Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T07:03:26.940Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A STRAWSON–LEWIS DEFENCE OF SOCIAL PREFERENCES

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 November 2012

Jelle de Boer*
Affiliation:
University of Amsterdam and Delft University of Technology, the [email protected]

Abstract

This paper examines a special kind of social preference, namely a preference to do one's part in a mixed-motive setting because the other party expects one to do so. I understand this expectation-based preference as a basic reactive attitude (Strawson 1974). Given this, and the fact that expectations in these circumstances are likely to be based on other people's preferences, I argue that in cooperation a special kind of equilibrium ensues, which I call a loop, with people's preferences and expectations mutually cross-referring. As with a Lewis-norm, the loop can get started in a variety of ways. It is self-sustaining in the sense that people with social preferences have sufficient reason not to deviate.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Andreoni, J. and Miller, J. 2002. Giving according to GARP: an experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica 70: 737753.Google Scholar
Bacharach, M., Guearra, G. and Zizzo, D. 2007. The self fulfilling property of trust: an experimental study. Theory and Decision 63: 349388.Google Scholar
Battigalli, P. and Dufwenberg, M. 2007. Guilt in games. American Economic Review 97: 170176.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1995. Game Theory and the Social Contract, Volume I: Playing Fair. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 2008. Do conventions need to be common knowledge? Topoi 27: 1727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bischoff, I. 2007. Institutional choice versus communication in social dilemmas: an experimental approach. Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization 62: 2036.Google Scholar
Bohnet, I. and Frey, B. 1999. The sound of silence in prisoner's dilemma and dictator games. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 38: 4357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. and Ockenfels, A. 2000. A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. American Economic Review 90: 166193.Google Scholar
Brosig, J. 2002. Identifying cooperative behaviour: some experimental results in a prisoner's dilemma game. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 47: 275290.Google Scholar
Bruin, B. de 2005. Game theory in philosophy. Topoi 24: 197208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burnham, T., McCabe, K. and Smith, V.. 2000. Friend-or-foe intentionality priming in an extensive form trust game. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 43: 5773.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. and Fehr, B. 2004. Measuring social norms and preferences using experimental games: a guide for social scientists. In Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies, ed. Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E. and Gintis, H., 5595. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. and Fehr, E. 2006. When does ‘economic man’ dominate social behaviour? Science 311: 4752.Google Scholar
Charness, G. and Rabin, M. 2002. Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 817869.Google Scholar
Colman, A. 2003. Cooperation, psychological game theory, and limitations of rationality in social interaction. Behavioural and Brain Sciences 26: 139198.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cox, J. 2004. How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behaviour 46: 260281.Google Scholar
Cox, J., Sadirai, K. and Sadirai, V. 2008. Experimental Economics 11: 124.Google Scholar
Cubitt, R. and Sugden, R. 2003. Common knowledge, salience and convention: a reconstruction of David Lewis’ game theory. Economics and Philosophy 19: 175210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M. and Kirchsteiger, G. 2004. A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behaviour 47: 268298.Google Scholar
Ekman, P. 2003. Emotions Revealed. New York, NY: Henri Holt.Google Scholar
Elster, J. 1983. Sour Grapes. Studies in the Subversion of Rationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Falk, A., Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U. 2008. Testing theories of fairness – intentions matter. Games and Economic Behaviour 62: 287303.Google Scholar
Fehr, B. and Gächter, S. 2002. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415: 137140.Google Scholar
Fehr, B. and Schmidt, K. 1999. A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 817868.Google Scholar
Frank, R. 2004. What Price the Moral High Ground? Ethical Dilemmas in Competitive Environments. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gauthier, D. 1986. Morals by Agreement. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Geanokoplos, J., Pearce, D. and Stachetti, E. 1989. Psychological games and sequential rationality. Games and Economic Behaviour 1: 6079.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammerstein, P. (ed.) 2003. Genetic and Cultural Evolution of Cooperation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hartogh, G. den 1998. A conventionalist theory of obligation. Law and Philosophy 17: 351376.Google Scholar
Hartogh, G. den 2002. Mutual Expectations. A Conventionalist Theory of Law. The Hague: Kluwer.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. and Smith, N.. 2004. Comparative experimental evidence from Machiguenga, Mapuche, Huinca, and American populations. In Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies, ed. Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E. and Gintis, H., 125167. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E. and Gintis, H. (eds.) 2004. Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. 2000 [1739]. A Treatise of Human Nature, ed. Norton, D. F. and Norton, M. J.. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kincaid, H. 2008. Structural realism and the social sciences. Philosophy of Science 75: 720731.Google Scholar
Lewis, D. 1969. Convention. A Philosophical Study. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
McCabe, K., Rigdon, M. and Smith, V. 2003. Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 52: 267275.Google Scholar
McClennen, E. 1990. Rationality and Dynamic Choice. Foundational Explorations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Orbell, J., van de Kragt, A. and Dawes, R. 1988. Explaining discussion induced cooperation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 40: 4551.Google Scholar
Pelligra, V. 2005. Under trusting eyes: the responsive nature of trust. In Economics and Social Interaction. Accounting for Interpersonal Relations, ed. Gui, B. and Sugden, R., 105124. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pettit, P. 1995. The cunning of trust. Philosophy and Public Affairs 25: 202225.Google Scholar
Pettit, P. 1996. Functional explanation and virtual selection. British Journal for the Philosophy of Science 47: 291302.Google Scholar
Rabin, M. 1993. Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review 83: 12811302.Google Scholar
Ross, D. 2008. Classical game theory, socialization and the rationalization of conventions. Topoi 27: 5772.Google Scholar
Roth, A., Prasnikar, V., Okuno-Fujiwara, M. and Zamir, S. 1991. Bargaining and market behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: an experimental study. American Economic Review 81: 10681095.Google Scholar
Sally, D. 1995. Conversation and cooperation in social dilemmas: a meta-analysis of experiments from 1958 to 1992, Rationality and Society 7: 5892.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. 1978. Micromotives and Macrobehaviour. New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Sillari, G. 2005. A logical framework for convention. Synthese 147: 379400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sillari, G. 2008. Common knowledge and convention. Topoi 27: 2939.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1759. The Theory of Moral Sentiments, ed. Raphael, D.D. and Macfie, A.L.. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. 2010. What would Adam Smith think? Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 73: 8386.Google Scholar
Sober, E. 1983. Equilibrium explanation. Philosophical Studies 43: 201210.Google Scholar
Strawson, P. 1974. Freedom and resentment. In Freedom and Resentment and Other essays. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1984/2005. The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare. New York, NY: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1989. Spontaneous order. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3: 8597.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1998. Normative expectations: the simultaneous evolution of institutions and norms. In Economics, Values, and Organization, ed. Ben-Ner, A. and Putterman, L., 73100. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, J. and Murnighan, J. 2008. Suckers or saviors? Consistent contributors in social dilemmas. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 95: 13401353.Google Scholar
Wilson, B. 2010. Social preferences aren't preferences. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 73: 7782.Google Scholar