pietruska, Looking Forward.

4. Farber, Underwriters. Though some American life insurers had earlier origins, their growth began in earnest with the Jacksonian Era. Murphy, Investing in Life; Levy, Freaks of Fortune; Thornton, Bowditch.

5. Murphy, Investing in Life; Madison, “Evolution of Commercial Credit Reporting;” Olegario, Culture of Credit; Lipartito, “Mediating Reputation;” Lauer, Creditworthy.

6. Murphy, Investing in Life. For the rise of numeracy and statistical thinking: Cohen, Calculating People; Porter, Rise of Statistical Thinking; Daston, Classical Probability; Gigerenzer et al., Empire of Chance; Hacking, Taming of Chance; Porter, Trust in Numbers; Alborn and Murphy, Anglo-American Life Insurance.

7. Gilded Age life insurers faced criticism of their economic power and financial crises founded in bad investments, but these challenges belied the maturity of their risk-making project. Keller, Life Insurance Enterprise; Grant, Insurance Reform; Wright and Smith, Mutually Beneficial; Murphy, Investing in Life; Levy Freaks of Fortune; Bouk, How Our Days.

8. Wright and Smith, Mutually Beneficial; Murphy, Investing in Life; Bouk, How Our Days.

9. Bouk, How Our Days; Horan, Insurance Era. In this, they have built on Alborn, Regulated Lives.

10. While recent work has focused primarily on life insurance, business historians have occasionally addressed nineteenth-century fire insurance or health insurance’s evolution since the Great Depression. Grant, Insurance Reform; Baranoff, “Principals, Agents, and Control;” Baranoff, “Shaped by Risk;” Baranoff, “Policy of Cooperation;” Chapin, Ensuring America’s Health. Chapin’s work joined that of legal and economic historians examining America’s workmen’s compensation and health insurance systems: Thomasson, “From Sickness to Health;” Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State; Witt, Accidental Republic; Murray, Origins of American Health Insurance. Another exception is work highlighting the reconsideration of risk’s social character in early attempts at consumer-facing automobile liability insurance. Mohun, Risk; Horan, Insurance Era; Simon, “Driving Governmentality;” Kaminski, “Kaminski on Kinzler, Highway Robbery.” The historiography, however, has continued to treat life insurance as normative with these exceptions largely reinforcing narratives treating probabilistic quantification as a dominant theme in the development of modern capitalism.

11. Arrow, “Alternative Approaches,” 417, 435; Alchian, “Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory;” Hodgson, “Eclipse of the Uncertainty Concept;” Schliesser, “What Happened to Knightian (and Keynesian) Uncertainty.” Even practitioners of such stochastic models like Lars Peter Hansen have increasingly highlighted the dangers of collapsing uncertainty into risk. Hansen, “Challenges;” Hansen, “Uncertainty Outside and Inside Economic Models.”

12. Chandler, Visible Hand; Levenstein, Accounting for Growth; Cook, Pricing of Progress; Zakim, Accounting for Capitalism.

13. Wilensky, “The Professionalization of Everyone;” Bledstein, Culture of Professionalism; Larson, Rise of Professionalism; Nelson, Frederick W. Taylor; Haskell, Authority of Experts; Abbott, System of Professions; Kimball, Professional Ideal.

14. McCall, Review of Life Insurance, 15, 36.

15. Baranoff, “Shaped by Risk,” 208–212; Baranoff, “Policy of Cooperation.”

16. National Association of Life Underwrites, Proceedings, 82–83.

17. Bouk, How Our Days; American Industries, Oct. 1, 1903, 13–14.

18. Perlman and Taft, History of Labor; Wiebe, Businessmen and Reform, 157–178; Montgomery, Fall; Scranton, Figured Tapestry; Watts, Order Against Chaos; Ernst, Lawyers Against Labor; Andrews, Killing for Coal; Currarino, Labor Question; Pearson, Reform or Repression; Hulden, The Bosses’ Union; Batzell, Organizing Workers.

19. Knight, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, 249–250.

20. Hossfeld, “Strike Insurance,” 62.

21. Lamoreaux, Great Merger Movement, 188; McCraw, Prophets of Regulation.

22. Chandler, Visible Hand; Chandler, Scale and Scope; Sawyer, American Fair Trade.

23. Rosenbloom, “Tables Ba4783–4791 and Ba4954–4964.”

24. Hossfeld, “Strike Insurance,” 62.

25. Hossfeld, “Strike Insurance,” 62.

26. Arbeiter-Zeitung, Nov. 30, 1900, 8; Soziale Praxis, Dec. 20, 1900, 287.

27. Chicago Tribune, Nov. 9, 1900, 6; San Francisco Chronicle, Nov. 24, 1900, 6; Scientific American, Dec. 22, 1900, 39; Wall Street Journal, Nov. 6, 1900, 5; Washington Post, Dec. 9, 1900, 24.

28. Insurance Times, Dec. 1900, 427; Insurance Press, June 5, 1901, 13.

29. Commercial and Financial Chronicle, July 4, 1903, 7.

30. Manchester Guardian, Feb. 24, 1890, 4.

31. Insurance Times, Dec. 1900, 427.

32. Chicago Tribune, March 1, 1890, 4.

33. The ontological boundary between Knight’s concepts of risk and uncertainty remains a subject of debate, but there is more consensus on insurability. Knight, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit; LeRoy and Singell, “Knight on Risk and Uncertainty;” Boudreaux and Holcombe, “Coasian and Knightian Theories;” Langlois and Cosgel, “Frank Knight on Risk, Uncertainty, and the Firm.”

34. Commercial and Financial Chronicle, July 4, 1903, 7. Analyzing the origins of entrepreneurial profit was a major fixation of turn-of-the-century American economists. Despite ongoing disputes, they typically agreed that profit represented a firm’s “unpredetermined residue” after receiving variable revenues and paying fixed obligations. Kaminski, “Managers of Uncertainty,” 66–121.

35. The Spectator, Sept. 4, 1902, 100. These reports proved premature. Three years later the Viennese scheme still awaited the 250 applicants needed to start operations—a goal it would never meet. Wochenschrift des Centralvereines für Rübenzucker-Industrie, Feb. 14, 1906, 79.

36. The Nation, Sept. 4, 1902, 184.

37. Alborn, Regulated Lives; Bouk, How Our Days.

38. The Nation. Sept. 4, 1902, 184.

39. Chicago Tribune, Sept. 17, 1902, 12.

40. Age of Steel, Sept. 27, 1902, 14.

41. Neues Wiener Tagblatt, Jan. 25, 1902, 11.

42. For full reprints of the editorial: Public Opinion, Sept. 18, 1902, 366; Bulletin of the National Metal Trades Association, Dec. 1, 1902, 234–235. This article includes a small trade publication–skewed sample of press building on the Nation’s editorial.

43. The Nation, Sept. 4, 1902, 184.

44. Zelizer, Morals and Markets, 131–135; Beito, From Mutual Aid to the Welfare State; Kaufman, For the Common Good?; Witt, Accidental Republic, 71–102; Levy, Freaks of Fortune, 191–230.

45. Glenn, “Fraternal Rhetoric;” Kaufman, For the Common Good.

46. Beito, From Mutual Aid to the Welfare State, 130–142; Kaufman, For the Common Good; Witt, Accidental Republic, 92–93; Levy, Freaks of Fortune, 224–230. Friendly societies’ sickness and accident benefits proved comparatively more stable as their relatively homogenous risk pools, ritualized socialization, and bundled benefits helped avert adverse selection and moral hazard. Emery and Emery, Young Man’s Benefit.

47. Kaminski, “Managers of Uncertainty,” 16–65.

48. The Nation, Sept. 4, 1902, 184.

49. Insurance Press, Sept. 10, 1902, 6.

50. The Spectator, Oct. 9, 1902, 162.

51. Die Arbeit, Nov. 18, 1900, 2; Insurance Monitor, June 1903, 252.

52. National Association of Life Underwriters, Proceedings, 82–83.

53. The Underwriters Review, June 12, 1903, 238.

54. NAM, Proceedings of the Eighth Annual Convention, 142.

55. Perlman and Taft, History of Labor, 129–137; Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance,” 483–490.

56. NAM, Proceedings of the Eighth Annual Convention, 15–62, 142; Parry, Scarlet Empire.

57. New York Times, May 13, 1903, 1.

58. American Industries, Nov. 2, 1903, 11.

59. Commercial and Financial Chronicle, July 4, 1903, 7; Insurance Monitor, July 1903, 300; Oct. 1903, 432.

60. Western Underwriter, Nov. 19, 1903, 7.

61. The Mutual’s founding leadership including three men with insurance experience might appear an exception. Yet manufacturer Robert Foote Griggs was its director and he—with other manufacturers—took an increasing share of its leadership over time. Moreover, its officials with insurance experience all acquired it as customer-facing insurance agents—not acturies or claims adjusters—and mingled this work with manufacturing and banking interests. For example, George Judd’s “interests [were]…broad and varied.” “Aside from his banking and real estate interests,” he was “president and treasurer of the Mattatuck Manufacturing Company which he established…for the manufacture of upholstery hardware.” Louis van Keuren—the Mutual’s president and public voice in its early years—similarly mingled financial, industrial, and political pursuits. The Successful American, Nov. 1901, 627; Special Acts and Resolutions, 181–183; Western Underwriter, Nov. 26, 1903, 10; New York Times, May 13, 1903, 1; Monthly Journal of Insurance Economics, July 1903, 85; Best’s Insurance Reports, Eleventh Annual Edition, 424; Pape, History of Waterbury, 3:86.

62. Strike insurance advocates like David Parry oft represented firms stretching the definition of SMEs yet embodied the ethos of small business proprietorship rather than large managerial capital. Parry’s company built the “largest buggy works in the world” shortly before his 1902 election as NAM president—inaugurating his role as a liberal-individualist SME mouthpiece. Farm Implements, Dec. 28, 1901, 53; Wiebe, Businessmen and Reform; Delton, Industrialists; Hulden, The Bosses’ Union. While the Westphalian Mine Owners Association represented a cartel of some of Germany’s largest firms, the Viennese scheme sprung from the Federation of Austrian Industrialists—an association formed in 1896 to represent SMEs. Przigoda, “Entwicklung;” Bruckmüller and Meixner, “Wiener Wirtschaftsbürgertum,” 361. Likewise, the SME-oriented Federation of German Employers’ Associations—rather than the heavy industry–dominated Main Office of German Employers’ Associations—took the lead reinforcing Germany’s strike insurance infrastructure following the infamous 1903–1904 Crimmitschau strike. Germann, Streik-Versicherung, 17–21; Kuo, “Political Origins,” 96–204.

63. Springfield Republican, April 30, 1903, 10; The Standard, June 12, 1903, 548; Monthly Journal of Insurance Economics, July 1903, 85.

64. After leaving brass, Griggs embarked on a successful investment-brokerage career but remained director of several Waterbury manufacturers. Anderson, Town and City of Waterbury, 404; Sherrill, Yale College, 168–169; Pape, History of Waterbury, 213.

65. Railway Age, June 12, 1903, 980.

66. Railway Age, July 3, 1903, 7–8.

67. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 148–149.

68. There were exceptions, such as a St.-Louis manufacturer who could “not see how an organization could be perfected or how calculations for revenue could be made.” Railway Age, July 3, 1903, 7–8.

69. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 124–128.

70. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 146.

71. That is, Fay and his contemporaries expected strike insurance to counter unions’ divide-and-conquer whipsaw strikes. Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance.” Austrian businessmen had articulated a similar understanding before proposing the Viennese scheme. Die Arbeit, July 8, 1900, 4029.

72. Clark, “Insurance and Business Profit,” 51–52.

73. Railway Age, June 12, 1903, 980; Insurance Monitor, June 1903, 252.

74. Chicago Inter-Ocean, Nov. 23, 1887, 7; Insurance Press, Sept. 10, 1902, 6.

75. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 127.

76. Chad Pearson has complicated this contrast but cautioned against understating tensions between NAM and NCF’s labor relations strategies. Bulletin of the National Metal Trades Association, Dec. 1, 1902, 234–235; Railway Age, July 3, 1903, 8–9; Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance;” Montgomery, Fall, 267–269; Pearson, Reform or Repression, 54–55, 243.

77. Insurance Monitor, July 1903, 300; Perlman and Taft, History of Labor, 129–137; Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance,” 483–490.

78. Foster suggested this as the reason behind trade associations’ secrecy about their strike insurance efforts, but Parry and others’ public stridency limits this argument’s plausibility. Fay’s celebration that commercial strike insurance carried “No taint of illegal combination,” however, suggests that legal strategizing following the Sherman Antitrust Act may have played a role. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 128; Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance.”

79. Railway Age, July 3, 1903, 8.

80. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 124–128, 161.

81. American Industries, Sept. 1, 1903, 1–2.

82. American Industries, Sept. 15, 1903, 3.

83. American Industries, Sept. 15, 1903, 3.

84. American Industries, Sept. 15, 1903, 3.

85. American Industries, Oct. 1, 1903, 13–14.

86. American Industries, Oct. 1, 1903, 13–14.

87. American Industries, Oct. 1, 1903, 13–14.

88. American Industries, Oct. 1, 1903, 13–14.

89. American Industries, Oct. 1, 1903, 13–14.

90. Bouk, How Our Days.

91. NAM, Proceedings of the Tenth Annual Convention, 190–194; Wall Street Journal, June 15, 1905, 1; Morning Olympian, June 26, 1906, 1.

92. The Spectator, Jan. 19, 1905, 34–35; State of Connecticut, Forty-Second Annual Report, 526–528.

93. Surety, Plate Glass and Miscellaneous Insurance, 59; Eastern Underwriter, Oct. 31, 1907, 15.

94. Commercial and Financial Chronicle, July 4, 1903, 7.

95. American Exchange and Review, Sept. 1905, 380.

96. “Assurance Mutuelle Contre la Grève,” 43–46; The Spectator, Jan. 19, 1905, 34–35; American Exchange and Review, Sept. 1905, 380.

97. The Chronicle, July 6, 1905, 9–10.

98. NAM, Proceedings of the Tenth Annual Convention, 190–194.

99. Fitchburg Sentinel, July 13, 1908, 2.

100. Buffalo Forge Company v. Mutual Security Company, 396–398.

101. The Iron Trade Review, March 30, 1905, 56.

102. Railway Age, July 3, 1903, 8–9; Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor, March 1904, 428–429.

103. Buffalo Forge Company v. Mutual Security Company, 397–398.

104. Buffalo Forge Company v. Mutual Security Company, 393–407; The Review, July 1906, 8–10; Pearson, Reform or Repression, 126–152.

105. Waterbury Evening Democrat, Feb. 5, 1908, 5; National Labor Tribune, Oct. 28, 1909, 4; Buffalo Forge Company v. Mutual Security Company, 393–407.

106. Buffalo Forge Company v. Mutual Security Company, 398, 406–407.

107. Pearson, Reform or Repression, 136.

108. Olegario, Culture of Credit; Lipartito, “Mediating Reputation;” Lauer, Creditworthy.

109. Life insurers followed a similar strategy until the 1880s rise of “incontestability” clauses guaranteeing claim payments—even in cases of suspected error or fraud. Thereafter, they relied on a specialized industry akin to credit reporters. Bouk, How Our Days, 64–68.

110. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 126; Washington Times, Feb. 25, 1903, 2; Bridgeport Evening Farmer, Jan. 8, 1914, 1.

111. Mutual Security Company v. Sidney Blumenthal & Company.

112. New Orleans Picayune, June 4, 1903, 2; July 15, 1903, 2; May 19, 1904, 9; Dec. 1, 1905, 16; Jan. 25, 1910, 8.

113. Daily People, Jan. 27, 1910, 4; Philadelphia Inquirer, March 13, 1910, 7; May 26, 1910, 6; The Spectator: Monthly Casualty and Survey Supplement, April 28, 1910, 15; Chicago Tribune, May 21, 1911, E4.

114. Eastern Underwriter, Oct. 31, 1907, 15.

115. Daily People, May 20, 1904, 1; New Orleans Picayune, May 20, 1904, 11; Daily People, Jan. 27, 1910, 4.

116. Tonindustrie-Zeitung, Nov. 27, 1909, 1575.

117. Monthly Review of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Oct. 1915, 82.

118. Wirtschaftspolitische Annalen, 1907, 408; Lefort, LAssurance; Rivista di Politica Economica, Nov. 1913, 365–368; Feb. 1914, 155–161.

119. Kulemann, Die Berufsvereine, 186; Germann, Streik-Versicherung, 16, 20.

120. St. Girons, L’Assurance Patronale, 149–150; Kulemann, Die Berufsvereine, 180–220; Germann, Streik-Versicherung; Sommer, Risiken des Arbeitskampfes, 252–271.

121. Standard Printing & Publishing v. Bothwell et al; Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance,” 492–496.

122. Foster, “Employers’ Strike Insurance,” 500, 512; Hirsch, “Strike Insurance and Collective Bargaining;” Unterberger and Koziara, “Airline Strike Insurance;” Unterberger and Koziara, “Demise of Airline Strike Insurance.”

123. NAM, Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention, 128.

124. National Association of Life Underwrites, Proceedings, 82–83.

125. American Industries, Oct. 1, 1903, 13–14.

References

Bibliography of Works Cited

Abbott, Andrew Delano. A System of Professions: An Essay on the Division of Expert Labor, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alborn, Timothy. Regulated Lives: Life Assurance and British Society, 1840-1920, Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alborn, Timothy, and Murphy, Sharon Ann. Anglo-American Life Insurance, 1800–1914, London: Pickering & Chatto, 2013.Google Scholar
Anderson, Joseph. The Town and City of Waterbury Connecticut, Vol. II. New Haven, CT: The Price & Lee Company, 1896.Google Scholar
Andrews, Thomas G. Killing for Coal: America’s Deadliest Labor War, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Batzell, Rudi. Organizing Workers in the Shadow of Slavery: Global Inequality, Racial Boundaries, and the Rise of Unions, 1870—1929, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2025.Google Scholar
Beito, David. From Mutual Aid to the Welfare State: Fraternal Societies and Social Services, 1890-1967, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Best’s Insurance Reports: Fire, Marine, and Miscellaneous , eleventh annual ed, New York: Alfred M. Best Company, 1910.Google Scholar
Bledstein, Burton J. The Culture of Professionalism: The Middle Class and the Development of Higher Education in America, New York: W.W. Norton & Co., 1976.Google Scholar
Bonnett, Clarence. Employers’ Associations in the United States: A Study of Typical Associations, New York: The Macmillan Company, 1922.Google Scholar
Bonnett, Clarence. History of Employers’ Associations in the United States, New York: Vantage Press, 1956.Google Scholar
Bouk, Dan. How Our Days Became Numbered: Risk and the Rise of the Statistical Individual, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. Jr. Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism, Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. Jr. The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business, Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Chapin, Christy Ford. Ensuring America’s Health: The Public Creation of the Corporate Health Care System, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, Patricia. A Calculating People: The Spread of Numeracy in Early America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Cook, Eli. The Pricing of Progress: Economic Indicators and the Capitalization of American Life, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currarino, Rosanne. The Labor Question in America: Economic Democracy in the Gilded Age, Urbana, Chicago, and Springfield: University of Illinois Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Daston, Lorraine. Classical Probability in the Enlightenment, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delton, Jennifer A. The Industrialists: How the National Association of Manufacturers Shaped American, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2020.Google Scholar
Emery, George Neil, and Emery, John Charles Herbert. A Young Man’s Benefit: The Independent Order of Odd Fellows and Sickness Insurance in the United States and Canada, 1860-1920, Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ernst, Daniel R. Lawyers Against Labor: From Individual Rights to Corporate Liberalism, Urbana and Chicago: University of Illinois Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Farber, Hannah. Underwriters of the United States: How Insurance Shaped the American Founding, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishback, Price, and Kantor, Shawn. Prelude to the Welfare State: The Origins of Workers’ Compensation, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Walter. Fortune Tellers: The Story of America’s First Economic Forecasters, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Germann, Georg. Die Streik-Versicherung in Deutschland und Frankreich, Bonn: M. Gladbach, 1910.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd, Swijtink, Zeno, Porter, Theodore, Daston, Lorraine, Beatty, John, and Kruger, Lorenz. The Empire of Chance: How Probability Changed Science and Everyday Life, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, H. Roger. Insurance Reform: Consumer Action in the Progressive Era, Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1979.Google Scholar
Hacking, Ian. The Taming of Chance, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haskell, Thomas L. The Authority of Experts: Studies in History and Theory, Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Horan, Caley. Insurance Era: Risk, Governance, and the Privatization of Security in Postwar America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hulden, Vilja. The Bosses’ Union: How Employers Organized to Fight Labor before the New Deal, Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 2023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, Jason. For the Common Good? American Civic Life and the Golden Age of Fraternity, New York: Oxford University Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, Morton. Regulating a New Economy: Policy Change and Economic Change in America, 1900-1933, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Kimball, Bruce A. The “True Professional Ideal” in America: A History, Cambridge, MA: Blackwell, 1992.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co., 1921.Google Scholar
Kulemann, Wilhelm. Die Berufsvereine, Vol. 3, Jena: Gustav Fischer, 1908.Google Scholar
Larson, Magali Sarfatti. The Rise of Professionalism: A Sociological Analysis, Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R. The Great Merger Movement in American Business, 1895-1904, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lauer, Josh. Creditworthy: A History of Consumer Surveillance and Financial Identity in America, New York: Columbia University Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lefort, Joseph Jean. LAssurance contre les Grèves, Paris: Fontemoing et Cie, 1911.Google Scholar
Levenstein, Margaret. Accounting for Growth: Information Systems and the Creation of the Large Corporation, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Levy, Jonathan. Freaks of Fortune: The Emerging World of Capitalism and Risk in America, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCall, John. A Review of Life Insurance from the Date of the First National Convention of Insurance Officials. 1871-1897, New York: n.p., 1898.Google Scholar
McCraw, Thomas. Prophets of Regulation, Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Mohun, Arwen. Risk: Negotiating Safety in American Society, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Montgomery, David. The Fall of the House of Labor, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, David. Workers Control in America, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1979.Google Scholar
Murphy, Sharon Ann. Investing in Life: Insurance in Antebellum America, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Murray, John. Origins of American Health Insurance: A History of Industrial Sickness Funds, New Haven, CT: Yale Univeristy Press, 2007.Google Scholar
National Association of Life Underwriters. Proceedings of the Thirteenth Annual Convention, Grand Hotel, Cincinnati, O., October 15, 16, and 17, 1902, Boston: The Standard Publishing Co., 1902.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Proceedings of the Eighth Annual Convention of the National Association of Manufacturers of the United States of America Held at New Orleans, La., April 14, 15, and 16, 1903, n.p., 1903.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention of the National Association of Manufacturers of the United States of America Held at Pittsburg, Pa., May 17, 18, and 19, 1904, New York: n.p., 1904.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Proceedings of the Tenth Annual Convention of the National Association of Manufacturers of the United States of America, Held at Atlanta, Ga., May 16, May 17, and May 18, 1905, New York: n.p., 1905.Google Scholar
Nelson, Daniel. Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Olegario, Rowena. A Culture of Credit: Embedding Trust and Transparency in American Business, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pape, William J. History of Waterbury and the Naugatuck Valley, Chicago: S.J. Clarke Publishing Company, 1918.Google Scholar
Parry, David M. The Scarlet Empire, Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1906.Google Scholar
Pearson, Chad. Reform or Repression: Organizing America’s Anti-Union Movement, Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania, 2015.Google ScholarPubMed
Perlman, Selig, and Taft, Philip. History of Labor in the United States, Vol. IV, New York: The Macmillan Company, 1935.Google Scholar
Pietruska, Jamie. Looking Forward: Prediction and Uncertainty in Modern America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Theodore. The Rise of Statistical Thinking, 1820-1900, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Theodore. Trust in Numbers: The Pursuit of Objectivity in Science and Public Life, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Sawyer, Laura Phillips. American Fair Trade: Proprietary Capitalism, Corporatism, and the ‘New Competition,’ 1890-1940, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Scranton, Philip. Figured Tapestry: Production, Markets, and Power in Philadelphia Textiles, 1885-1941, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Sherrill, Charles Hitchcock. Yale College, Yale University, Class of ’89 Quindecennial, New Haven, CT: The Tuttle, Morehouse & Taylor Company, 1904.Google Scholar
Sommer, Torsten. Risiken des Arbeitskampfes und Versicherungsschutz: Grundlagen einer Streikversicherung moderner Prägung, Tübingen, Germany: Mohr Siebeck, 2017.Google Scholar
Special Acts and Resolutions Passed by the General Assembly of the State of Connecticut at the January Session , 1903, Hartford, CT: Case, Lockwood & Brainard, 1903.Google Scholar
The Spectator Company. Surety, Plate Glass and Miscellaneous Insurance: A Manual, New York: The Spectator Company, 1908.Google Scholar
St. Girons, Pierre. L’Assurance Patronale Contre la Grève, Paris: L. Larose & L. Tenin, 1908.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fortieth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1904, Life, Accident, Casualty, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: Case, Lockwood, & Brainard Co., 1905.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-First Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1905, Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: Case, Lockwood, & Brainard Co., 1906.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Second Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1907 (Business of 1906), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: Case, Lockwood, & Brainard Co., 1907.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Third Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1908 (Business of 1907), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1908.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Fourth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1909 (Business of 1908), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1909.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Fifth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1910 (Business of 1909), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1910.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Sixth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1911 (Business of 1910), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1911.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Seventh Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1912 (Business of 1911), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1912.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Eighth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1913 (Business of 1912), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1913.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Ninth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1914 (Business of 1913), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1914.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fiftieth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1915 (Business of 1914), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1915.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fifty-First Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1916 (Business of 1915), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1916.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fifty-Second Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1917 (Business of 1916), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1917.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fifty-Third Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1918 (Business of 1917), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1918.Google Scholar
Thornton, Tamara Plakins. Nathaniel Bowditch and the Power of Numbers, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, Sarah Lyons. Order Against Chaos: Business Culture and Labor Ideology in America, Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Wiebe, Robert H. Businessmen and Reform: A Study of the Progressive Movement, Chicago: Ivan R. Dee, 1962/1989.Google Scholar
Wiebe, Robert H. The Search for Order, 1877-1920, New York: Hill and Wang, 1967.Google Scholar
Witt, John Fabian. The Accidental Republic: Crippled Workingmen, Destitute Widows, and the Remaking of American Law, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Robert, and Smith, George. Mutually Beneficial: The Guardian and Life Insurance in America, New York: New York University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Zakim, Michael. Accounting for Capitalism: The World the Clerk Made, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zelizer, Viviana A. Rotman. Morals and Markets: Development of Life Insurance in the United States, New York: Columbia University Press, 1979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, Armen. “Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory,” Journal of Political Economy 58, no. 3 (June 1950): 211221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth. “Alternative Approaches to the Theory of Choice in Risk-Taking Situations,” Econometrica 19, no. 4 (October 1951): 404437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Une Assurance Mutuelle Contre la Grève,” In Circulaires, 201-300, 4346. Paris: Comité Central des Armateurs de France, 1905.Google Scholar
Baranoff, Dalit. “A Policy of Cooperation,” Financial History Review 10, no. 2 (October 2003): 119136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baranoff, Dalit. “Principals, Agents, and Control in the American Fire Insurance Industry,” Business and Economic History 27, no. 1 (Fall 1998): 91101.Google Scholar
Baranoff, Dalit. “Shaped by Risk: The American Fire Insurance Industry, 1790-1920,” Ph.D. Diss., Johns Hopkins University, 2003.Google Scholar
Boudreaux, Donald and Holcombe, Randall. “The Coasian and Knightian Theories of the Firm,” Managerial and Decision Economics 10, no. 2 (June 1989): 147154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruckmüller, Ernst and Meixner, Wolfgang. “Wiener Wirtschaftsbürgertum,” in Wirtschaftsbürgertum in den Deutschen Staaten, ed. Möckl, Karl, 343374. Munich: Harland Boldt Verlag, 1996.Google Scholar
Clark, John Bates. “Insurance and Business Profit,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 7, no. 1 (October 1892): 4054.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, Harold. “Employers Strike Insurance,” Labor History 12, no. 4 (Fall 1971): 483529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glenn, Brian. “Fraternal Rhetoric and the Development of the U.S. Welfare State,” Studies in American Political Development 15, no. 2 (Fall 2001): 220233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Lars Peter. “Challenges in Identifying and Measuring Systemic Risk,” in Risk Topography, ed. Brunnermeier, Markus and Krishnamurthy, Arvind, 1530. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Hansen, Lars Peter. “Uncertainty Outside and Inside Economic Models,” Journal of Political Economy 122, no. 5 (October 2014): 945987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, John S.Strike Insurance and Collective Bargaining,” ILR Review 22, no. 3 (April 1969): 399415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey. “The Eclipse of the Uncertainty Concept in Mainstream Economics,” Journal of Economic Issues 45, no. 1 (March 2011): 159175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hossfeld, Frederick. “Strike Insurance in Austria,” in U.S. Congress. House of Representatives. Consular Reports: Commerce, Manufactures, Etc., Vol. 65, No. 244 (Jan. 1901), 56th Cong., 2d sess., 1901, H. Doc. 240-4140, 62.Google Scholar
Kaminski, Robert. “Managers of Uncertainty: Labor, Finance, and America’s Corporate Consolidation, 1885-1907,” Ph.D. Diss., University of Chicago, 2020.Google Scholar
Kaminski, Robert. “Kaminski on Kinzler, Highway Robbery: The Two-Decade Battle to Reform America’s Automobile Insurance System,” H-Sci-Med-Tech (September 2022).Google Scholar
Kuo, Alexander. “Political Origins of Firm Strategies,” PhD Diss., Stanford University, 2010.Google Scholar
Langlois, Richard, and Cosgel, Metin. “Frank Knight on Risk, Uncertainty, and the Firm,” Economic Inquiry 31, no. 3 (July 1993): 456465.Google Scholar
LeRoy, Stephen and Singell, Larry. “Knight on Risk and Uncertainty,” Journal of Political Economy 95, no. 2 (April 1987): 394406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipartito, Kenneth. “Mediating Reputation: Credit Reporting Systems in American History,” Business History Review 87, no. 4 (Winter 2013): 655677.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madison, James H.The Evolution of Commercial Credit Reporting Agencies in Nineteenth-Century America,” Business History Review 48, no. 2 (Summer 1974): 164186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przigoda, Stefan. “Zur Entwicklung der Arbeitgeberverbände im Ruhrbergbau,” Mitteilungsblatt des Instituts zur Erforschung der europäischen Arbeiterbewegung 18 (1997): 112141.Google Scholar
Rosenbloom, Joshua L. Tables Ba4783–4791 and Ba4954–4964,“ in Historical Statistics of the United States, Millennial Edition, eds. Carter, Susan B., Gartner, Scott Sigmund, Haines, Michael R., Olmstead, Alan L., Sutch, Richard, and Wright, Gavin. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Schliesser, Eric. “What Happened to Knightian (and Keynesian) Uncertainty Post WWII?” SSRN Electronic Journal (April 2012).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Jonathan. “Driving Governmentality: Automobile Accidents, Insurance, and the Challenge to Social Order in the Inter-War Years, 1919 to 1941,” Connecticut Insurance Law Journal 4 (1997–1998): 521588.Google Scholar
Thomasson, Melissa Anne. “From Sickness to Health,” Ph.D. Diss., University of Arizona, 1998.Google Scholar
Unterberger, S. Herbert, and Koziara, Edward C.. “Airline Strike Insurance: A Study in Escalation,” ILR Review 29, no. 1 (October 1975): 2645.Google Scholar
Unterberger, S. Herbert, and Koziara, Edward C.. “The Demise of Airline Strike Insurance,” ILR Review 34, no. 1 (October 1980): 8289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilensky, Harold L.The Professionalization of Everyone?American Journal of Sociology 70, no. 2 (September 1964): 137158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Age of Steel Google Scholar
American Exchange and Review Google Scholar
American Industries Google Scholar
Die Arbeit Google Scholar
Arbeiter-Zeitung Google Scholar
Boston Globe Google Scholar
Bridgeport Evening Farmer Google Scholar
Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor Google Scholar
Bulletin of the National Metal Trades Association Google Scholar
Chicago Inter-Ocean Google Scholar
Chicago Tribune Google Scholar
The Chronicle: A Weekly Insurance Journal Google Scholar
Commercial and Financial Chronicle Google Scholar
Daily People Google Scholar
Eastern Underwriter Google Scholar
Farm Implements Google Scholar
Fitchburg Sentinel Google Scholar
Insurance Monitor Google Scholar
Insurance Press Google Scholar
Insurance Times Google Scholar
The Iron Trade Review Google Scholar
Manchester Guardian Google Scholar
Monthly Journal of Insurance Economics Google Scholar
Monthly Review of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Google Scholar
Morning Olympian Google Scholar
The Nation Google Scholar
National Labor Tribune Google Scholar
Neues Wiener Tagblatt Google Scholar
New Orleans Picayune Google Scholar
New York Times Google Scholar
Philadelphia Inquirer Google Scholar
Public Opinion Google Scholar
Railway Age Google Scholar
The Review Google Scholar
Rivista di Politica Economica Google Scholar
San Francisco Chronicle Google Scholar
Scientific American Google Scholar
Soziale Praxis Google Scholar
The Spectator Google Scholar
Springfield Republican Google Scholar
The Standard Google Scholar
The Successful American Google Scholar
Tonindustrie-Zeitung Google Scholar
The Underwriters Review Google Scholar
Wall Street Journal Google Scholar
Washington Post Google Scholar
Washington Times Google Scholar
Waterbury Evening Democrat Google Scholar
Western Underwriter Google Scholar
Wirtschaftspolitische Annalen Google Scholar
Wochenschrift des Centralvereines für Rübenzucker-Industrie Google Scholar
Buffalo Forge Company v. Mutual Security Company, 76 A. 995, 83 Conn. 393 (Conn., 1910).Google Scholar
Mutual Security Company v. Sidney Blumenthal & Company, 86 A. 573, 86 Conn. 667 (Conn., 1913).Google Scholar
Standard Printing & Publishing Co. v. Bothwell et al, 122 A. 195 (Md. Ct. App., 1923).Google Scholar
Abbott, Andrew Delano. A System of Professions: An Essay on the Division of Expert Labor, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alborn, Timothy. Regulated Lives: Life Assurance and British Society, 1840-1920, Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alborn, Timothy, and Murphy, Sharon Ann. Anglo-American Life Insurance, 1800–1914, London: Pickering & Chatto, 2013.Google Scholar
Anderson, Joseph. The Town and City of Waterbury Connecticut, Vol. II. New Haven, CT: The Price & Lee Company, 1896.Google Scholar
Andrews, Thomas G. Killing for Coal: America’s Deadliest Labor War, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Batzell, Rudi. Organizing Workers in the Shadow of Slavery: Global Inequality, Racial Boundaries, and the Rise of Unions, 1870—1929, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2025.Google Scholar
Beito, David. From Mutual Aid to the Welfare State: Fraternal Societies and Social Services, 1890-1967, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Best’s Insurance Reports: Fire, Marine, and Miscellaneous , eleventh annual ed, New York: Alfred M. Best Company, 1910.Google Scholar
Bledstein, Burton J. The Culture of Professionalism: The Middle Class and the Development of Higher Education in America, New York: W.W. Norton & Co., 1976.Google Scholar
Bonnett, Clarence. Employers’ Associations in the United States: A Study of Typical Associations, New York: The Macmillan Company, 1922.Google Scholar
Bonnett, Clarence. History of Employers’ Associations in the United States, New York: Vantage Press, 1956.Google Scholar
Bouk, Dan. How Our Days Became Numbered: Risk and the Rise of the Statistical Individual, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. Jr. Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism, Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. Jr. The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business, Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Chapin, Christy Ford. Ensuring America’s Health: The Public Creation of the Corporate Health Care System, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, Patricia. A Calculating People: The Spread of Numeracy in Early America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Cook, Eli. The Pricing of Progress: Economic Indicators and the Capitalization of American Life, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currarino, Rosanne. The Labor Question in America: Economic Democracy in the Gilded Age, Urbana, Chicago, and Springfield: University of Illinois Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Daston, Lorraine. Classical Probability in the Enlightenment, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delton, Jennifer A. The Industrialists: How the National Association of Manufacturers Shaped American, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2020.Google Scholar
Emery, George Neil, and Emery, John Charles Herbert. A Young Man’s Benefit: The Independent Order of Odd Fellows and Sickness Insurance in the United States and Canada, 1860-1920, Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 1999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ernst, Daniel R. Lawyers Against Labor: From Individual Rights to Corporate Liberalism, Urbana and Chicago: University of Illinois Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Farber, Hannah. Underwriters of the United States: How Insurance Shaped the American Founding, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishback, Price, and Kantor, Shawn. Prelude to the Welfare State: The Origins of Workers’ Compensation, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Walter. Fortune Tellers: The Story of America’s First Economic Forecasters, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Germann, Georg. Die Streik-Versicherung in Deutschland und Frankreich, Bonn: M. Gladbach, 1910.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd, Swijtink, Zeno, Porter, Theodore, Daston, Lorraine, Beatty, John, and Kruger, Lorenz. The Empire of Chance: How Probability Changed Science and Everyday Life, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, H. Roger. Insurance Reform: Consumer Action in the Progressive Era, Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1979.Google Scholar
