Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T06:54:17.008Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economics and Hermeneutics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 December 2008

Lawrence A. Berger
Affiliation:
University of Pennsylvania

Extract

In a recent article in this journal, D. Wade Hands (1987) reviewed Charles Taylor's two-volume work, Philosophical Papers (1985). Hands predicts that Taylor's work will have no impact on the philosophy of economics. This may indeed turn out to be the case; but if so, it will only be because the profession is not listening. Of course, it is typical of the profession to be more interested in exporting its product than in learning from other disciplines. This is exemplified in Hands's use of the term “philosophy of economics” – philosophy is the handmaiden of the highly successful enterprise of economics. But this journal is called Economics and Philosophy, which means that a conversation requiring an openness and attentiveness is called for between economics and philosophy.

Type
Essays
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Arrow, Kenneth A. 1986. “Rationality of Self and Others in an Economic System.” In Rational Choice, edited by Hogarth, R. M. and Reder, M. W., pp. 201–16. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bowman, E. H. 1963. “Consistency and Optimality in Managerial Decision Making.” Management Science 9:310–21.Google Scholar
Chance, M. R. A. 1967. “Attention Structure as the Basis of Primate Rank Orders.” Man 2:503–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chance, M. R. A., and Larsen, R. R. (editors). 1976. The Social Structure of Attention. London: Wiley.Google Scholar
Clarke, Margaret S., and Fiske, Susan T. (editors). 1982. Affect and Cognition. Hillsdale: Erlbaum.Google Scholar
Douglas, Mary, and Wildavsky, Aaron. 1982. Risk and Culture. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Eysenck, Michael W. 1982. Attention and Arousal. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankfurt, H. 1971. “Freedom of the Will and the Concept of a Person.” Journal of Philosophy 67:520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Frydman, Roman. 1982. “Towards an Understanding of Market Processes: Individual Expectations, Learning, and Convergence to Rational Expectations Equilibrium.” American Economic Review 72:652–68.Google Scholar
Frydman, Roman, and Phelps, Edmund. 1983. Individual Forecasting and Aggregate Outcomes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gadamer, Hans-Georg. 1975. Truth and Method. New York: Crossroad.Google Scholar
Guttentag, J., and Herring, R. 1984. “Credit Rationing and Financial Disorder.” Journal of Finance 34:1359–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hands, D. Wade. 1987. Review of Charles Taylor's Human Agency and Language: Philosophical Papers I and Philosophy and the Human Sciences: Philosophical Papers II. Economics and Philosophy 3:172–75.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” American Economic Review 35:519–30.Google Scholar
Hellwig, Martin F. 1980. “On the Aggregation of Information in Competitive Markets.” Journal of Economic Theory 22:477–98.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1984. “Against Parsimony: Three Easy Ways of Complicating Some Categories of Economic Discourse.” American Economic Review Proceedings 74:8996.Google Scholar
Izard, Carroll E. 1977. Human Emotions. New York: Plenum Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel. 1973. Attention and Effort. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1935. The Ethics of Competition. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Kreps, David. 1984. “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory.” Mimeo. Stanford University.Google Scholar
Lehrer, K. and Wagner, C. 1981. Rational Consensus in Society. London: Reidel.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, James. 1982. “Theories of Choice and Making Decisions.” Society 20:2939.Google Scholar
March, James. 1988. Decisions and Organization. London: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
March, James, and Olsen, J. (editors). 1976. Ambiguity and Choice in Organizations. Bergen, Norway: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
March, James. 1987. “Popular Sovereignty and the Search for Appropriate Institutions.” Journal of Public Policy 6:341–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, James, and Shapira, Zur. 1987. “Managerial Perspectives on Risk and Risk Taking.” Management Science 33:1404–18.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald. 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Messer, S., Sass, A., and Woolfolk, R. (editors). 1988. Hermeneutics and Psychological Theory. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P., and Roberts, J. 1986. “Price and Advertising Signals of Product Quality.” Journal of Political Economy 94:796821.Google Scholar
Minsky, Hyman P. 1975. John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Phillip. 1987. “Shall I Compare Thee to a Minkowski-Ricardo-Leontief-Metzler Matrix of the Mosak-Hicks Type? Or, Rhetoric, Mathematics, and the Nature of Neoclassical Economic Theory.” Economics and Philosophy 3:6795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. 1986. “Negotiations in Games: A Theoretical Overview.” In Uncertainty, Information and Communication, Essays in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, Volume III, edited by Heller, W., pp. 324. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, P. 1974. “Advertising as Information.” Journal of Political Economy 81:729–54.Google Scholar
Radner, Roy, and Rothschild, Michael. 1975. “On the Allocation of Effort.” Journal of Economic Theory 10:358–76.Google Scholar
Rommetveit, Ragnar. 1987. “Meaning, Context, and Control: Convergent Trends and Controversial Issues in Current Social-Scientific Research on Human Cognition and Communication.” Inquiry 30:7799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, Alvin E. 1986. “Laboratory Experimentation in Economics.” Economics and Philosophy 2:245–74.Google Scholar
Satterthwaite, M. 1979. “Consumer Information, Equilibrium Industry Price, and the Number of Sellers.” Bell Journal of Economics 10:483502.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schmalensee, Richard. 1978. “A Model of Advertising and Product Quality.” Journal of Political Economy 86:485503.Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert J. 1984. “Stock Prices and Social Dynamics.” In Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, edited by Brainard, W. C. and Perry, G. L., pp. 457–98. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Shubik, Martin. 1985. “The Use of Simple Games to Illustrate Concepts and to Provide Experimental Evidence.” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 744, Yale University.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1965. “Decision Making as an Economic Resource.” In New Horizons of Economic Progress, edited by Seltzer, L. H., pp. 7195. Detroit: Wayne State University.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1978. “Rationality as Process and as Product of Thought.” American Economic Review 68:116.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1984. “On the Behavioral and Rational Foundations of Economic Dynamics.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 5:3555.Google Scholar
Smith, V., Suchanek, G., and Williams, A. 1988. “Bubbles, Crashes and Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets.” Econometrica 56:1119–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, Charles. 1985. Human Agency and Language: Philosophical Papers I. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, Charles. 1985. Philosophy and the Human Sciences: Philosophical Papers II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, Charles. 1987. “Overcoming Epistemology.” In After Philosophy, edited by Baynes, K., Bohman, J., and McCarthy, T., pp. 464–88. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Townsend, Robert. 1987. “Economic Organization and Limited Communication.” American Economic Review 77:954–71.Google Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. 1981. “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice.” Science 211:453–58.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., Sattah, S., and Slovic, P. 1988. “Contingent Weighting in Judgment and Choice.” Psychological Review 95:371–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winter, Sidney. 1982. “Attention Allocation and Input Proportions.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 2:3146.Google Scholar
Winter, Sidney. 1986. “Comments on Arrow and Lucas.” In Rational Choice, edited by Hogarth, R. M. and Reder, M. W., pp. 243–50. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar