Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T05:25:14.111Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The business of city-building. Long-term change and continuity in the construction sector (Brussels, 1830–1970)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 April 2024

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The construction sector has long been underrepresented in business historical studies and debates. While an application of the “historical alternatives to mass production” approach has provided a valuable conceptual framework, this paper offers a still-needed quantitative basis to assess actual long-term changes and continuities in the forms of business organization and entrepreneurship in construction. A database of c. 16,700 construction enterprises in Brussels between 1830 and 1970, drawn from trade directories and fiscal registers, uncovers evolutions in sectoral and subsectoral numbers of enterprises, firm sizes, and rates of company formation. Thus, the growing divergence at the core of the construction industry becomes clear. Industrialization and urbanization led to market concentration, firm growth, and incorporation with some capital-intensive enterprises, whereas the variability of the work on the construction site resulted, with many others, in the persistence of labor-intensive processes, and small-scale, flexible, and informal forms of business organization.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Business History Conference

Introduction

The construction industry, despite its importance in local economies around the world, has long been underrepresented in business historical studies and debates. In the twentieth century, a lack of perceived modernization led scholars and policymakers to deplore the industry’s alleged inefficiency and backwardness,Footnote 1 while ordinary construction enterprises were insufficiently analyzed within a business historical tradition dominated by Chandlerian views, in which internationalization and scaling up of business activities formed the principal long-term evolutions.Footnote 2

The focus was, as a result, on the few productivity gains and economies of scale that made their way into construction. Large contracting firms employing hundreds of workers were already active in public works in late seventeenth-century England,Footnote 3 but the nineteenth century was especially seen as a period of major change. Leading the way were contractors executing large-scale public works of road, railroad, and canal construction, where the straightforward and repetitive nature of the work enabled economies of scale, which, according to Chandler, promoted the formation of large-scale, hierarchically managed corporations.Footnote 4

Others stressed that these giants were not representative of most construction enterprises that remained organized on a small scale and local basis. Remarkable continuities were observed between the Ancien Régime,Footnote 5 and the industrial era, when construction remained highly fragmented. In the Netherlands, construction firms had an average of 5.4 workers, almost the lowest average workforce of all sectors in 1905.Footnote 6 In Belgium, the percentage of enterprises with fewer than 5 workers only slightly declined from 88 percent to 84 percent between 1890 and 1961, while the share of companies with more than 50 workers barely surpassed 1 percent.Footnote 7 In France, there were similarly only 1 percent of large companies in the second half of the twentieth century and a growing rate of enterprises with 1 to 5 workers: from 81 percent in 1954 to 85 percent in 1971.Footnote 8

As a result, it was argued that construction could not fit into the common long-run scheme of increasing mass production, nor could it aspire to accomplish it in the future. Instead, construction came in sight of historians working on the “other side of industrialization.”Footnote 9 The “historical alternatives to mass production” approach emerged in the mid-1980s with the key argument that the variability of demand could prevent mass production from taking over in certain industries, where producers’ specialized skills allowed them to flexibly adapt the volume and composition of output and rapidly introduce new products in response to shifts in demand and other changing circumstances.Footnote 10

Piore and Sabel mentioned construction in 1984 as the “first example of these counterprinciples in operation.”Footnote 11 In 2005, Harris and Buzzelli developed the idea into a business–historical conceptual framework for the construction sector. Drawing also on the work of economists writing on the current housing scene,Footnote 12 they argued that, in construction, economies of scale did not pay off when flexible specialization was required to address complex and differentiated working conditions. Builders always had to adapt to an unpredictable and unstable market determined by the idiosyncratic nature of construction demand and by differentiated submarkets of housing, commercial, and other types of infrastructure. This resulted in an industry consisting for the most of small-scale, transient, and volatile forms of entrepreneurship and business organization.Footnote 13

Scholarship on the business history of construction thus straddles 2 paths, with some interpreting construction as a prime example of “historical alternatives to mass production,”Footnote 14 while others stress the rise of innovative building technologies, productivity gains, and economies of scale in the sector.Footnote 15 This paper aims to bridge the gap between both strands of literature by providing a long-term analysis that quantifies the relative importance of both interpretations and how they changed over time. It questions to what extent the industry was indeed characterized by the persistent importance of flexible specialization and to what degree processes of firm growth, industrialization, and market concentration made their way into the construction sector.

To answer these questions, a quantitative empirical basis is required. This paper provides a long-term quantitative benchmark study for the construction sector using a database of 16,714 construction enterprises established in Brussels between 1830 and 1970. This approach is inspired by the recent work of Bennett et al., who studied ordinary and small-scale forms of entrepreneurship from a long-term quantitative perspective. Drawing on a database of over nine million English and Welsh entrepreneurs between 1851 and 1911, they advocated a broad definition of entrepreneurs as “those responsible for undertaking a business activity, responding to business opportunities by trying to meet or anticipate demand and organize supply, assembling factor inputs, achieving a return for their skills by successfully doing so, and bearing the risk if they failed.”Footnote 16 In this way, they reacted to narrower, Schumpeterian definitions of entrepreneurs as “those who innovate.”Footnote 17

Such a broad definition of entrepreneurship makes it possible to include the many self-employed sole proprietors running a construction business for their own account and at their own risk.Footnote 18 It yields new insights on how most businesses operate daily, and if and how that changed over time. Applying it to construction provides an excellent gateway to grasping the atypical historical position of the industry within the broader world of business and entrepreneurship. Ordinary entrepreneurs and their small-scale businesses form the cornerstone of the construction sector, about which too little is known.Footnote 19

The database makes it possible to address the research question on 3 levels. First, the relative number of enterprises (on 1,000 recently constructed buildings in the city) indicates the evolution of the extent to which the urban construction market was fragmented across many enterprises or concentrated within the hands of fewer firms. Second, firm sizes (in terms of workforce numbers) indicate long-term changes in the importance of small-scale versus large-scale enterprises. Third, the role of capital needs is studied by looking at the changing rates of company formation, which made it possible to pool capital resources within larger, more capital-intensive firms.

Each level is assessed both for the industry as a whole and for its different constituent building trades, which point to widely varying levels of labor and capital intensity within the construction sector. Later research can enrich this picture by including other variables, such as the effects of the character and availability of finance on the organization of the industry. This paper aims to provide a first long-term quantitative benchmark study for the construction sector, based on evolutions in (relative) enterprise numbers, firm sizes, and rates of company formation.

The findings make clear that between 1830 and 1970, a divergence occurred at the core of the construction sector. The labor intensity of on-site building ensured that most of the construction market remained highly fragmented over large numbers of enterprises working on a small scale, whereas dynamics of consolidation and firm size growth increasingly characterized not only the trades where capital-intensive, mechanized shop-floor production processes made economies of scale possible but gradually and to a more limited extent affected several on-site building trades.

In the next section, I provide additional context on the particularities of construction and the construction sector, first in general and then focusing on Belgium and Brussels. Next, I explain the sources and methods used to compose the database of construction enterprises, followed by 3 levels of analysis for the long-term evolution of the construction sector: enterprise numbers, firm sizes, and company formation. Each of these sections is subdivided into an analysis of the construction sector as a whole and one that distinguishes between the different building trades.

Context: Building in Belgium and Brussels

Reflecting on the peculiar nature of construction and its fragmentation across many small-scale enterprises, several scholars have identified different causal dynamics.Footnote 20 According to Lacoste, they can be reduced to 3 atypical characteristics of the industry’s final product, buildings.Footnote 21

The magnitude of buildings ensures that they must be produced on-site, where unique production conditions result in few opportunities to achieve economies of scale. On-site work also implies a need for spatial proximity between supply and demand. Given the ubiquitous demand for housing and other types of built infrastructure, construction enterprises must be equally scattered. They form an essentially localized industry, as Whitehand argued,Footnote 22 and are a vital part of local economies in cities, towns, and often even villages across the world.Footnote 23

Second, industry fragmentation is promoted by the heterogeneity of buildings, which requires the work of various specialized building trades. For them, the need for flexibility and adaptation implies the use of labor-intensive production methods with low levels of mechanization. This, in turn, produces low requirements for (initial) capital input and poses a low threshold for market entry. With the right tools and knowhow, virtually anyone can establish their enterprise. This low capital intensity enables many small construction enterprises to be newly established but hinders the accumulation of capital within firms and their development into large companies.Footnote 24

Finally, the durability of buildings ensures that they represent long-term financial investments, which makes the demand for buildings volatile, and the building sector highly susceptible to economic trends. Prosperous times resulted in the formation of many new, small firms, whereas economic crises led to high transience and turnover rates.Footnote 25 This trend susceptibility also results in a flexible composition of the labor force. Firms can rapidly contract whenever necessary, and therefore rarely aim for long-term firm growth.Footnote 26 The volatility of demand also reduces opportunities for integrating workers of all building specialisms into a single enterprise, which produces a far-reaching division of labor and the prevalence of subcontracting work to small skill-specialist firms.Footnote 27

Taken together, these dynamics form a complex set of interacting forces that constrain firm growth and promote the small-scale organization of construction enterprises. It is also broadly observed in Belgium, a country that has benefited from a broad historical interest in the production of its built (urban) space. Specifically, with regard to the economic history of construction in nineteenth- and twentieth-century Belgium, the works of Vincent Duchêne and Erik Buyst are important. Focusing on the periods 1830–1890 and 1890–1961, they reconstructed figures of capital formation in residential construction and analyzed the causal dynamics behind these long-term evolutions. They included changes on the supply side of the construction market, such as the price and availability of materials, the mechanization of production, and firm sizes in construction.Footnote 28 Based on industry censuses, they observed that construction enterprises were indeed organized on a persistently small scale. During high construction activity between 1896 and 1910, Duchêne even noticed an increased fragmentation of the industry: the proportion of enterprises with 1 to 4 workers increased from 29 to 32 percent, while enterprises with over 10 workers declined from 6 to 5 percent.Footnote 29

However, they concluded that little was known about the long-term evolution of the Belgian construction sector. Buyst recognized the first significant changes in the productivity of enterprises in the early twentieth century, with innovations in the mechanization and standardization of production due to the rise of motor power and electricity and more efficient building methods such as reinforced concrete.Footnote 30 Innovations in building technology and business organization in the Belgian building sector were further studied by Inge Bertels and Jelena Dobbels.Footnote 31 They focused on the growth of public works contractors and general contractors, among whom innovative and large players emerged and who used steam engines on construction sites from the late nineteenth century.Footnote 32 However, by excluding ordinary enterprises in many skill-specialist building trades, from carpenters to plumbers and painters, they left much-needed room for nuance and further investigation.

A valuable conclusion of their research for this study is that Belgian construction enterprises rarely focused exclusively on either residential construction or public works and other large-scale infrastructures.Footnote 33 In the sources as well, no distinction is made between enterprises executing different types of construction activities. Therefore, in this study, these different types are considered. Residential construction, however, formed the vast majority of construction activities. In Brussels, it fluctuated around 95 percent until World War II, after which it dropped to 92 percent by 1961.Footnote 34

Earlier research has made clear that the local scale, rather than the national scale, is the most relevant for studying the structure of the building industry.Footnote 35 As mentioned, construction is a highly localized sector, tied to a specific city or region, where the dynamics of growth and volatility in construction activity, market demands, housing and building cultures, property structures, and planning regulations could strongly differ from one place to the next.Footnote 36

The focus here is on Brussels, which represents a growing and industrializing capital city with expanding and diversifying housing and construction needs, as in much of nineteenth- and twentieth-century urban Europe. Population figures increased from approximately 140,000 residents in 1831, when Brussels became the capital of the new kingdom of Belgium, to a peak of around 1,075,000 in 1970, after which a deurbanization trend set in.Footnote 37 On par with that evolution, the number of buildings in the city increased from approximately 20,400 in 1831 to approximately 184,000 by 1961.Footnote 38

Figure 1 shows the long- and short-term trends in construction activity. For Brussels, only annual averages are available, based on the growth in the number of buildings between 2 population censuses. They nevertheless correspond closely with the more detailed figures for Belgium as a whole, represented as an index of capital formation in residential construction, based on the data collected by Duchêne and Buyst. Only the decades of strong urban growth around 1900 stand out, with much higher construction activity in Brussels than in Belgium as a whole.

Figure 1. Average annual growth in the number of buildings in the Brussels Capital Region (BCR, left Y-axis) and index capital formation in residential construction activity in Belgium (right Y-axis).

Even leaving renovations aside, this urban growth evidently impacted the local construction sector to a great extent. Based on the Belgian industry censuses, it is possible to collect total employment figures in construction (with enterprises established in Brussels), as shown in Table 1.Footnote 39

Table 1. Absolute and relative evolution of construction employment in Brussels (data: population and industry censuses, Vandermotten Reference Vandyck, Degraeve, Van de Voorde, Mascarenhas-Mateus and Pires1978)

Table 1 shows that in the nineteenth century, absolute growth in construction employment reflected the scale of urban development. Between 1846 and 1896, their relative importance for the entire Brussels population more than doubled. However, as urban industry expanded in general, the relative importance of construction employment within total industrial employment remained fairly constant. In the twentieth century, the sector continued to grow in absolute numbers until World War II, when a slight setback occurred. The construction sector lost some of its importance compared to the total urban population, but it still represented a constant 16–17 percent of urban industrial employment.

However, especially the evolution after World War II exemplifies the atypicality of construction within the urban economy. The rapid postwar growth of the urban fabric ensured a strong continued growth of the construction sector, which almost doubled in importance between 1947 and 1970, not only in relation to the total urban population but also in relation to total industrial employment. While large-scale manufacturing started to leave the city in this period, construction necessarily occurred on building sites and could not be displaced toward industrial zones outside Brussels or abroad.Footnote 40

Simultaneously, the construction sector also had to adapt to the changing qualitative context of housing and building cultures, property structures, and planning regimes specific to Brussels. Brussels has an atypical fabric, which consists less of apartment blocks than of narrow plots, which allows only small, three- to four-story dwellings to be built.Footnote 41 Although they often have a similar floor plan and arrangement,Footnote 42 it produced an immense heterogeneity in housing construction that promoted a small-scale organization of the construction sector. More research on the financing of construction enterprises and speculative building is desirable, but it seems that the plots were often separately developed, either speculative or on contract, which also enabled small builders with relatively little financial means to participate in a fragmented housing development market.Footnote 43

This fragmentation was reinforced by demographic trends that made increasingly small nuclear families the main housing unit, which led to a growing demand for single-household dwellings.Footnote 44 Only from the interwar years, it was partly countered by the growth of (high-rise) apartment buildings in Brussels. New legislation in 1924 on co-ownership in apartment buildings enabled mortgage loans for the acquisition of individual apartments, which promoted investments in apartment buildings.Footnote 45

Drastic changes, specific to Belgium and Brussels, thus characterized the practices and organization of construction in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. The question is how these changes impacted the forms of business organization and entrepreneurship in construction. Did the industry remain highly fragmented and organized on a mostly small-scale and labor-intensive basis? Or was it characterized by the rise of large-scale, capital-intensive firms and increasing levels of market concentration? Did the latter remain limited to the shop-floor production of building materials and components, or did they also affect the building trades working on-site?

Sources and methods for building a database of construction enterprises

This paper uses a database of 16,714 enterprises active in five sample years (1833, 1866, 1899, 1932, and 1965). They make it possible to compare different timeframes of construction booms, which correspond to upturns in building cycles (as shown in Figure 1).Footnote 46 They also represent different generations of entrepreneurs working under rapidly changing societal and technological conditions. Thus, it is possible to analyze the flexibility with which the construction sector reacted to the demands, opportunities, and challenges of each time frame.

Two sources, both preserved in the Brussels City Archives (BCA), make it possible to record the large number of construction firms. They list enterprises in Brussels along with information on their business activities and organization. The main sources are the city’s trade directories or almanacs of commerce and industry, published annually from 1820 to 1969 for the entire urban agglomeration.Footnote 47 In one part, entrepreneurs are listed per trade, which allowed me to enter those active in building trades into a database. For the first sample year 1833, I used an existing dataset.Footnote 48

To address the shortcomings in the comprehensiveness of almanacs until the 1860s,Footnote 49 I supplemented the first 2 samples with entrepreneurs listed in the fiscal patent registers of Brussels in 1831 and 1864.Footnote 50 These registres des patentables recorded everyone who undertook a commercial or industrial trade, which required the payment of an annual “patent” tax in Belgium between 1795 and 1919.Footnote 51 They list entrepreneurs by address, trade, number of employees, and fiscal class.Footnote 52 They are arranged geographically, so they were scanned entirely to add all construction entrepreneurs to the database.

Based on these sources, I compiled a database in which each entry represents an enterprise and contains information on the name, address, occupation, a possible specification or combination of business activities, indications of family partnerships and other company forms, and (based on the 1831 and 1864 patent registers) the size of the workforce. Because one enterprise could be mentioned in multiple occupational categories and sources, I assigned unique identifications based on similarities in name, activities, and location. This made it possible to determine how many individual enterprises were active in each sample year, the results of which are shown in Table 2.

Table 2. Composition of the database: records and individual enterprises per source and sample year

However, we must be aware of the vast gray area between wage labor and entrepreneurship in construction. On the one hand, many were working in precarious positions as falsely self-employed subcontractors. On the other hand, unregistered ventures by wage laborers working as self-employed “on the side” have contributed to an immense amount of unreported work.Footnote 53 These informal enterprises remain untraceable in these sources and should form the object of further study; however, there are no indications that their importance radically changed over time.Footnote 54 The focus here is necessarily on officially registered enterprises, which provide a representatively large image of the construction sector at any given time.

Enterprise numbers: market concentration versus fragmentation

The first approach to evaluate long-term evolutions in construction involves analyzing enterprise numbers. Absolute numbers are useful to assess the extent to which entrepreneurship kept pace with urban growth, but enterprise numbers relative to the number of recently constructed buildings in the city are more revealing because they indicate whether the construction market was concentrated in the hands of a few firms or fragmented across many enterprises. Both trends are discussed as follows: first, for the industry as a whole; then, a distinction is made between different building trades.

Long-term changes in enterprise numbers

From the different methodological steps undertaken in processing the data, we arrive at the total enterprise numbers per sample year, as shown in Table 2. The first logical step in analyzing long-term change in enterprise numbers consists of verifying whether they increased nearly proportionally to the extent of urban growth, which would only be the case under constant productivity.Footnote 55 Table 3 shows the average annual change in the number of enterprises between 2 sample years and compares an index of construction enterprise numbers (1833=100) with an index of the number of buildings in the city, derived from cadastral data and population censuses, which shows the extent of urban growth.Footnote 56

Table 3. Absolute numbers of construction enterprises and buildings in Brussels (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers, population censuses, cadastral data)

In absolute terms, the total number of construction enterprises grew until 1932. The sevenfold increase in 100 years testifies to the vast expansion of the city and the construction sector. Especially in the late nineteenth century, rapid growth occurred in approximately 53 enterprises per year. Looking at the indexed data shows that, during the nineteenth century, the expansion of the construction sector even ran slightly ahead of urban expansion itself.

This changed in the early twentieth century. Between 1899 and 1932, the annual growth in the number of construction enterprises slowed and no longer kept up with the number of buildings. Between 1932 and 1965, there was even an absolute decline in the number of enterprises, while the city continued to grow. This suggests an increasingly concentrated construction market in the twentieth century when fewer enterprises could cater to a persistently growing city. It is, however, only the manifestation of a trend that has been going on for much longer. This becomes clear by examining the number of construction enterprises relative to the changing size of the urban construction market.

Comparing the number of enterprises with the total population is not ideal because demographic shifts in household sizes and cohabitation patterns strongly impact the demand for buildings.Footnote 57 Specifically for construction, the number of buildings in the city provides a more adequate way to quantify demand. Comparing with the total number of buildings, however, includes many that did not require much construction work. To include only the actual market of newly constructed buildings, I estimated the number of recently added buildings by comparing the number of buildings from the most recent census with that from the previous one.Footnote 58 It reveals how many firms were required to erect 1,000 new buildings. This method does not consider the renovation market, nor does it distinguish between the sizes of buildings. However, since the average number of people per building declined between 1900 and 1960,Footnote 59 the growth of apartment buildings was more than offset by the simultaneous growing demand for single-household dwellings in Brussels.

In Table 4, the relative number of construction enterprises in the city, measured on 1,000 recently constructed buildings, shows a constant decrease from 406 in 1833 to 219 by 1965. Already in the nineteenth century, gradually fewer enterprises were needed to cater to the needs of the local urban market for (new) construction. This contrasts with the steadily increasing relative importance of employment figures in construction, as shown in Table 1. While the construction sector as a whole thus continued to grow, the rate of entrepreneurship decreased. This corresponds with the slowly declining trend, observed by Bennett et al., of the entrepreneurship rate in the construction sector in England and Wales between 1851 and 1911.Footnote 60 In Brussels, the high construction activity until the 1960s makes it unattributable to a decline in demand. Instead, it can be hypothesized that incremental productivity increases result in growing levels of market concentration. However, these dynamics were highly subsector-specific. By shedding light on the differences between various building trades, more conclusive statements can be made.

Table 4. Relative numbers of construction enterprises in Brussels (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers, population censuses, cadastral data)

Subsectoral change: differences between building trades

From a theoretical perspective on the “historical alternatives to mass production,” more than one production method can be applied in each industry. Typically, a range of firms pursue different strategies, marked by varying degrees of flexible specialization.Footnote 61 The construction sector is similarly fragmented across different subsectors. Harris and Buzzelli argued that housebuilding falls exceptionally close to the “flexible specialization” end of the spectrum,Footnote 62 but providing empirical evidence for this requires disentangling the sector into different building trades.

I selected 10 subsectors: contractors, bricklayers, joiners–carpenters, iron and steel workers, painters, plumbers, plasterers, marble and stone masons, glaziers, and roofers. Despite technological or organizational changes within these trades, they were listed during the entire period, which enabled their analysis over the long run. The selection contains both builders working on site and those who worked (partly) in workshops for the prefabrication of building parts. The paper thus adopts a broad definition of the construction sector,Footnote 63 which makes it possible to consider different levels of labor and capital intensity and productivity changes.

Each subsector’s long-term evolution becomes clear through their absolute and relative numbers of enterprises, as shown in Figure 2.Footnote 64 The absolute figures (in gray) show their expansion in a growing city. As for the construction sector in general, the absolute numbers of joiners–carpenters, plasterers, contractors, and plumbers increased until 1932, after which they declined. Marble and stone masons, bricklayers, iron and steel workers, and glaziers had already peaked in 1899. The number of enterprises owned by roofers and painters, on the other hand, continued to increase until 1965.

Figure 2. Absolute (gray, left Y-axis) and relative (red, right Y-axis, per 1,000 recent buildings) numbers of enterprises per subsector and sample year (1833, 1866, 1899, 1932 and 1965) (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers).

It is again from the relative figures (in red), however, that significant patterns of market fragmentation or concentration become clear. They resulted from interactions between diversification and expansion of demand, on the one hand, and supply-side dynamics with changes in productivity and technological possibilities, on the other. Different trajectories can be distinguished.

First, the long-term market concentration in the construction sector as a whole is best reflected by the numerically most important trades of iron and steel workers and joiners–carpenters. The long-term relative decline in both subsectors meant that fewer firms were required to construct 1,000 buildings. Their increasing labor productivity was at the heart of this evolution. As some of the first sectors to profit from industrialization, economies of scale were particularly achievable in iron and steel manufacturing and woodworking. For many building parts and components in iron and wood, such as locks, stoves, doors, and windows, demand for luxuriously and individually finished goods was increasingly exchanged for cheaper, mass-produced alternatives.Footnote 65 Growing shares of the work were relocated from the building site and into workshops and factories, where productivity increases resulted from mechanized and serial production processes that exchanged labor-intensive for more capital-intensive production methods.Footnote 66 Consequently, the few manufacturers who were able to make these investments outcompeted many other smaller joiners and iron and steel workers in the market, resulting in a relatively declining number of enterprises in these trades.

Several subsectors followed this path of long-term relative decline, but it was preceded or interrupted by a phase of relative expansion. Sometimes, trends in architecture and housing culture result in short-lived growth in demand. High demands for neoclassical decoration,Footnote 67 for example, led to the growth of plasterers and marble and stone masons between 1833 and 1866, after which they declined. Temporary upsurges in demand could also interrupt a long-term decline, as for glaziers (1866–1899).

Industrialization thus deeply affected the structure of the urban construction sector, resulting in long-term declining relative numbers of enterprises in several building trades. While they determined the relative decline in entrepreneurship in the construction sector as a whole, a few others countered this trend by showcasing the pervasiveness of flexible specialization.

This is exemplified, first of all, by the rise of contractors. The rapid urbanization of the nineteenth century involved a growing number, size, and complexity of construction sites. It required increased supervision and coordination, resulting in greater involvement of contractors.Footnote 68 Unlike ironworkers and woodworkers, their work necessarily remained on the building site, where they kept working in labor-intensive ways, without many possibilities for achieving economies of scale.Footnote 69 In the twentieth century, their slowed-down growth suggests that the mechanization of on-site work did result in some productivity increases,Footnote 70 but it did not prevent a continued fragmentation of the contractors’ market. In addition to coordinating and supervising, most contractors completed the construction works themselves. This resulted in the decline of other specialized building trades, such as bricklayers (after 1866) and, to a lesser extent, roofers, an evolution that Powell also observed for Britain.Footnote 71

Plumbers represent a unique pattern of decline followed by a strong expansion. Until 1866, they were similarly subject to processes of market concentration due to the industrialization of lead processing. Around that time, however, plumbers flexibly reacted to the new large-scale demands for domestic hygiene. Their reorientation toward the market of domestic sanitary facilities involved a flexible implementation of new materials, techniques, and production processes.Footnote 72 Consequently, the work of plumbers shifted in the opposite direction: away from workshops and factories and onto the building site, where they had to flexibly adapt their work to heterogeneous production contexts. As a result, plumbers underwent a unique development of increasing market fragmentation after 1866.

Finally, painters’ work remained similarly dominated by on-site labor. This submarket became increasingly fragmented in the nineteenth century and, following a slight setback in 1932, stabilized at a high level of fragmentation in the twentieth century. Followed by contractors and plumbers, painters formed the most numerous building trades in both absolute and relative terms by 1965, which makes these trades prime examples of the enduring viability of flexible specialization in construction.

Long-term trends in business size

Looking at long-term change in the number of enterprises only sketches a part of the picture. The divergent trends of market concentration and fragmentation went hand in hand with changes in the scale on which these businesses operated. If fewer enterprises catered to a growing market, this implied that these firms grew larger, while a fragmented market counted more small firms. Thus, a self-evident complementary approach considers long-term changes in firm sizes.

In contemporary studies, a preferred measure for business sizes in construction is data of physical output, such as the volume of built units,Footnote 73 or data on financial assets,Footnote 74 but their limited availability usually compels business historians to measure the firm size in terms of employment figures.Footnote 75 It has drawbacks due to incremental changes in labor productivity, and specifically for construction, due to changes in indirect employment through subcontractors.Footnote 76 Nonetheless, scholars are largely conclusive on the value of employment figures to indicate hierarchies between (construction) enterprises.Footnote 77

Whereas historiography stresses the persistently small scale of operations for construction enterprises, new evidence from Bennett et al. suggests long-term firm growth in construction. Among nonself-employed entrepreneurs in England and Wales, average firm sizes increased from 9.9 employees in 1851 to 14.7 in 1901. Furthermore, between 1851 and 1881, the number of construction entrepreneurs with 1 or 2 workers decreased, whereas those with 3 or more workers increased.Footnote 78 To what extent did larger-scale firms gain the upper hand in Brussels?

Changing firm size structures in the nineteenth century

In the patent registers, the fiscal class for entrepreneurs in manufacturing sectors was based on the number of workers, which makes it possible to analyze firm size structures.Footnote 79 In construction, only contractors were not taxed based on their labor force. However, for all others, the number of workers should still be evaluated cautiously. As the number of workers formed the basis for the tax rate, entrepreneurs were inclined to minimize it. They filed the patent requests themselves, after which the number of employees was sometimes validated by inspectors.

A second measure of caution stems from the cyclicality of building, which is determined not only by long-term building wavesFootnote 80 but also by seasonal building cycles.Footnote 81 During the off-peak winter season, firms usually lay off part of their workforce. Registration for the patent tax, however, took place at the end of the year, which may have led to an underestimation of construction workforces. However, if additional workers were hired the following year, entrepreneurs often moved to a higher fiscal class.Footnote 82 These class alterations are listed at the end of each register and are considered in this analysis.Footnote 83

Self-employed artisans without wage laborers were exempted in 1864 and were therefore also left out of the sample for 1831. In total, the 1831 sample counts 422 enterprises employing 1194 workers, or 2.8 workers on average. The 1864 sample has 778 enterprises with 4139 workers, or 5.3 workers on average. This average firm size growth is reflected by the changing relative distribution of enterprises in different firm size classes in Figure 3.

Figure 3. Distribution of enterprises and employment over five firm size classes in 1831 and 1864 (excluding self-employed entrepreneurs) (data: BCA patent registers).

In the previous section, the mid-nineteenth century already came forward as a period of early change with initiating dynamics of market concentration. The workforce numbers show that this evolution was paired with a growth in firm size. Between 1831 and 1864, the proportion of firms with 1 or 2 workers declined, whereas each category of firms with 3 or more workers grew. The distribution of the total employment figures over the firm size categories shows declining rates for firms with fewer than or equal to 10 workers and a strong increase for firms with more than 10 workers. The estimated labor market share of the latter grew from 8 percent to approximately 40 percent in 33 years.

Much of the rare comparable data comes from Britain. In terms of employment rates, Rodger similarly observed that large building firms were disproportionally important in Scottish cities in 1851. Among the nonself-employed, 30 percent of the firms had 10 or more workers, but they employed up to 80 percent of the entire building labor force. He argues that “the Scottish construction industry was far more dependent on the smaller builder than any other part of Britain,” but it was still organized on a significantly larger scale than in Brussels. Only from 1880 did the average size of building firms start to increase in Scotland.Footnote 84 In Brussels, on the contrary, earlier stages of urbanization (1831–1864) could be paired with firm growth in construction as well.

Urban growth, however, did not necessarily result in firm growth. A comparison with data for Brussels from the 1892 patent registers, drafted by Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk,Footnote 85 reveals that instead of a uniform trend toward increasing firm sizes, a trend-susceptible cyclicality drove firm sizes in construction. Between 1864 and 1892, the share of small firms with 1 or 2 workers expanded again, from 47 to 66 percent, while those of 3 to 5 workers (from 26 to 20 percent) and 6+ workers (from 27 to 15 percent) both declined, so each category had returned more or less to its 1831 status. This indicates the cyclical nature of firm sizes in construction, caused by the high construction activity in late nineteenth-century Brussels and similarly observed by Buzzelli for late twentieth-century Canada.Footnote 86 It was also part of a broader trend of market fragmentation in the late nineteenth century, resulting from an increase in diversification and specialist production to cope with growing competition from large-scale manufacturers.Footnote 87

Long-term subsectoral trends

In the nineteenth century, firm sizes were thus highly cyclical. Did long-term firm growth occur in the twentieth century, when the previously observed dynamics of market concentration were reinforced? This trend showed major subsectoral differences, but firm sizes varied significantly between building trades.Footnote 88 While the work in some subsectors required more labor input or was susceptible to a greater division of labor and standardization, others were necessarily organized on a smaller scale, provided too few means for firm expansion, or had too little to gain from it.

Long-term subsectoral patterns in average firm sizes can be evaluated from the patent registers of 1831 and 1864, along with the Belgian censuses of commerce and industry. From 1846 to 1970, censuses were commissioned quite irregularly (on average every 15–20 years) by the government. Per subsector and municipality, they list the number of enterprises and their workforce.Footnote 89 Average firm sizes were obtained per subsector from the 1846, 1896, 1910, and 1937 censuses. In the 1961 and 1970 censuses, they are only available on an aggregated level for the construction sector as a whole.

These data should be handled equally cautiously. On the one hand, industry censuses do not easily allow the assessment of changes in a complex and transforming industry such as construction: some trades frequently switched between categories, for example, while the 1896 census categorized contractors in the municipality where they worked and not where the entrepreneur was established.Footnote 90 On the other hand, as average workforce figures per enterprise, they are influenced by high outliers and exclude information on the much greater proportion of smaller enterprises. Nevertheless, even these average figures never exceeded 13 workers per enterprise, so we can safely assume that these averages do not distort the picture of a persistently small-scale organization in construction. Figure 4 shows trends in average firm sizes per subsector (excluding contractors).

Figure 4. Average firm sizes per subsector (1831–1937), excluding contractors, and for the construction sector as a whole (1831–1970) (data: industry censuses, BCA patent registers 1831 and 1864).

In most subsectors, the average firm size followed a general pattern that determined the long-term trend in the construction sector as a whole. Up to 1910, with less than 5 workers per enterprise, the average workforce in these subsectors remained strikingly low. In particular, glaziers worked on a very small scale. Eventually, between 1831 and 1937, however, there was a slow increase from 0.4–2.7 to 1.8–7.6 workers per enterprise. Such increasing scales of operations align with the earlier observed growth in market concentration and relatively declining enterprise numbers.

In addition to long-term firm size growth, there are noticeable fluctuations. These may have resulted from economic trends and the cyclical nature of building. Although economic growth and increasing construction activity compelled business growth, they also resulted in many new entrants and a dominant trend of market fragmentation. In times of crisis, on the other hand, many enterprises were outcompeted, and market concentration ensued. The peaks in 1846, therefore, may have resulted from higher levels of market concentration following the 1840s crisis, the downward trend between 1846 and 1864 from market fragmentation in the 1860s growth years, the upward trend between 1864 and 1896 from the 1880s crisis years, and the one between 1910 and 1937 from World War 1 and the 1930s crisis.

Nonetheless, the sources’ limitations may also explain many of these fluctuations. The 1846 census underrecorded small-scale industrial activities,Footnote 91 while the decline between 1896 and 1910 can also be explained by the recording of the workforce numbers at the very end of 1910, during the off-peak season.Footnote 92 Most importantly, the seemingly drastic impact of the 1930s crisis on increasing firm sizes should be nuanced, as self-employed entrepreneurs were not considered in 1937.Footnote 93

The general trend for 1831–1937 thus confirms, first and foremost, a persistently small scale of construction operations. To a more limited extent, they were also affected by a gradual overall increase in firm sizes because of industrialization, possibly counterbalanced by the fluctuations and cyclicalities that characterized construction in general.

Apart from this general trend, some building trades followed divergent firm size patterns. Marble and stone masons had relatively large enterprises on average until the mid-nineteenth century, after which their firm sizes rapidly declined.Footnote 94 Their evolution mirrors that of bricklayers, who had the largest firms in 1846, but afterward decline equally set in. We already saw how the rising relative importance of contractors was at the expense of bricklayers. Similarly, while bricklayers’ firm sizes declined, those of contractors steadily increased. Contractors had on average 5.5 workers in 1846, 36.5 in 1896, 25.4 in 1910,Footnote 95 and 43.2 by 1937.

Bricklayers and contractors had in common that their work occurred on the construction site. Their high average firm sizes correspond with Clarke’s observations of their extended use of wage labor on construction sites since the seventeenth century, which allowed them to extract more surplus and accumulate capital.Footnote 96 Their growth resulted from the need and ability to employ a larger body of mostly low-skilled workers on a (semi-) permanent basis on the growing number of large construction sites in a growing city, for instance, for large-scale public works commissioned by local governments,Footnote 97 and for the speculative development of new residential suburbs. However, in Brussels, the fragmented development market was not inaccessible for smaller-scale contractors as well.Footnote 98

Economies of scale, on the other hand, were not at play among contractors. Wellings showed that large on-site housebuilders in Britain did not have substantially greater profit margins than small ones. He argued that their growth is due to a complex interplay of reinvestments and accumulation of capital, extensions of the spatial range of operations, and the personal judicious qualities of entrepreneurs, such as their ability to spread and avoid risks at critical points in the building cycle.Footnote 99

The post-World War II developments are only available on an aggregate sectoral level but indicate the long-term importance of this kind of “on-site” firm growth in construction. The general decline between 1937 and 1961Footnote 100 suggests continued cyclicality and renewed fragmentation of the market, but the 1930s crisis and World War II still had a structural effect on the level of market concentration in the sector, since the general average firm size did not decrease back to the pre-1930s level. Many small firms persisted or were newly established around 1960, but the market balance was shifting in favor of the few big building firms. Between 1961 and 1970, the share of self-employed entrepreneurs increased from 55 to 62 percent of all firms, in line with the favorable economic climate and high construction activity during the 1960s. Simultaneously, however, market concentration occurred. The share of self-employed entrepreneurs in total construction employment declined from 6.9 to 5.6 percent, and the average firm size increased from 8.5 to 12.4 workers in only nine years.

In France, Martini also observed an expansion of large- and medium-sized building firms in the 1960s, largely due to their activities as project developers. Although it accelerated polarization in the construction sector, she argued that it did not fundamentally alter its fragmented structure.Footnote 101 Likewise, for the Canadian housebuilding industry in the second half of the twentieth century, Buzzelli saw that the level of market concentration did not even approach the high degree of centralization common in many other industries.Footnote 102 In Brussels, over half of all construction enterprises had fewer than 12.4 workers in 1970 and were thus still organized on a small scale.

The findings on business sizes thus confirm, first and foremost, the long-term importance of small firms in construction. Nevertheless, the comparison between firm size structures in 1831 and 1864 also indicated an early shift in market dominance in favor of firms with more than 5 workers. Gradual long-term firm growth was partly the result of industrialization and capital accumulation on construction sites. Firm growth was further promoted by crises, but in trend-susceptible industries such as construction, cyclicality and fluctuations remained the rule.

Long-term trends in company formation

Thus far, differences in the capital intensity of the production process and the possibilities for capital accumulation appeared crucial in determining the level of market concentration and firm growth in construction. Scrutinizing the varying effects of industrialization and flexible specialization therefore also requires taking into account the varying levels of capital in the construction sector. As mentioned earlier, the financing of construction enterprises is a major pathway for further research. A provisional solution consists of examining company forms and structures. Because they functioned as instruments to pool resources and mediate corresponding levels of risk, these company forms indicate the level of capital involved in a construction business.

This section discusses different company forms in Belgium, how they did or did not suit the needs of construction enterprises, and how their importance developed over time. For each sample year, I traced every construction enterprise that was not run by a sole proprietor in their personal name. It was not required to list each enterprise’s exact company form in the almanacs; therefore, they presumably represent slight underestimations. However, because an advanced form of corporate organization also functioned as a marketing tool, I assume that a representative majority is included in these figures. They are divided into 6 categories, represented in absolute numbers and percentages in Table 5.

Table 5. Company forms in the construction sector per sample year (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers)

In total, these company forms represent a growing number of enterprises, but the first observation is unavoidable; they constituted only a minority of 1.3 to 11.6 percent of all enterprises. Despite the gradually declining importance of the classic sole proprietorship, it remains the most popular form of business organization. For sole proprietorships, there was no legal framework and no division between private and company property.Footnote 103 The proprietor was personally fully responsible and liable in the case of bankruptcy, so it was the riskiest form of business organization. However, the very few legal obligations, the flexibility of establishment and liquidation, and the possibilities for quick decision-making offered advantages that suited the volatile conditions in construction very well.

However, nonsole proprietorship, although less significant, requires in-depth analysis as well, as it sheds light on the reasons why these company forms were less suitable in construction. Moreover, it expanded eventually. For the small but growing proportion of nonsole proprietors, the changing needs for capital input were addressed by increasingly appropriate company forms.

Family firms and informal partnerships

Just above sole proprietors, in terms of capital needs, were family firms and other informal business partnerships. Partnerships are considered effective mechanisms for business growth by expanding expertise, skills, and capital.Footnote 104 Especially in family firms, they conveniently kept staff monitoring costs low and facilitated the process of business acquisitions.Footnote 105 Family ties were essential to raise capital,Footnote 106 provide (cheap) labor,Footnote 107 and provide training, tacit knowledge, and other informational assets.Footnote 108 Smith et al. argued that family ties particularly suited sectors characterized by smaller firms and low levels of incorporation because they formed a “flexible kind of business organization, which allowed resources to be pooled and risks managed without the costs incurred through incorporation, (…) a useful alternative to incorporation and sole proprietorship.”Footnote 109

Family partnerships were either implicit, where family members worked together as self-employed persons in the same industry, or explicit, where the partnership of 2 or more family members was listed in the company name. The latter were listed in Brussels almanacs and patent registers, allowing for a longitudinal analysis of the importance of family ties in the construction industry. In the category of family partnerships in Table 5, all businesses are included for which 2 or more family members at the head of the firm are mentioned: “and son(s),” “father and son,” “(and) children,” “brothers (and sisters),” “widow and son,” “Mrs. and son,” “and wife,” as well as undefined kinship ties between 2 persons with the same surname.

The rate of explicit family partnerships increased from 0.9 in 1833 to 4.7 percent by 1965. However, they only form a visible fraction of family firms. In England and Wales, in 1881, only 34 percent of all partnerships between fathers and sons, as well as between brothers, were explicit. In construction, there was a similar rate of 36 percent explicit partnerships.Footnote 110 Therefore, we can assume that also the actual importance of family firms in the Brussels construction sector far exceeded these percentages.

Closely related to the informality of family ties were nonfamily partnerships, between people with different family names, and “& Cie” (and Co.) partnerships. The latter especially thrived around the turn of the century as a fashionable business term.Footnote 111 Their importance declined between 1932 and 1965 when they were overtaken by incorporated partnership forms that represented more advantages for nonrelated business partners. Together with family partnerships, they can be considered as “non-incorporated partnerships.” Due to the growth of family partnerships, their joint relative importance still increased from 1.3 to 5.4 percent between 1833 and 1965. This shows that such informal partnerships, especially those undertaken within the family, formed an increasingly important middle ground in construction between sole proprietorships and incorporations.

Incorporation in construction

The role of informal partnerships grew, but even greater change can be observed with incorporated company forms in construction. In the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, various types of corporate partnerships were created and adapted in Belgian commercial legislation in response to changing economic circumstances and business needs. The most influential form was the joint-stock company or Société Anonyme (SA), established by the French Code de Commerce in 1807.Footnote 112 An SA was highly suitable for injecting a lot of capital into an enterprise and minimizing risk. Strict rules were imposed that required government authorization for its establishment. Initially, establishing an SA, therefore, was a costly and complicated venture reserved only for the nation’s largest enterprises. Unsurprisingly, very few SAs were active in the Brussels construction sector during this period. In 1866, there was 1 SA active in steel production (the SA pour la fabrication des aciers), which could imply high capital needs. Only in 1873 did the liberalization of the commercial legislation remove all government interference in the creation of an SA. As a result, growing numbers of SAs were established in construction as well, especially in the twentieth century, when a small but increasing share of firms experienced growing capital needs that were most appropriately addressed by an SA.

Three other corporate forms are only occasionally mentioned and were, therefore, probably not very well suited for the capital needs in construction. There was only 1 limited partnership (Société en Commandite Simple, SCS) in 1965. It featured both liable commissioned associates and “silent” commissioning associates, who only provided funds and were not involved in the management. Cooperative partnerships with limited liability (Société Cooperative à Responsabilité Limitée, SCRL) also had limited success. There were eight SCRLs in 1932 and 6 in 1965. Lastly, there was 1 general partnership (Société en Nom Collectif, SNC) in 1899 and 2 in 1932. They required no minimum capital, and the input of partners could also consist of labor. However, they were personally fully liable, so this type of partnership was only suitable when risks were low, which explains its limited success in the building sector.

In 1935, a new corporate partnership form was created, the personal partnership with limited liability (Société de Personnes à Responsabilité Limitée, SPRL). It bridged the gap between joint-stock companies (SA) and general partnerships (SNC), which was required to regain the trust of financial investors during the 1930s crisis. Within an SPRL, each partner was only liable for the capital they had initially invested. Especially for nonfamily partnerships in construction, limited liability partnerships presented an appropriate alternative corporate form that increased the chance of success.Footnote 113 Unsurprisingly, then, while SPRLs made a great advance in the Brussels construction sector after 1932,Footnote 114 the number of nonfamily partnerships drastically declined during this period.

Taken together, corporate partnerships represented a growing share, from 0.05 percent of construction enterprises in 1866 to 6.2 percent by 1965. Bennett et al. observed comparably low but increasing rates of business incorporation in all sectors in England and Wales, from 0.2 percent in 1851 to 2.2 percent in 1911. There, the number of incorporated firms particularly increased from the 1880s crisis years on.Footnote 115 Economic downturns appeared to accelerate a shift in market dominance in favor of the corporate sector, where higher profits could be made by a small but increasing number of enterprises that were able to grow into large, hierarchically managed concerns.Footnote 116 In the Brussels construction sector, the largest expansion in incorporation occurred between 1932 and 1965. The 1930s crisis, World War II, and the postwar urban growth produced growing needs for capital and liability in construction, as well as opportunities for business growth, which could be increasingly addressed and accommodated by these new company forms.

Capital-intensive versus labor-intensive subsectors

The rates of company formation nevertheless show large subsectoral differences. Table 6 displays the percentage of company formation per subsector, containing the 6 aforementioned categories. The sequence is based on the rates for 1965, which are ranked from high to low.

Table 6. Percentage of company formation per subsector and sample year (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers)

The subsectoral rates of company formation span a wide range in each sample year: from 0–12.5 percent in 1833 to 4–26 percent in 1965. Moreover, the rates appear to be relatively path-dependent. Plumbers and painters, for example, are always found at the bottom of the ranking. Together with plasterers, roofers, joiners–carpenters, and bricklayers, their rates of incorporation never exceeded 10 percent. On the other hand, marble and stone masons, iron and steel workers, and contractors consistently had relatively high percentages of company formation, particularly from the middle of the twentieth century, when their rates reached around a quarter of all registered enterprises.

These findings resonate with my earlier observations on the impact of industrialization and market concentration (such as with iron and steel workers), on on-site firm growth (with contractors), and on persistently small scales of operation (with painters, roofers, and plumbers). The high capital intensity of the mechanized production of iron and steel building parts, marble, and eventually glass also implied a need to mediate greater financial risks and ensure greater profits made through partnerships and within large, hierarchically managed concerns. Similarly, opportunities for firm growth and capital accumulation on construction sites resulted in high rates of company formation among contractors.

At the other end of the spectrum are highly labor-intensive building trades, characterized by low rates of company formation. Fewer to no economies of scale could be obtained by roofers, painters, plumbers, etc., who ceaselessly had to adapt their work to the particularities of the building site. While some joiners–carpenters mechanized production, obtained economies of scale and competed many others out of the market, many remaining ones reoriented toward the renovation market and continued working in labor-intensive ways. For them, as for the vast majority of the construction sector in general, informal and flexible forms of business organization remained the most advantageous.

Conclusion

Looking at long-term evolutions in enterprise numbers, firm sizes, and rates of company formation among construction enterprises in Brussels between 1830 and 1970, this paper argues that in this period of strong urban growth, a divergence occurred within the construction sector, under the influence of the counteracting forces of urbanization and industrialization. Owing to the variety and labor intensity of on-site construction work, nearly the entire construction market remained highly fragmented over large numbers of enterprises working on a small scale. Market fragmentation even increased in trades where on-site work became increasingly important, such as contractors and plumbers. In general, average firm sizes never exceeded 13 workers, and by 1965, 88 percent of enterprises were sole proprietors with limited capital needs.

In contrast, the construction sector was also affected by the dynamics of market concentration, firm growth, and incorporation. Relocating work from the building site into a more capital-intensive, mechanized shop-floor production process made economies of scale possible and allowed a small number of entrepreneurs to outcompete many others. On the construction site as well, dynamics of consolidation and firm size growth occurred. The expansion of labor forces, especially by contractors, caused some firms to accumulate capital and evolve into large-scale firms. Dynamics of market concentration and firm size growth were initiated in the mid-nineteenth century. Then still part of a cyclical process, they had more lasting effects in the twentieth century, accelerated by economic crises and aided by increasingly appropriate company forms.

In this way, the structure of the building sector aptly reflects the divided historiography of the industry itself. By providing a long-term quantitative framework that clarifies each side’s developing relative importance over time, this paper has aimed to bridge the gap between the scholarly work that stresses a Chandlerian track of firm growth and increasing productivity in construction,Footnote 117 and theoretical reflections on the persistent importance of flexible specialization.Footnote 118 Overall, while processes of firm growth, industrialization, and market concentration did make their way into the construction sector, this was only to a very limited extent, so most enterprises working on-site, on a small scale, and in labor-intensive ways represent the long-term viability of flexible specialization as an alternative pathway for the efficient organization of industrial activity.

While Brussels served as a representative case for the strongly growing and industrializing (capital) cities of Western Europe, the specificity of its urban fabric and development had particular effects on the organization of the urban construction industry. Scarce comparable data on construction enterprises from other cities and countries show that the fragmented property structure in Brussels, with its predominantly single-household dwellings embedded in planning policies, promoted a particularly pronounced fragmentation of the construction market. The cyclicality of construction had its effects on the capital as well. In particular, in the late nineteenth century, a major construction boom produced an immense expansion and fragmentation of the construction market, followed by a relative and absolute decline in the number of enterprises in the twentieth century.

From a broader historiographical perspective, these results demonstrate the importance of long-term quantitative analyses of entrepreneurial populations.Footnote 119 Taking the many self-employed sole proprietors into account, who took great risks and responsibilities for their survival and that of their families, allows for a broad perspective on entrepreneurship. Such quantitative studies open up major avenues for further business–historical research, both for the assessment of individual firms’ representativity or singularity and for comparisons across industries, regions, and timeframes.

Footnotes

1. Jacobs, The Economy of Cities, 243; Schmitz and Ducuroir, “Vers l’industrialisation du bâtiment”; Châtelain, “Une grande industrie motrice”; Lacoste, “Aspects géographiques”; Schlesinger and Erlich, “Housing.”

2. Harris, Building a Market, 6–7. Noteworthy exceptions to the lack of business–historical studies on construction include: Rodger, “Speculative Builders” (who did stress the role of small firms and limited capital needs in construction); McKenna and Rodger, “Control by Coercion”; Lund, “Building Hitler’s Europe”; Stephenson, “The Economic Institutions”; Scott, “Friends in high places”; and Vejzagić, “Persistent Centralisation of Decision-Making.”

3. Clarke, Building Capitalism; Stephenson, “The Economic Institutions.”

4. Lacoste, “Aspects géographiques”; McLean, “Constructors in a foreign land”; Chandler, “The Railroads”; Chandler, The visible hand, chapters 3–5.

5. Woodward, Men at work, 25 and 91; Baer, “The House-Building Sector,” 410–411.

6. van Gerwen and de Goey, Ondernemers in Nederland, 33.

7. Buyst, An Economic History, 132.

8. Martini, Bâtiment en famille, 45–50.

9. Harris, Building a Market, 6–7; Harris and Buzzelli, “House Building in the Machine Age.”

10. Sabel and Zeitlin, “Historical Alternatives”; Zeitlin, “The historical alternatives.”

11. Piore and Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide, 115.

12. Ball, “The International Restructuring”; Tuckman, “Looking Backwards,” 59; Barlow, “From Craft Production.”

13. Harris and Buzzelli, “House Building in the Machine Age.”

14. Harris and Buzzelli, “House Building in the Machine Age”; Buzzelli, “Firm Size Structure”; Martini, Bâtiment en famille.

15. This approach is especially central to the discipline of construction history, see for instance: Dobbels, Building a Profession; Rabeneck, “Recent Geopolitics of Construction”; Middlemas, The Master Builders.

16. Bennett et al., The Age of Entrepreneurship, 5–9.

17. Schumpeter, “The Creative Response,” 149–159. Used among others by Baumol, The Microtheory; Casson, Entrepreneurship; Whaples, “Economic history”; Mokyr, “Entrepreneurship,” 197.

18. Martini, Bâtiment en famille, 221.

19. Bertels et al., “Pour une historiographie,” 1189–1199.

20. Hillebrandt, Economic theory, 2; Buyst, An Economic History, 131–133.

21. Lacoste, “Aspects géographiques généraux,” 125–131.

22. Whitehand, The Making of the Urban Landscape; Buzzelli and Harris, “Cities as the Industrial Districts.”

23. de Vries and van der Woude, Nederland 1500-1815, 594; Blondé, Een economie, 67–68, 86–87; Van Uytven, “Peiling naar de beroepsstructuur,” 172–203.

24. Powell, An Economic History, 25.

25. Powell, “He That Runs Against Time,” 61–67; Rodger, “Structural Instability.”

26. Buzzelli, “Firm Size Structure.”

27. Goffee and Scase, The Entrepreneurial Middle Class, 53–65; Eccles, “The Quasifirm,” 343.

28. Buyst, An Economic History, 131–175; Duchêne, De brutobinnenlandse kapitaalvorming, 248–253.

29. Duchêne, De brutobinnenlandse kapitaalvorming, 250.

30. Buyst, An Economic History, 177–180.

31. Bertels, “Building contractors”; Dobbels, Building a Profession.

32. Bertels, Building the City, 445 and 449; Dobbels, Building a Profession; Rauhut, “La mécanisation.”

33. Dobbels, “Becoming Professional Practitioners,” 74.

34. The percentages were calculated by dividing the number of buildings destined for housing by the total number of buildings in the Brussels population censuses (see Footnote note 58). These percentages only provide an indication of the high importance of housebuilding within the Brussels construction activity. Due to the larger scale of other types of infrastructure works, they do not represent an absolute assessment of the importance of housebuilding within the overall construction activity.

35. Rodger, “Structural Instability,” 48.

36. See for instance: Galavan, Dublin’s Bourgeois Homes; Rilling, Making houses; Bertels, Building the City; Martini, Bâtiment en famille.

37. Daelemans, “De bevolking.”

38. Population censuses and cadastral data, obtained via Sven Vrielinck (LOKSTAT – Universiteit Gent).

39. Total industrial employment for 1846 and 1910 is derived from Vandermotten, “Ebauche d’une macrogéographie,” 659–60, 669–75, to which I added employment in construction from the industry censuses, which he excluded.

40. Vandermotten, “De Brusselse industrie,” 16.

41. Wagenaar, Stedebouw en burgerlijke vrijheid; Ledent and Porotto, Brussels Housing.

42. Heymans, Les dimensions d’ordinaire.

43. Billiet and Verstappen, De aanleg van de Blaesstraat; Content, “L’habitat ouvrier.”

44. Smith et al., “The Demand for Housing.”

45. van Dijk, Appartementsgebouwen uit het interbellum, 19–20.

46. Barras, Building Cycles.

47. Brussels City Archives (BCA), online available via <https://archief.brussel.be/almanakken>.

48. Data obtained via Anneleen Arnout – Centre for Urban History, University of Antwerp.

49. Debroux, “Des artistes en ville,” 105–7.

50. BCA, Registres des patentables, 1831 and 1864. To offset the presumed time lag in the almanacs, I used patent registers from 2 years earlier.

51. For the second sample year (1864/1866), the patent registers are only preserved for the city of Brussels. Moreover, since 1849, self-employed artisans without workers have been exempted (Parisel, “Les artisans,” 97–99). Therefore, the almanacs were the only source of information for the suburbs and the self-employed in 1866.

52. Hannes, De economische bedrijvigheid; Lemmens, “Kritische en methodologische beschouwingen”; Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk and Vire, “Les registres des patentables.”

53. De Boeck et al., “Making space,” 67–77.

54. Breman, “A Short History of the Informal Economy” 23.

55. Wellings, British Housebuilders.

56. See Footnote note 58.

57. Smith et al., “The Demand for Housing”; Buyst, An Economic History, 186–190.

58. I used cadastral data on the number of buildings in 1834 and 1961, and data from population censuses on the number of buildings in 1846, 1856, 1866, 1890, 1900, 1910, 1920, 1930, and 1947 (via Sven Vrielinck (LOKSTAT – Universiteit Gent), as well as an estimate of the number of buildings in 1821 based on the number of parcels on the digitized “Plan Bastendorff” (via Ann Degraeve and Reinout Klaarenbeek). I used the data for the same municipalities as those considered by the database for the corresponding sample year.

59. The average number of people per building fluctuated around 7.5 until 1900, after which the decline reached 5.5 by 1961.

60. Bennett et al., The Age of Entrepreneurship, 97–98.

61. Zeitlin, “The Historical Alternatives,” 129–131. See, for example, Scranton’s concept of batch production or Pine’s concept of mass customization: Scranton, Endless Novelty, 10–11; Pine, Mass Customization.

62. Harris and Buzzelli, “House Building in the Machine Age.”

63. Cf. Ive and Gruneberg, The Economics of the Modern Construction Sector; Pearce, The Social and Economic Value of Construction.

64. Some enterprises were registered in more than one professional category, since they performed more than one activity as portfolio businesses. They are listed with each of these activities in Figure 2, but were counted only once for the total figures in Tables 3 and 4, so these represent the accurate number of enterprises.

65. Marneffe, “De gietijzeren kachel”; Houbrechts, Artisans du bois.

66. Louw, “The Mechanisation, Part II”; Vandyck et al., “Brussels iron and steel builders.”

67. Loir, Bruxelles néoclassique.

68. Bertels, “Building Contractors”; Dobbels, Building a Profession.

69. Wellings, British Housebuilders.

70. Buyst, An Economic History, 177–180; Dobbels, Building a Profession.

71. Powell, An Economic History, 71–72, 113.

72. Degraeve, “From Lead Casters to Sanitary Installers.”

73. Buzzelli, “Firm Size Structure”; Wellings, British Housebuilders, 27–29; Nicol and Hooper, “Contemporary Change,” 59.

74. Rodger, “Speculative Builders,” 237.

75. Wardley, “On the Ranking of Firms,” 131; Heyrman, “Les petits commerçants,” 271.

76. Wellings, British Housebuilders, 30.

77. Martini, Bâtiment en famille, 43; Storey, Understanding, 8; Atkinson and Storey, eds., Employment.

78. Bennett et al., The Age of Entrepreneurship, 121–126.

79. Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, “Les patentables,” 75; Hannes, De economische bedrijvigheid, 15.

80. Cooney, “Long Waves in Building”; Knotter, “Bouwgolven in Amsterdam.”

81. Knotter, “De Amsterdamse bouwnijverheid,” 124–125; Martini, Bâtiment en famille, 363–364.

82. Lemmens, “Kritische en methodologische beschouwingen,” 216.

83. Eighty-four of 705 (11.9%) construction entrepreneurs whose number of workers was listed in the patent register obtained a new patent during 1864 because their number of workers had increased.

84. Rodger, “Structural instability,” 50–53.

85. Her narrower delineation of the construction sector compelled me to compare my figures with hers for the construction, wood, and metal industries taken together: Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, “Les patentables.”

86. Buzzelli, “Firm Size Structure.”

87. Bennett et al., The Age of Entrepreneurship, 133; Jaumain, Les petits commerçants; Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, “Les patentables,” 77–78.

88. As was also demonstrated by Rodger, “Structural instability,” 52.

89. De Brabander, Regionale structuur, 16–26, 88–90.

90. Bertels, “Building Contractors,” 4; Buyst, An Economic History, 137.

91. Kruithof, “De sociale samenstelling,” 224; Hannes, De economische bedrijvigheid. For 1864, self-employed entrepreneurs were considered by estimating some 547 self-employed, based on the number of entrepreneurs listed in the 1866 almanacs in the city of Brussels who were absent from the 1864 patent registers.

92. Buyst, An Economic History, 137.

93. De Brabander, De regionaal-sectoriële verdeling.

94. Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, “Les patentables,” 78.

95. Contractors and bricklayers acted as communicating vessels in industry censuses for a while, which explains the counteracting trend between 1896 and 1910.

96. Clarke, Building Capitalism.

97. Bertels, “Building Contractors.”

98. Billiet en Verstappen, “De aanleg van de Blaesstraat”; Content, “L’habitat ouvrier.”

99. Wellings, British Housebuilders, 137, 167–168, 249–263.

100. This should be nuanced because the 1937 figures probably represent an overestimation of firm sizes due to the exclusion of self-employed entrepreneurs.

101. Martini, Bâtiment en famille, 45.

102. Buzzelli, “Firm Size Structure.”

103. Willems and Buelens, “Belgische vennootschapsvormen.”

104. Hannah, “Corporations,” 867–70; Payne, British Entrepreneurship, 17; Payne, “Family Business in Britain,” 172–74; Lamoreaux, “Constructing Firms,” 44; Lamoreaux and Rosenthal, “Contractual Tradeoffs,” 32–40; Guinnane et al., “Contractual Freedom.”

105. Pollard, The Genesis, 153; Hannah, “The “Divorce” of Ownership,” 404; Hannah, “Corporations,” 869; Lamoreaux, “Constructing Firms,” 43; Lamoreaux and Rosenthal, “Contractual Tradeoffs,” 5–12; Guinnane et al., “Putting the Corporation in Its Place,” 703–8.

106. Cottrell, Industrial Finance, 236–44; Davidoff, Thicker Than Water, 57–58; Capie and Collins, “Industrial Lending”; Owens, “Inheritance and the Life-Cycle.”

107. Casson, The Entrepreneur, 169–170; Bennett et al., The Age of Entrepreneurship, 162; Crossick and Haupt, The petite bourgeoisie, 98–99.

108. Smith et al., “Households and Entrepreneurship”; Jaumain, Les petits commerçants, 555–56.

109. Smith et al., “Households and entrepreneurship.”

110. In the 1881 census, the explicit partnership rate for construction was underestimated, evidencing the limitations of the census instructions. Bennett, “Interpreting Business Partnerships,” 1199–1227.

111. Bennett, “Interpreting Business Partnerships.”

112. The description of this and the following forms of business incorporation is based on Willems and Buelens, “Belgische vennootschapsvormen.”

113. Hilt and O’Banion, “The Limited Partnership.”

114. The 3 “SPRLs” that already existed in 1932 were British or American “Ltd.” companies active in Brussels.

115. Bennett et al., The Age of Entrepreneurship, 128–134.

116. Chandler, Scale and Scope; Hannah, “Corporations”; Hannah and Kay, Concentration in Modern Industry; Wardley, “The Emergence of Big Business”; Landes, The Unbound Prometheus; Prais, The Evolution of Giant Firms.

117. Chandler, “The Railroads”; Chandler, The Visible Hand, chapters 3–5.

118. Harris and Buzzelli, “House Building in the Machine Age.”

119. Such as those recently performed by Bennett et al.

References

Bibliography of Works Cited

Atkinson, John, and Storey, David, eds. Employment, the Small Firm and the Labour Market. London: Routledge, 1994.Google Scholar
Barras, Richard, Building Cycles. Growth & Instability. London: Wiley-Blackwell, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J. The Microtheory of Innovative Entrepreneurship. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Bennett, Robert J., Smith, Harry, van Lieshout, Carry, Montebruno, Piero, and Newton, Gill. The Age of Entrepreneurship. Business Proprietors, Self-Employment and Corporations Since 1851 - Routledge International Studies in Business History. Routledge International Studies in Business History, London: Taylor and Francis, 2019.Google Scholar
Blondé, Bruno. Een economie met verschillende snelheden: ongelijkheden in de opbouw and de ontwikkeling van het Brabantse stedelijke netwerk (ca. 1750 - ca. 1790). Brussels: Paleis der Academieën, 1999.Google Scholar
Buyst, Erik. An Economic History of Residential Building in Belgium Between 1890 and 1961, Studies in Social and Economic History 23. Leuven: Universitaire Pers Leuven, 1992.Google Scholar
Casson, Mark. Entrepreneurship: Theory, Networks, History. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casson, Mark. The Entrepreneur: An Economic Theory. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield, 1982.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. The visible hand. The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, Linda. Building Capitalism: Historical Change and the Labour Process in the Production of the Built Environment. London: Routledge, 1992.Google Scholar
Cottrell, Philip L. Industrial Finance, 1830-1914: The Finance and Organization of English Manufacturing Industry. London: Methuen, 1980.Google Scholar
Crossick, Geoffrey, and Haupt, Heinz-Gerhard. The Petite Bourgeoisie in Europe 1780-1914. Enterprise, Family and Independence. London: Routledge, 1995.Google Scholar
Davidoff, Leonore. Thicker Than Water: Siblings and Their Relations, 1780-1920. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2012.Google Scholar
De Brabander, Guido. Regionale structuur and werkgelegenheid. Een economische and geografische studie over de Belgische lange-termijn-ontwikkeling. Brussels: Paleis der Academieën, 1983.Google Scholar
De Brabander, Guido. De regionaal-sectoriële verdeling van de economische activiteit in België (1846-1979): een kritische studie van het bronnenmateriaal. Leuven: Nauwelaerts, 1984.Google Scholar
Dijk, Pauline van. Appartementsgebouwen uit het interbellum. Brussels: Brussels Hoofdstedelijk Gewest, 2006.Google Scholar
Dobbels, Jelena. Building a Profession. A History of General Contractors in Belgium. Brussels: VUBPress, 2021.Google Scholar
Galavan, Susan. Dublin’s Bourgeois Homes. Building the Victorian Suburbs, 1850-1901. London: Routledge, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerwen, Jacques van, and de Goey, Ferry. Ondernemers in Nederland - Variaties in ondernemen. Bedrijfsleven in Nederland in de Twintigste Eeuw (BINT) 1, Amsterdam: Boom, 2008.Google Scholar
Goffee, Robert, and Scase, Richard. The Entrepreneurial Middle Class. London: Croom Helm, 1982.Google Scholar
Hannah, Leslie, and Kay, J.A.. Concentration in Modern Industry: Theory, Measurement and the UK Experience. London: MacMillan, 1977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannes, Juul. De economische bedrijvigheid te Brussel, 1846-1847. Controle en aanvulling van de nijverheidstelling van 15-10-1846. Paris: Nauwelaerts, 1975.Google Scholar
Harloe, Michael, Isaacharoff, Ruth, and Minns, Richard. The Organization of Housing: Public and Private Enterprise in London. London: Heinemann, 1974.Google Scholar
Harris, Richard. Building a Market: The Rise of the Home Improvement Industry, 1914–1960. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heymans, Vincent. Les dimensions d’ordinaire: la maison particulière entre mitoyens à Bruxelles. Fin XIXème - début XXème siècle. Paris: L’Harmattan, 1998.Google Scholar
Hillebrandt, Patricia. Economic Theory and the Construction Industry. London: MacMillan, 1974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houbrechts, David, Artisans du bois en Wallonie et à Bruxelles. Hier et aujourd’hui. Namur: Institut du Patrimoine wallon, 2015.Google Scholar
Ive, Graham, and Gruneberg, Stephen L., The Economics of the Modern Construction Sector. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, Jane. The Economy of Cities. New York: Random House, 1969.Google Scholar
Jaumain, Serge. Les petits commerçants belges face à la modernité (1880-1914). Brussels: Editions de l’Université Libre de Bruxelles, 1995.Google Scholar
Landes, David S. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Ledent, Gérald, and Porotto, Alessandro. Brussels Housing: Atlas of Residential Building Types. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter GmbH, 2023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loir, Christophe. Bruxelles néoclassique. Mutation de l’espace urbain (1775-1840). Brussels: cfc éditions, 2017.Google Scholar
Martini, Manuela. Bâtiment and famille: migrations et petite entreprise and banlieue parisienne au XXe siècle. Paris: CNRS, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Middlemas, Robert Keith. The Master Builders, London: Hutchinson, 1963.Google Scholar
Payne, Peter Lester. British Entrepreneurship in the Nineteenth Century. London: Macmillan International Higher Education, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
David, Pearce, The Social and Economic Value of Construction: The Construction Industry’s Contribution to Sustainable Development. London: Construction Industry Research and Innovation Strategy Panel, 2003.Google Scholar
Pine, B. Joseph. Mass Customization: The New Frontier in Business Competition. Harvard Business School Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Piore, Michael, and Sabel, Charles. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books, 1984.Google Scholar
Pollard, Sidney. The Genesis of Modern Management: A Study of the Industrial Revolution in Great Britain. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Powell, Christopher. An Economic History of the British Building Industry, 1815-1979. London: Architectural Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Prais, S.J. The Evolution of Giant Firms in Britain: A Study of the Growth of Concentration in Manufacturing Industry in Britain 1909-1970. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Rilling, Donna J. Making Houses, Crafting Capitalism. Builders in Philadelphia, 1790-1850. Pennsylvania: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Scranton, Philip. Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1997.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storey, David. Understanding the Small Business Sector. London: Routledge, 1994.Google Scholar
Vries, Jan de, and van der Woude, Ad. Nederland 1500-1815. De eerste ronde van moderne economische groei. Amsterdam: Balans, 1995.Google Scholar
Wagenaar, Michiel. Stedebouw en burgerlijke vrijheid: de contrasterende carrières van zes Europese hoofdsteden. Bussum: Thoth, 1998.Google Scholar
Wellings, Fred. British Housebuilders: History and Analysis. London: John Wiley & Sons, 2008.Google Scholar
Whitehand, Jeremy W.R. The Making of the Urban Landscape. Oxford: Blackwell, 1992.Google Scholar
Woodward, Donald. Men at work. Labourers and Building Craftsmen in the Towns of Northern England, 1450-1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baer, William C.The house-building sector of London’s economy.” Urban History 39, no. 3 (2012): 409430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, Michael. “The International Restructuring of Housing Provision,” In Housing and Social Change in Europe and the U.S.A., eds. Ball, Michael, Harloe, Michael, and Martens, Maartje, 169198. London: Routledge, 1988.Google Scholar
Barlow, James. “From Craft Production to Mass Customisation. Innovation Requirements for the UK Housebuilding Industry.” Housing Studies 14, no. 1 (1999): 2342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennett, Robert J.Interpreting Business Partnerships in Late Victorian Britain.” The Economic History Review 69, no. 4 (2016): 11991227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertels, Inge. “Building Contractors in Late-nineteenth-century Belgium: From Craftsmen to Contractors.” Construction History 26 (2011): 118.Google Scholar
Bertels, Inge. “Building the City, Antwerp 1819-1890.” PhD dissertation, KU Leuven, 2008.Google Scholar
Bertels, Inge, Deneweth, Heidi, Horemans, Boris, and Van de Voorde, Stephanie. “Pour une historiographie de l”entrepreneur du bâtiment (1400-2000),” in Les temps de la construction. Processus, acteurs, matériaux: Recueil de textes issus du deuxième congrès francophone d’histoire de la construction, eds. Fleury, François, Baridon, Laurent, Mastrorilli, Antonella, Mouterde, Rémy, and Reveyron, Nicolas, 11891199. Paris: Picard, 2016.Google Scholar
Billiet, Patrick, and Verstappen, Alain. “De aanleg van de Blaesstraat te Brussel, 1853–1860, een stedebouwkundige en historische analyse.” PhD-dissertation, KU Leuven, 1981.Google Scholar
Breman, Jan. “A Short History of the Informal Economy.” Global Labour Journal 14, no. 1 (2023).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzzelli, Michael. “Firm Size Structure in North American Housebuilding: Persistent Deconcentration, 1945–1998.” Environment and Planning A 33 (2001): 533–450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzzelli, Michael, and Harris, Richard. “Cities as the Industrial Districts of Housebuilding.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 30, no. 4 (2006): 894917.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capie, Forrest, and Collins, Michael. “Industrial Lending by English Commercial Banks, 1860s–1914: Why Did Banks Refuse Loans?Business History 38, no. 1 (1996): 2644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D.The Railroads: Pioneers in Modern Corporate Management.” The Business History Review 39, no. 1 (1965): 1640.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Châtelain, Abel. “Une grande industrie motrice française attardée: le bâtiment.” Annales. Economies, Sociétés, Civilisations 13, no. 3 (1958): 573585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Content, A.C.L’habitat ouvrier à Bruxelles au XIXe siècle.” Belgisch Tijdschrift voor Nieuwste Geschiedenis 8, no. 3–4 (1977): 501517.Google Scholar
Cooney, E. W.Long Waves in Building in the British Economy of the Nineteenth Century.” The Economic History Review 13, no. 2 (1960): 257269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daelemans, F.De bevolking,” in Het gewest Brussel. Van de oude dorpen tot de stad van nu, ed. Smolar-Meynart, Arlette and Stengers, Jean, 212217. Brussels: Gemeentekrediet, 1989.Google Scholar
De Boeck, Sarah, Bassens, David, and Ryckewaert, Michael. “Making Space for a More Foundational Economy: The Case of the Construction Sector in Brussels.” Geoforum 105 (2019): 6777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Debroux, Tatiana. “Des artistes and ville. Géographie rétrospective des plasticiens à Bruxelles (1833-2008).” PhD-dissertation, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 2012.Google Scholar
Degraeve, Matthijs. “From Lead Casters to Sanitary Installers. The Evolution of the Plumbing Trade in Nineteenth-century Brussels.” Construction History 37, no. 2 (2022): 87105.Google Scholar
Dobbels, Jelena. “Becoming Professional Practitioners. A History of Feneral Contractors in Belgium (1870-1970).” PhD-dissertation, Vrije Universiteit Brussel, 2018.Google Scholar
Duchêne, Vincent. “De brutobinnenlandse kapitaalvorming in woongebouwen in België tussen 1830 en 1890: reconstructie en analyse van de investeringen en van het investeringsgedrag.” PhD-dissertation, KU Leuven, 2000.Google Scholar
Eccles, R.G.The Quasifirm in the Construction Industry.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 2 (1981): 335357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guinnane, Timothy, Harris, Ron, Lamoreaux, Naomi R., and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. “Putting the Corporation in Its Place.” Enterprise & Society 8, 3 (2007): 687729.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guinnane, Timothy W., Harris, Ron, and Lamoreaux, Naomi R.. “Contractual Freedom and Corporate Governance in Britain in the Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries.” Business History Review 91, no. 2 (2017): 227277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannah, Leslie. “Corporations in the US and Europe 1790–1860.” Business History 56, no. 6 (2014): 865899.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannah, Leslie. “The “Divorce” of Ownership from Control from 1900 Onwards: Re-calibrating Imagined Global Trends.” Business History 49, no. 4 (2007): 404438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, Richard, and Buzzelli, Michael. “House Building in the Machine Age, 1920s-1970s. Realities and Perceptions of Modernization in North America.” Business History 47, no. 1 (2005): 5985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heyrman, Peter. “Les petits commerçants et les artisans.” In Les classes sociales and Belgique: deux siècles d”histoire, edited by Vanthemsche, Guy, 267310. Brussels: CRISP, 2016.Google Scholar
Hilt, Eric, and O’Banion, Katharine. “The Limited Partnership in New York 1822–1858: Partnerships without Kinship.” The Journal of Economic History 69, no. 3 (2009): 615645.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knotter, Ad. “De Amsterdamse bouwnijverheid in de 19e eeuw tot ca. 1870. Loonstarheid and trekarbeid op een dubbele arbeidsmarkt.” Tijdschrift voor Sociale Geschiedenis 10, no. 2 (1984): 123154.Google Scholar
Kruithof, Jaap. “De sociale samenstelling van de bevolking te Antwerpen, Brussel, Gent and Luik in 1846-1847.” Handelingen der Maatschappij voor Geschiedenis and Oudheidkunde te Gent 11 (1957): 197235.Google Scholar
Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, Régine. “Les patentables à Bruxelles au XIXe siècle.” Le Mouvement Social 108 (1979): 6388.Google Scholar
Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, Régine, and Vire, G.. “Les registres des patentables, source de l’histoire de Bruxelles à la fin du XIXe siècle.” Acta Historica Bruxellensia 4 (1981): 367415.Google Scholar
Lacoste, Yves. “Aspects géographiques généraux des industries de la construction.” Annales de Géographie 68, no. 366 (1959): 121153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R.Constructing Firms: Partnerships and Alternative Contractual Arrangements in Early Nineteenth-Century American Business.” Business and Economic History 24, no. 2 (1995): 4371.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R., and Rosenthal, J.-L.. “Contractual Tradeoffs and SMEs’ Choice of Organizational Form: A View from U.S. and French History, 1830-2000.” American Law and Economics Review 7 (2005): 2861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lemmens, P.Kritische and methodologische beschouwingen bij het gebruik van de patentbelasting als bron voor kwantitatief, dynamisch and stratificerend onderzoek,” in Bijdragen tot de geschiedenis van Vlaanderen and Brabant. Sociaal and Economisch, eds. Craeybeckx, Jan and Daelemans, Frank, 211239. Brussels: Vrije Universiteit Brussel, 1988.Google Scholar
Louw, Hentie. “The Mechanisation of Architectural Woodwork in Britain from the Late-Eighteenth to the Early-Twentieth Century, and its Practical, Social and Aesthetic implications. Part II: Technological Progress c. 1860 to c. 1915.” Construction History 9 (1993): 2750.Google Scholar