Hacking, Ian. The Taming of Chance, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haskell, Thomas L. The Authority of Experts: Studies in History and Theory, Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Horan, Caley. Insurance Era: Risk, Governance, and the Privatization of Security in Postwar America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hulden, Vilja. The Bosses’ Union: How Employers Organized to Fight Labor before the New Deal, Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 2023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, Jason. For the Common Good? American Civic Life and the Golden Age of Fraternity, New York: Oxford University Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, Morton. Regulating a New Economy: Policy Change and Economic Change in America, 1900-1933, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Kimball, Bruce A. The “True Professional Ideal” in America: A History, Cambridge, MA: Blackwell, 1992.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co., 1921.Google Scholar
Kulemann, Wilhelm. Die Berufsvereine, Vol. 3, Jena: Gustav Fischer, 1908.Google Scholar
Larson, Magali Sarfatti. The Rise of Professionalism: A Sociological Analysis, Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R. The Great Merger Movement in American Business, 1895-1904, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lauer, Josh. Creditworthy: A History of Consumer Surveillance and Financial Identity in America, New York: Columbia University Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lefort, Joseph Jean. LAssurance contre les Grèves, Paris: Fontemoing et Cie, 1911.Google Scholar
Levenstein, Margaret. Accounting for Growth: Information Systems and the Creation of the Large Corporation, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Levy, Jonathan. Freaks of Fortune: The Emerging World of Capitalism and Risk in America, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCall, John. A Review of Life Insurance from the Date of the First National Convention of Insurance Officials. 1871-1897, New York: n.p., 1898.Google Scholar
McCraw, Thomas. Prophets of Regulation, Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Mohun, Arwen. Risk: Negotiating Safety in American Society, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Montgomery, David. The Fall of the House of Labor, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, David. Workers Control in America, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1979.Google Scholar
Murphy, Sharon Ann. Investing in Life: Insurance in Antebellum America, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Murray, John. Origins of American Health Insurance: A History of Industrial Sickness Funds, New Haven, CT: Yale Univeristy Press, 2007.Google Scholar
National Association of Life Underwriters. Proceedings of the Thirteenth Annual Convention, Grand Hotel, Cincinnati, O., October 15, 16, and 17, 1902, Boston: The Standard Publishing Co., 1902.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Proceedings of the Eighth Annual Convention of the National Association of Manufacturers of the United States of America Held at New Orleans, La., April 14, 15, and 16, 1903, n.p., 1903.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention of the National Association of Manufacturers of the United States of America Held at Pittsburg, Pa., May 17, 18, and 19, 1904, New York: n.p., 1904.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Proceedings of the Tenth Annual Convention of the National Association of Manufacturers of the United States of America, Held at Atlanta, Ga., May 16, May 17, and May 18, 1905, New York: n.p., 1905.Google Scholar
Nelson, Daniel. Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Olegario, Rowena. A Culture of Credit: Embedding Trust and Transparency in American Business, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pape, William J. History of Waterbury and the Naugatuck Valley, Chicago: S.J. Clarke Publishing Company, 1918.Google Scholar
Parry, David M. The Scarlet Empire, Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1906.Google Scholar
Pearson, Chad. Reform or Repression: Organizing America’s Anti-Union Movement, Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania, 2015.Google ScholarPubMed
Perlman, Selig, and Taft, Philip. History of Labor in the United States, Vol. IV, New York: The Macmillan Company, 1935.Google Scholar
Pietruska, Jamie. Looking Forward: Prediction and Uncertainty in Modern America, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Theodore. The Rise of Statistical Thinking, 1820-1900, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Theodore. Trust in Numbers: The Pursuit of Objectivity in Science and Public Life, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Sawyer, Laura Phillips. American Fair Trade: Proprietary Capitalism, Corporatism, and the ‘New Competition,’ 1890-1940, New York: Cambridge University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Scranton, Philip. Figured Tapestry: Production, Markets, and Power in Philadelphia Textiles, 1885-1941, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Sherrill, Charles Hitchcock. Yale College, Yale University, Class of ’89 Quindecennial, New Haven, CT: The Tuttle, Morehouse & Taylor Company, 1904.Google Scholar
Sommer, Torsten. Risiken des Arbeitskampfes und Versicherungsschutz: Grundlagen einer Streikversicherung moderner Prägung, Tübingen, Germany: Mohr Siebeck, 2017.Google Scholar
Special Acts and Resolutions Passed by the General Assembly of the State of Connecticut at the January Session , 1903, Hartford, CT: Case, Lockwood & Brainard, 1903.Google Scholar
The Spectator Company. Surety, Plate Glass and Miscellaneous Insurance: A Manual, New York: The Spectator Company, 1908.Google Scholar
St. Girons, Pierre. L’Assurance Patronale Contre la Grève, Paris: L. Larose & L. Tenin, 1908.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fortieth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1904, Life, Accident, Casualty, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: Case, Lockwood, & Brainard Co., 1905.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-First Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1905, Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: Case, Lockwood, & Brainard Co., 1906.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Second Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1907 (Business of 1906), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: Case, Lockwood, & Brainard Co., 1907.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Third Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1908 (Business of 1907), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1908.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Fourth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1909 (Business of 1908), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1909.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Fifth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1910 (Business of 1909), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1910.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Sixth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1911 (Business of 1910), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1911.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Seventh Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1912 (Business of 1911), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1912.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Eighth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1913 (Business of 1912), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1913.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Forty-Ninth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1914 (Business of 1913), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1914.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fiftieth Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1915 (Business of 1914), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1915.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fifty-First Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1916 (Business of 1915), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1916.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fifty-Second Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1917 (Business of 1916), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1917.Google Scholar
State of Connecticut. Fifty-Third Annual Report of the Insurance Commissioner, for 1918 (Business of 1917), Life, Accident, Casualty, Fidelity, and Surety Companies, Part II, Hartford: State of Connecticut, 1918.Google Scholar
Thornton, Tamara Plakins. Nathaniel Bowditch and the Power of Numbers, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, Sarah Lyons. Order Against Chaos: Business Culture and Labor Ideology in America, Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Wiebe, Robert H. Businessmen and Reform: A Study of the Progressive Movement, Chicago: Ivan R. Dee, 1962/1989.Google Scholar
Wiebe, Robert H. The Search for Order, 1877-1920, New York: Hill and Wang, 1967.Google Scholar
Witt, John Fabian. The Accidental Republic: Crippled Workingmen, Destitute Widows, and the Remaking of American Law, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Robert, and Smith, George. Mutually Beneficial: The Guardian and Life Insurance in America, New York: New York University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Zakim, Michael. Accounting for Capitalism: The World the Clerk Made, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zelizer, Viviana A. Rotman. Morals and Markets: Development of Life Insurance in the United States, New York: Columbia University Press, 1979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, Armen. “Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory,” Journal of Political Economy 58, no. 3 (June 1950): 211221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth. “Alternative Approaches to the Theory of Choice in Risk-Taking Situations,” Econometrica 19, no. 4 (October 1951): 404437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Une Assurance Mutuelle Contre la Grève,” In Circulaires, 201-300, 4346. Paris: Comité Central des Armateurs de France, 1905.Google Scholar
Baranoff, Dalit. “A Policy of Cooperation,” Financial History Review 10, no. 2 (October 2003): 119136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baranoff, Dalit. “Principals, Agents, and Control in the American Fire Insurance Industry,” Business and Economic History 27, no. 1 (Fall 1998): 91101.Google Scholar
Baranoff, Dalit. “Shaped by Risk: The American Fire Insurance Industry, 1790-1920,” Ph.D. Diss., Johns Hopkins University, 2003.Google Scholar
Boudreaux, Donald and Holcombe, Randall. “The Coasian and Knightian Theories of the Firm,” Managerial and Decision Economics 10, no. 2 (June 1989): 147154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruckmüller, Ernst and Meixner, Wolfgang. “Wiener Wirtschaftsbürgertum,” in Wirtschaftsbürgertum in den Deutschen Staaten, ed. Möckl, Karl, 343374. Munich: Harland Boldt Verlag, 1996.Google Scholar
Clark, John Bates. “Insurance and Business Profit,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 7, no. 1 (October 1892): 4054.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, Harold. “Employers Strike Insurance,” Labor History 12, no. 4 (Fall 1971): 483529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glenn, Brian. “Fraternal Rhetoric and the Development of the U.S. Welfare State,” Studies in American Political Development 15, no. 2 (Fall 2001): 220233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Lars Peter. “Challenges in Identifying and Measuring Systemic Risk,” in Risk Topography, ed. Brunnermeier, Markus and Krishnamurthy, Arvind, 1530. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Hansen, Lars Peter. “Uncertainty Outside and Inside Economic Models,” Journal of Political Economy 122, no. 5 (October 2014): 945987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, John S.Strike Insurance and Collective Bargaining,” ILR Review 22, no. 3 (April 1969): 399415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey. “The Eclipse of the Uncertainty Concept in Mainstream Economics,” Journal of Economic Issues 45, no. 1 (March 2011): 159175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hossfeld, Frederick. “Strike Insurance in Austria,” in U.S. Congress. House of Representatives. Consular Reports: Commerce, Manufactures, Etc., Vol. 65, No. 244 (Jan. 1901), 56th Cong., 2d sess., 1901, H. Doc. 240-4140, 62.Google Scholar
Kaminski, Robert. “Managers of Uncertainty: Labor, Finance, and America’s Corporate Consolidation, 1885-1907,” Ph.D. Diss., University of Chicago, 2020.Google Scholar
Kaminski, Robert. “Kaminski on Kinzler, Highway Robbery: The Two-Decade Battle to Reform America’s Automobile Insurance System,” H-Sci-Med-Tech (September 2022).Google Scholar
Kuo, Alexander. “Political Origins of Firm Strategies,” PhD Diss., Stanford University, 2010.Google Scholar
Langlois, Richard, and Cosgel, Metin. “Frank Knight on Risk, Uncertainty, and the Firm,” Economic Inquiry 31, no. 3 (July 1993): 456465.Google Scholar
LeRoy, Stephen and Singell, Larry. “Knight on Risk and Uncertainty,” Journal of Political Economy 95, no. 2 (April 1987): 394406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipartito, Kenneth. “Mediating Reputation: Credit Reporting Systems in American History,” Business History Review 87, no. 4 (Winter 2013): 655677.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madison, James H.The Evolution of Commercial Credit Reporting Agencies in Nineteenth-Century America,” Business History Review 48, no. 2 (Summer 1974): 164186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przigoda, Stefan. “Zur Entwicklung der Arbeitgeberverbände im Ruhrbergbau,” Mitteilungsblatt des Instituts zur Erforschung der europäischen Arbeiterbewegung 18 (1997): 112141.Google Scholar
Rosenbloom, Joshua L. Tables Ba4783–4791 and Ba4954–4964,“ in Historical Statistics of the United States, Millennial Edition, eds. Carter, Susan B., Gartner, Scott Sigmund, Haines, Michael R., Olmstead, Alan L., Sutch, Richard, and Wright, Gavin. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Schliesser, Eric. “What Happened to Knightian (and Keynesian) Uncertainty Post WWII?” SSRN Electronic Journal (April 2012).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Jonathan. “Driving Governmentality: Automobile Accidents, Insurance, and the Challenge to Social Order in the Inter-War Years, 1919 to 1941,” Connecticut Insurance Law Journal 4 (1997–1998): 521588.Google Scholar
Thomasson, Melissa Anne. “From Sickness to Health,” Ph.D. Diss., University of Arizona, 1998.Google Scholar
Unterberger, S. Herbert, and Koziara, Edward C.. “Airline Strike Insurance: A Study in Escalation,” ILR Review 29, no. 1 (October 1975): 2645.Google Scholar
Unterberger, S. Herbert, and Koziara, Edward C.. “The Demise of Airline Strike Insurance,” ILR Review 34, no. 1 (October 1980): 8289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilensky, Harold L.The Professionalization of Everyone?American Journal of Sociology 70, no. 2 (September 1964): 137158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Age of Steel Google Scholar
American Exchange and Review Google Scholar
American Industries Google Scholar
Die Arbeit Google Scholar
Arbeiter-Zeitung Google Scholar
Boston Globe Google Scholar
Bridgeport Evening Farmer Google Scholar
Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor Google Scholar
Bulletin of the National Metal Trades Association Google Scholar
Chicago Inter-Ocean Google Scholar
Chicago Tribune Google Scholar
The Chronicle: A Weekly Insurance Journal Google Scholar
Commercial and Financial Chronicle Google Scholar
Daily People Google Scholar
Eastern Underwriter Google Scholar
Farm Implements Google Scholar
Fitchburg Sentinel Google Scholar
Insurance Monitor Google Scholar
Insurance Press Google Scholar
Insurance Times Google Scholar
The Iron Trade Review Google Scholar
Manchester Guardian Google Scholar
Monthly Journal of Insurance Economics Google Scholar
Monthly Review of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Google Scholar
Morning Olympian Google Scholar
The Nation Google Scholar
National Labor Tribune Google Scholar
Neues Wiener Tagblatt Google Scholar
New Orleans Picayune Google Scholar
New York Times Google Scholar
Philadelphia Inquirer Google Scholar
Public Opinion Google Scholar
Railway Age Google Scholar
The Review Google Scholar
Rivista di Politica Economica Google Scholar
San Francisco Chronicle Google Scholar
Scientific American Google Scholar
Soziale Praxis Google Scholar
The Spectator Google Scholar
Springfield Republican Google Scholar
The Standard Google Scholar
The Successful American Google Scholar
Tonindustrie-Zeitung Google Scholar
The Underwriters Review Google Scholar
Wall Street Journal Google Scholar
Washington Post Google Scholar
Washington Times Google Scholar
Waterbury Evening Democrat Google Scholar
Western Underwriter Google Scholar
Wirtschaftspolitische Annalen Google Scholar
Wochenschrift des Centralvereines für Rübenzucker-Industrie Google Scholar
Buffalo Forge Company v. Mutual Security Company, 76 A. 995, 83 Conn. 393 (Conn., 1910).Google Scholar
Mutual Security Company v. Sidney Blumenthal & Company, 86 A. 573, 86 Conn. 667 (Conn., 1913).Google Scholar
Standard Printing & Publishing Co. v. Bothwell et al, 122 A. 195 (Md. Ct. App., 1923).Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. The Mutual Security Company’s balance sheet, 1904-1917