Lund, Joachim. “Building Hitler’s Europe: Forced Labor in the Danish Construction Business during World War II.” Business History Review 84, no. 3 (2010): 479499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marneffe, Françoise, “De gietijzeren kachel. Een revolutionair object.” Erfgoed Brussel 33 (2020): 8299.Google Scholar
McKenna, J. A., and Rodger, Richard G.. “Control by Coercion: Employers’ Associations and the Establishment of Industrial Order in the Building Industry of England and Wales, 1860–1914.” Business History Review 59, no. 2 (1985): 203231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLean, David. “Constructors in a Foreign Land: Messrs. Lynch & Co. on the Bakhtiari road 1897–1913.” Business History 54, no. 4 (2012): 487509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. “Entrepreneurship and the Industrial Revolution in Britain,” in The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times, eds. Landes, David S., Mokyr, Joel, and Baumol, William J.. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Nicol, Chris, and Hooper, Alan. “Contemporary Change and the Housebuilding Industry: Concentration and Standardisation in Production.” Housing Studies 14, no. 1 (1999): 5776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owens, Alastair. “Inheritance and the Life-Cycle of Family Firms in the Early Industrial Revolution.” Business History 44, no. 1 (2002): 2146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parisel, Claire. “Les artisans de la Ville de Bruxelles de 1816 à 1860.” Master dissertation, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 1961.Google Scholar
Payne, Peter Lester. “Family Business in Britain: An Historical and Analytical Survey,” in Family business in the Era of Industrial Growth: Its Ownership and Management, eds. Okochi, A. and Yasuoka, S., 171206. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Powell, Christopher. “He That Runs Against Time: Life Expectancy of Building Firms in Nineteenth Century Bristol.” Construction History 2 (1986): 6167.Google Scholar
Rabeneck, Andrew. “Recent Geopolitics of Construction - Origins and Consequences,” in Building Knowledge, Constructing Histories. Proceedings of the Sixth International Congress on Construction History, ed. Wouters, Ine et al., vol. 2: 10891096. London: CRC Press, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rauhut, Christophe. “La mécanisation: fiction et réalité.” In L’art du chantier. Construire et démolir du XVIe au XXIe siècle, ed. Nègre, Valérie, 8487. Paris: Cité de l’architecture et du patrimoine, 2018.Google Scholar
Rodger, Richard. “Speculative Builders and the Structure of the Scottish Building Industry, 1860–1914.” Business History 21, no. 2 (1979): 226246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodger, Richard. “Structural Instability in the Scottish Building Industry 1820-80.” Construction History 2 (1986): 4860.Google Scholar
Sabel, Charles, and Zeitlin, Jonathan. “Historical Alternatives to Mass Production: Politics, Markets and Technology in Nineteenth-Century Industrialization.” Past and Present 108 (1985): 133176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlesinger, Tom, and Erlich, Mark. “Housing: The Industry Capitalism Did Not Forget,” in Critical Perspectives on Housing, eds. Bratt, Rachel, Hartman, Chester, and Meyerson, Ann, 139164. Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Schmitz, Nelly, and Ducuroir, Michel. “Vers l’industrialisation du bâtiment and Belgique.” Cahiers Economiques de Bruxelles 49 (1971).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A.The Creative Response in Economic History.” The Journal of Economic History 7, no. 2 (1947): 149159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, Peter. “Friends in High Places: Government-Industry Relations in Public Sector House-Building During Britain’s Tower Block Era.” Business History 62, no. 4 (2020): 545–465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Harry, Bennett, Robert J., van Lieshout, Carry, and Montebruno, Piero. “Households and entrepreneurship in England and Wales, 1851–1911.” The History of the Family 26, no. 1 (2021): 100122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Lawrence B., Rosen, Kenneth T., Markandya, Anil, and Ullmo, Pierre-Antoine. “The Demand for Housing, Household Headship Rates, and Household Formation: An International Analysis.” Urban Studies 21, no. 4 (1984): 407414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephenson, Judy Z.The Economic Institutions of Construction in London after the Great Fire.” Enterprise & Society 20, no. 1 (2019): 229252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuckman, Alan. “Looking Backwards: Historical Specificity of the Labour Process in Construction.” Production of the Built Environment 2 (1981): 5460.Google Scholar
Van Uytven, Raymond. “Peiling naar de beroepsstructuur op het Brabantse platteland omstreeks 1755.” Bijdragen tot de geschiedenis 55 (1972): 172203.Google Scholar
Vandermotten, Christian. “De Brusselse industrie. Twee en een halve eeuw evolutie.” Erfgoed Brussel 1516 (2015): 8–21.Google Scholar
Vandermotten, Christian. “Ebauche d’une macrogéographie de l’industrie en Belgique, 1846-1970.” PhD-dissertation, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 1978.Google Scholar
Vandyck, Frederik, Degraeve, Matthijs, and Van de Voorde, Stephanie. “Brussels Iron and Steel Builders in the 19th and 20th Centuries: A Macroeconomic and Spatial Exploration,” in History of Construction Cultures. Proceedings of the 7th International Congress on Construction History, eds. Mascarenhas-Mateus, João and Pires, Ana Paula, vol. 1: 479487. London: CRC Press, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vejzagić, Saša. “Persistent Centralisation of Decision-Making in the Age of Industrial Atomisation and Self-Management on the Case of Construction Company Industrogradnja Zagreb (1966–1980).” Business History (2023).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wardley, Peter. “Debate - On the Ranking of Firms: A Response to Jeremy and Farnie.” Business History 43, no. 3 (2001): 119134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wardley, Peter. “The Emergence of Big Business: The Largest Corporate Employers of Labour in the United Kingdom, Germany and the United States, c. 1907.” Business History 41, no. 4 (1999): 88116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whaples, Robert. “Economic History and Entrepreneurship,” in Routledge Handbook of Modern Economic History, eds. Whaples, R. and Parker, R.E., 7181. London: Routledge, 2013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willems, Hans, and Buelens, Frans. “Belgische vennootschapsvormen in de negentiende en de twintigste eeuw,” in Een succesvolle onderneming: handleiding voor het schrijven van een bedrijfsgeschiedenis, ed. Vancoppenolle, Chantal, 171208. Brussels: Algemeen Rijksarchief, 2005.Google Scholar
Zeitlin, Jonathan. “The Historical Alternatives Approach,” in The Oxford Handbook of Business History, eds. Jones, Geoffrey and Zeitlin, Jonathan, 120140. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Brussels City Archives (BCA), Brussels, Belgium.Google Scholar
Atkinson, John, and Storey, David, eds. Employment, the Small Firm and the Labour Market. London: Routledge, 1994.Google Scholar
Barras, Richard, Building Cycles. Growth & Instability. London: Wiley-Blackwell, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J. The Microtheory of Innovative Entrepreneurship. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Bennett, Robert J., Smith, Harry, van Lieshout, Carry, Montebruno, Piero, and Newton, Gill. The Age of Entrepreneurship. Business Proprietors, Self-Employment and Corporations Since 1851 - Routledge International Studies in Business History. Routledge International Studies in Business History, London: Taylor and Francis, 2019.Google Scholar
Blondé, Bruno. Een economie met verschillende snelheden: ongelijkheden in de opbouw and de ontwikkeling van het Brabantse stedelijke netwerk (ca. 1750 - ca. 1790). Brussels: Paleis der Academieën, 1999.Google Scholar
Buyst, Erik. An Economic History of Residential Building in Belgium Between 1890 and 1961, Studies in Social and Economic History 23. Leuven: Universitaire Pers Leuven, 1992.Google Scholar
Casson, Mark. Entrepreneurship: Theory, Networks, History. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casson, Mark. The Entrepreneur: An Economic Theory. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield, 1982.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. The visible hand. The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, Linda. Building Capitalism: Historical Change and the Labour Process in the Production of the Built Environment. London: Routledge, 1992.Google Scholar
Cottrell, Philip L. Industrial Finance, 1830-1914: The Finance and Organization of English Manufacturing Industry. London: Methuen, 1980.Google Scholar
Crossick, Geoffrey, and Haupt, Heinz-Gerhard. The Petite Bourgeoisie in Europe 1780-1914. Enterprise, Family and Independence. London: Routledge, 1995.Google Scholar
Davidoff, Leonore. Thicker Than Water: Siblings and Their Relations, 1780-1920. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2012.Google Scholar
De Brabander, Guido. Regionale structuur and werkgelegenheid. Een economische and geografische studie over de Belgische lange-termijn-ontwikkeling. Brussels: Paleis der Academieën, 1983.Google Scholar
De Brabander, Guido. De regionaal-sectoriële verdeling van de economische activiteit in België (1846-1979): een kritische studie van het bronnenmateriaal. Leuven: Nauwelaerts, 1984.Google Scholar
Dijk, Pauline van. Appartementsgebouwen uit het interbellum. Brussels: Brussels Hoofdstedelijk Gewest, 2006.Google Scholar
Dobbels, Jelena. Building a Profession. A History of General Contractors in Belgium. Brussels: VUBPress, 2021.Google Scholar
Galavan, Susan. Dublin’s Bourgeois Homes. Building the Victorian Suburbs, 1850-1901. London: Routledge, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerwen, Jacques van, and de Goey, Ferry. Ondernemers in Nederland - Variaties in ondernemen. Bedrijfsleven in Nederland in de Twintigste Eeuw (BINT) 1, Amsterdam: Boom, 2008.Google Scholar
Goffee, Robert, and Scase, Richard. The Entrepreneurial Middle Class. London: Croom Helm, 1982.Google Scholar
Hannah, Leslie, and Kay, J.A.. Concentration in Modern Industry: Theory, Measurement and the UK Experience. London: MacMillan, 1977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannes, Juul. De economische bedrijvigheid te Brussel, 1846-1847. Controle en aanvulling van de nijverheidstelling van 15-10-1846. Paris: Nauwelaerts, 1975.Google Scholar
Harloe, Michael, Isaacharoff, Ruth, and Minns, Richard. The Organization of Housing: Public and Private Enterprise in London. London: Heinemann, 1974.Google Scholar
Harris, Richard. Building a Market: The Rise of the Home Improvement Industry, 1914–1960. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heymans, Vincent. Les dimensions d’ordinaire: la maison particulière entre mitoyens à Bruxelles. Fin XIXème - début XXème siècle. Paris: L’Harmattan, 1998.Google Scholar
Hillebrandt, Patricia. Economic Theory and the Construction Industry. London: MacMillan, 1974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houbrechts, David, Artisans du bois en Wallonie et à Bruxelles. Hier et aujourd’hui. Namur: Institut du Patrimoine wallon, 2015.Google Scholar
Ive, Graham, and Gruneberg, Stephen L., The Economics of the Modern Construction Sector. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, Jane. The Economy of Cities. New York: Random House, 1969.Google Scholar
Jaumain, Serge. Les petits commerçants belges face à la modernité (1880-1914). Brussels: Editions de l’Université Libre de Bruxelles, 1995.Google Scholar
Landes, David S. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Ledent, Gérald, and Porotto, Alessandro. Brussels Housing: Atlas of Residential Building Types. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter GmbH, 2023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loir, Christophe. Bruxelles néoclassique. Mutation de l’espace urbain (1775-1840). Brussels: cfc éditions, 2017.Google Scholar
Martini, Manuela. Bâtiment and famille: migrations et petite entreprise and banlieue parisienne au XXe siècle. Paris: CNRS, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Middlemas, Robert Keith. The Master Builders, London: Hutchinson, 1963.Google Scholar
Payne, Peter Lester. British Entrepreneurship in the Nineteenth Century. London: Macmillan International Higher Education, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
David, Pearce, The Social and Economic Value of Construction: The Construction Industry’s Contribution to Sustainable Development. London: Construction Industry Research and Innovation Strategy Panel, 2003.Google Scholar
Pine, B. Joseph. Mass Customization: The New Frontier in Business Competition. Harvard Business School Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Piore, Michael, and Sabel, Charles. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books, 1984.Google Scholar
Pollard, Sidney. The Genesis of Modern Management: A Study of the Industrial Revolution in Great Britain. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Powell, Christopher. An Economic History of the British Building Industry, 1815-1979. London: Architectural Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Prais, S.J. The Evolution of Giant Firms in Britain: A Study of the Growth of Concentration in Manufacturing Industry in Britain 1909-1970. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Rilling, Donna J. Making Houses, Crafting Capitalism. Builders in Philadelphia, 1790-1850. Pennsylvania: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Scranton, Philip. Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1997.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Storey, David. Understanding the Small Business Sector. London: Routledge, 1994.Google Scholar
Vries, Jan de, and van der Woude, Ad. Nederland 1500-1815. De eerste ronde van moderne economische groei. Amsterdam: Balans, 1995.Google Scholar
Wagenaar, Michiel. Stedebouw en burgerlijke vrijheid: de contrasterende carrières van zes Europese hoofdsteden. Bussum: Thoth, 1998.Google Scholar
Wellings, Fred. British Housebuilders: History and Analysis. London: John Wiley & Sons, 2008.Google Scholar
Whitehand, Jeremy W.R. The Making of the Urban Landscape. Oxford: Blackwell, 1992.Google Scholar
Woodward, Donald. Men at work. Labourers and Building Craftsmen in the Towns of Northern England, 1450-1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baer, William C.The house-building sector of London’s economy.” Urban History 39, no. 3 (2012): 409430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, Michael. “The International Restructuring of Housing Provision,” In Housing and Social Change in Europe and the U.S.A., eds. Ball, Michael, Harloe, Michael, and Martens, Maartje, 169198. London: Routledge, 1988.Google Scholar
Barlow, James. “From Craft Production to Mass Customisation. Innovation Requirements for the UK Housebuilding Industry.” Housing Studies 14, no. 1 (1999): 2342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennett, Robert J.Interpreting Business Partnerships in Late Victorian Britain.” The Economic History Review 69, no. 4 (2016): 11991227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertels, Inge. “Building Contractors in Late-nineteenth-century Belgium: From Craftsmen to Contractors.” Construction History 26 (2011): 118.Google Scholar
Bertels, Inge. “Building the City, Antwerp 1819-1890.” PhD dissertation, KU Leuven, 2008.Google Scholar
Bertels, Inge, Deneweth, Heidi, Horemans, Boris, and Van de Voorde, Stephanie. “Pour une historiographie de l”entrepreneur du bâtiment (1400-2000),” in Les temps de la construction. Processus, acteurs, matériaux: Recueil de textes issus du deuxième congrès francophone d’histoire de la construction, eds. Fleury, François, Baridon, Laurent, Mastrorilli, Antonella, Mouterde, Rémy, and Reveyron, Nicolas, 11891199. Paris: Picard, 2016.Google Scholar
Billiet, Patrick, and Verstappen, Alain. “De aanleg van de Blaesstraat te Brussel, 1853–1860, een stedebouwkundige en historische analyse.” PhD-dissertation, KU Leuven, 1981.Google Scholar
Breman, Jan. “A Short History of the Informal Economy.” Global Labour Journal 14, no. 1 (2023).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzzelli, Michael. “Firm Size Structure in North American Housebuilding: Persistent Deconcentration, 1945–1998.” Environment and Planning A 33 (2001): 533–450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzzelli, Michael, and Harris, Richard. “Cities as the Industrial Districts of Housebuilding.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 30, no. 4 (2006): 894917.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capie, Forrest, and Collins, Michael. “Industrial Lending by English Commercial Banks, 1860s–1914: Why Did Banks Refuse Loans?Business History 38, no. 1 (1996): 2644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D.The Railroads: Pioneers in Modern Corporate Management.” The Business History Review 39, no. 1 (1965): 1640.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Châtelain, Abel. “Une grande industrie motrice française attardée: le bâtiment.” Annales. Economies, Sociétés, Civilisations 13, no. 3 (1958): 573585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Content, A.C.L’habitat ouvrier à Bruxelles au XIXe siècle.” Belgisch Tijdschrift voor Nieuwste Geschiedenis 8, no. 3–4 (1977): 501517.Google Scholar
Cooney, E. W.Long Waves in Building in the British Economy of the Nineteenth Century.” The Economic History Review 13, no. 2 (1960): 257269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daelemans, F.De bevolking,” in Het gewest Brussel. Van de oude dorpen tot de stad van nu, ed. Smolar-Meynart, Arlette and Stengers, Jean, 212217. Brussels: Gemeentekrediet, 1989.Google Scholar
De Boeck, Sarah, Bassens, David, and Ryckewaert, Michael. “Making Space for a More Foundational Economy: The Case of the Construction Sector in Brussels.” Geoforum 105 (2019): 6777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Debroux, Tatiana. “Des artistes and ville. Géographie rétrospective des plasticiens à Bruxelles (1833-2008).” PhD-dissertation, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 2012.Google Scholar
Degraeve, Matthijs. “From Lead Casters to Sanitary Installers. The Evolution of the Plumbing Trade in Nineteenth-century Brussels.” Construction History 37, no. 2 (2022): 87105.Google Scholar
Dobbels, Jelena. “Becoming Professional Practitioners. A History of Feneral Contractors in Belgium (1870-1970).” PhD-dissertation, Vrije Universiteit Brussel, 2018.Google Scholar
Duchêne, Vincent. “De brutobinnenlandse kapitaalvorming in woongebouwen in België tussen 1830 en 1890: reconstructie en analyse van de investeringen en van het investeringsgedrag.” PhD-dissertation, KU Leuven, 2000.Google Scholar
Eccles, R.G.The Quasifirm in the Construction Industry.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 2 (1981): 335357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guinnane, Timothy, Harris, Ron, Lamoreaux, Naomi R., and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. “Putting the Corporation in Its Place.” Enterprise & Society 8, 3 (2007): 687729.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guinnane, Timothy W., Harris, Ron, and Lamoreaux, Naomi R.. “Contractual Freedom and Corporate Governance in Britain in the Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries.” Business History Review 91, no. 2 (2017): 227277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannah, Leslie. “Corporations in the US and Europe 1790–1860.” Business History 56, no. 6 (2014): 865899.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannah, Leslie. “The “Divorce” of Ownership from Control from 1900 Onwards: Re-calibrating Imagined Global Trends.” Business History 49, no. 4 (2007): 404438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, Richard, and Buzzelli, Michael. “House Building in the Machine Age, 1920s-1970s. Realities and Perceptions of Modernization in North America.” Business History 47, no. 1 (2005): 5985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heyrman, Peter. “Les petits commerçants et les artisans.” In Les classes sociales and Belgique: deux siècles d”histoire, edited by Vanthemsche, Guy, 267310. Brussels: CRISP, 2016.Google Scholar
Hilt, Eric, and O’Banion, Katharine. “The Limited Partnership in New York 1822–1858: Partnerships without Kinship.” The Journal of Economic History 69, no. 3 (2009): 615645.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knotter, Ad. “De Amsterdamse bouwnijverheid in de 19e eeuw tot ca. 1870. Loonstarheid and trekarbeid op een dubbele arbeidsmarkt.” Tijdschrift voor Sociale Geschiedenis 10, no. 2 (1984): 123154.Google Scholar
Kruithof, Jaap. “De sociale samenstelling van de bevolking te Antwerpen, Brussel, Gent and Luik in 1846-1847.” Handelingen der Maatschappij voor Geschiedenis and Oudheidkunde te Gent 11 (1957): 197235.Google Scholar
Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, Régine. “Les patentables à Bruxelles au XIXe siècle.” Le Mouvement Social 108 (1979): 6388.Google Scholar
Kurgan-Van Hentenrijk, Régine, and Vire, G.. “Les registres des patentables, source de l’histoire de Bruxelles à la fin du XIXe siècle.” Acta Historica Bruxellensia 4 (1981): 367415.Google Scholar
Lacoste, Yves. “Aspects géographiques généraux des industries de la construction.” Annales de Géographie 68, no. 366 (1959): 121153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R.Constructing Firms: Partnerships and Alternative Contractual Arrangements in Early Nineteenth-Century American Business.” Business and Economic History 24, no. 2 (1995): 4371.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R., and Rosenthal, J.-L.. “Contractual Tradeoffs and SMEs’ Choice of Organizational Form: A View from U.S. and French History, 1830-2000.” American Law and Economics Review 7 (2005): 2861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lemmens, P.Kritische and methodologische beschouwingen bij het gebruik van de patentbelasting als bron voor kwantitatief, dynamisch and stratificerend onderzoek,” in Bijdragen tot de geschiedenis van Vlaanderen and Brabant. Sociaal and Economisch, eds. Craeybeckx, Jan and Daelemans, Frank, 211239. Brussels: Vrije Universiteit Brussel, 1988.Google Scholar
Louw, Hentie. “The Mechanisation of Architectural Woodwork in Britain from the Late-Eighteenth to the Early-Twentieth Century, and its Practical, Social and Aesthetic implications. Part II: Technological Progress c. 1860 to c. 1915.” Construction History 9 (1993): 2750.Google Scholar
Lund, Joachim. “Building Hitler’s Europe: Forced Labor in the Danish Construction Business during World War II.” Business History Review 84, no. 3 (2010): 479499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marneffe, Françoise, “De gietijzeren kachel. Een revolutionair object.” Erfgoed Brussel 33 (2020): 8299.Google Scholar
McKenna, J. A., and Rodger, Richard G.. “Control by Coercion: Employers’ Associations and the Establishment of Industrial Order in the Building Industry of England and Wales, 1860–1914.” Business History Review 59, no. 2 (1985): 203231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLean, David. “Constructors in a Foreign Land: Messrs. Lynch & Co. on the Bakhtiari road 1897–1913.” Business History 54, no. 4 (2012): 487509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. “Entrepreneurship and the Industrial Revolution in Britain,” in The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times, eds. Landes, David S., Mokyr, Joel, and Baumol, William J.. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010.Google Scholar
Nicol, Chris, and Hooper, Alan. “Contemporary Change and the Housebuilding Industry: Concentration and Standardisation in Production.” Housing Studies 14, no. 1 (1999): 5776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owens, Alastair. “Inheritance and the Life-Cycle of Family Firms in the Early Industrial Revolution.” Business History 44, no. 1 (2002): 2146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parisel, Claire. “Les artisans de la Ville de Bruxelles de 1816 à 1860.” Master dissertation, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 1961.Google Scholar
Payne, Peter Lester. “Family Business in Britain: An Historical and Analytical Survey,” in Family business in the Era of Industrial Growth: Its Ownership and Management, eds. Okochi, A. and Yasuoka, S., 171206. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Powell, Christopher. “He That Runs Against Time: Life Expectancy of Building Firms in Nineteenth Century Bristol.” Construction History 2 (1986): 6167.Google Scholar
Rabeneck, Andrew. “Recent Geopolitics of Construction - Origins and Consequences,” in Building Knowledge, Constructing Histories. Proceedings of the Sixth International Congress on Construction History, ed. Wouters, Ine et al., vol. 2: 10891096. London: CRC Press, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rauhut, Christophe. “La mécanisation: fiction et réalité.” In L’art du chantier. Construire et démolir du XVIe au XXIe siècle, ed. Nègre, Valérie, 8487. Paris: Cité de l’architecture et du patrimoine, 2018.Google Scholar
Rodger, Richard. “Speculative Builders and the Structure of the Scottish Building Industry, 1860–1914.” Business History 21, no. 2 (1979): 226246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodger, Richard. “Structural Instability in the Scottish Building Industry 1820-80.” Construction History 2 (1986): 4860.Google Scholar
Sabel, Charles, and Zeitlin, Jonathan. “Historical Alternatives to Mass Production: Politics, Markets and Technology in Nineteenth-Century Industrialization.” Past and Present 108 (1985): 133176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlesinger, Tom, and Erlich, Mark. “Housing: The Industry Capitalism Did Not Forget,” in Critical Perspectives on Housing, eds. Bratt, Rachel, Hartman, Chester, and Meyerson, Ann, 139164. Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Schmitz, Nelly, and Ducuroir, Michel. “Vers l’industrialisation du bâtiment and Belgique.” Cahiers Economiques de Bruxelles 49 (1971).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A.The Creative Response in Economic History.” The Journal of Economic History 7, no. 2 (1947): 149159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, Peter. “Friends in High Places: Government-Industry Relations in Public Sector House-Building During Britain’s Tower Block Era.” Business History 62, no. 4 (2020): 545–465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Harry, Bennett, Robert J., van Lieshout, Carry, and Montebruno, Piero. “Households and entrepreneurship in England and Wales, 1851–1911.” The History of the Family 26, no. 1 (2021): 100122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Lawrence B., Rosen, Kenneth T., Markandya, Anil, and Ullmo, Pierre-Antoine. “The Demand for Housing, Household Headship Rates, and Household Formation: An International Analysis.” Urban Studies 21, no. 4 (1984): 407414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephenson, Judy Z.The Economic Institutions of Construction in London after the Great Fire.” Enterprise & Society 20, no. 1 (2019): 229252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuckman, Alan. “Looking Backwards: Historical Specificity of the Labour Process in Construction.” Production of the Built Environment 2 (1981): 5460.Google Scholar
Van Uytven, Raymond. “Peiling naar de beroepsstructuur op het Brabantse platteland omstreeks 1755.” Bijdragen tot de geschiedenis 55 (1972): 172203.Google Scholar
Vandermotten, Christian. “De Brusselse industrie. Twee en een halve eeuw evolutie.” Erfgoed Brussel 1516 (2015): 8–21.Google Scholar
Vandermotten, Christian. “Ebauche d’une macrogéographie de l’industrie en Belgique, 1846-1970.” PhD-dissertation, Université Libre de Bruxelles, 1978.Google Scholar
Vandyck, Frederik, Degraeve, Matthijs, and Van de Voorde, Stephanie. “Brussels Iron and Steel Builders in the 19th and 20th Centuries: A Macroeconomic and Spatial Exploration,” in History of Construction Cultures. Proceedings of the 7th International Congress on Construction History, eds. Mascarenhas-Mateus, João and Pires, Ana Paula, vol. 1: 479487. London: CRC Press, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vejzagić, Saša. “Persistent Centralisation of Decision-Making in the Age of Industrial Atomisation and Self-Management on the Case of Construction Company Industrogradnja Zagreb (1966–1980).” Business History (2023).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wardley, Peter. “Debate - On the Ranking of Firms: A Response to Jeremy and Farnie.” Business History 43, no. 3 (2001): 119134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wardley, Peter. “The Emergence of Big Business: The Largest Corporate Employers of Labour in the United Kingdom, Germany and the United States, c. 1907.” Business History 41, no. 4 (1999): 88116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whaples, Robert. “Economic History and Entrepreneurship,” in Routledge Handbook of Modern Economic History, eds. Whaples, R. and Parker, R.E., 7181. London: Routledge, 2013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willems, Hans, and Buelens, Frans. “Belgische vennootschapsvormen in de negentiende en de twintigste eeuw,” in Een succesvolle onderneming: handleiding voor het schrijven van een bedrijfsgeschiedenis, ed. Vancoppenolle, Chantal, 171208. Brussels: Algemeen Rijksarchief, 2005.Google Scholar
Zeitlin, Jonathan. “The Historical Alternatives Approach,” in The Oxford Handbook of Business History, eds. Jones, Geoffrey and Zeitlin, Jonathan, 120140. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Brussels City Archives (BCA), Brussels, Belgium.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Average annual growth in the number of buildings in the Brussels Capital Region (BCR, left Y-axis) and index capital formation in residential construction activity in Belgium (right Y-axis).

Figure 1

Table 1. Absolute and relative evolution of construction employment in Brussels (data: population and industry censuses, Vandermotten 1978)

Figure 2

Table 2. Composition of the database: records and individual enterprises per source and sample year

Figure 3

Table 3. Absolute numbers of construction enterprises and buildings in Brussels (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers, population censuses, cadastral data)

Figure 4

Table 4. Relative numbers of construction enterprises in Brussels (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers, population censuses, cadastral data)

Figure 5

Figure 2. Absolute (gray, left Y-axis) and relative (red, right Y-axis, per 1,000 recent buildings) numbers of enterprises per subsector and sample year (1833, 1866, 1899, 1932 and 1965) (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers).

Figure 6

Figure 3. Distribution of enterprises and employment over five firm size classes in 1831 and 1864 (excluding self-employed entrepreneurs) (data: BCA patent registers).

Figure 7

Figure 4. Average firm sizes per subsector (1831–1937), excluding contractors, and for the construction sector as a whole (1831–1970) (data: industry censuses, BCA patent registers 1831 and 1864).

Figure 8

Table 5. Company forms in the construction sector per sample year (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers)

Figure 9

Table 6. Percentage of company formation per subsector and sample year (data: BCA almanacs and patent registers)