Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T13:02:46.324Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Persuasion and Economic Efficiency: The Cost-Benefit Analysis of Banning Abortion

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 October 2009

Julianne Nelson
Affiliation:
Stern School of Business, New York University

Extract

How do economists persuade their readers that one policy is superior to another? A glance at the literature on welfare economics quickly provides the answer to this question: Economists enter policy debates armed with mathematical models, evaluating options on the basis of their consequences. Economists typically classify a policy change as a welfare (or “potential Pareto”) improvement with respect to the status quo if the gain realized by the winners exceeds the harm sustained by the losers. The best policy becomes the one that generates the highest net benefit.

Type
Essays
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

American Political Network. 1991. “Germany: Europe and Germans Protest Border Searches.” Abortion Report, April 11.Google Scholar
Bailey, Martin J. 1980. Reducing Risks to Life. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Belkin, Lisa. 1991. “7 More Patients Accuse Doctor of Botching Their Abortions.” New York Times, November 21B, p. 1.Google Scholar
Burns, Sarah et al. ,. 1991. Amici Curiae Brief filed before the U.S. Supreme Court in William L. Webster v. Reproductive Health Services.Google Scholar
Clarity, James. 1992. “Irishwomen, Just Talking: The Topic is Abortion.” Nezv York Times, May 21:A, p. 4.Google Scholar
Cole, David. 1991. “Beyond Unconstitutional Conditions: Charting Spheres of Neutrality in Government-Funded Speech.” Georgetown University Law Center mimeo.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules. 1982. “The Economic Analysis of Law.” In Nomos XXVI: Ethics, Economics and the Law, edited by Pennock, J. Roland and Chapman, John W., pp. 83103. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules. 1984. “Economics and the Law: A Critical Review of the Foundations of the Economic Approach to the Law.” Ethics 94(4):649–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, Jules, and John, Ferejohn. 1984. “Democracy and Social Choice.” Ethics 97(1):626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, Isaac. 1973. “Participation in Illegitimate Activities: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Political Theory 81:521–65.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Green, Jerry, and Jean-Jacques, Laffont. 1979. Incentives in Public Decision-Making. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Hausman, Jerry A. 1981. “Exact Consumer's Surplus and Deadweight Loss.” American Economic Review 71:662–76.Google Scholar
Kelman, Mark. 1987. A Guide to Critical Legal Studies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kelman, Steven. 1981. “Cost-Benefit Analysis: An Ethical Critique.” Regulation (January-February) 5:3340.Google ScholarPubMed
Meeks, Thomas J. 1990. “The Economic Efficiency and Equity of Abortion.” Economics and Philosophy 6:95138.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mirowski, Philip. 1986. “Mathematical Formalism and Economic Explanation.” In The Reconstruction of Economic Theory, edited by Mirowski, P., Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishan, E. J. 1976. Cost-Benefit Analysis (new and expanded edition). New York: Praeger Publishers.Google Scholar
Navarro, Mireya. 1991. “State Chose Not to Punish Physician Tied to a Death.” New York Times, November 23:1, p. 27.Google Scholar
Nelson, Julianne. 1991. “The Role of Privacy in the Search for an Efficient Legal System.” Center for Legal and Economic Studies, Columbia Law School, working paper.Google Scholar
Parfit, Derek. 1984. Reasons and Persons. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1992. Sex and Reason. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schafer, Wayne, and Hugo, Sonnenschein. 1982. “Market Demand and Excess Demand Functions.” In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 2, edited by Kenneth, Arrow and Michael, Intriligator, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1941. “A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics.” Review of Economic Studies 9:7781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Small, Kenneth A., and Rosen, Harvey S.. 1981. “Applied Welfare Economics with Discrete Choice Models.” Econometrica 49(l):105–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, Judith J. 1971. “A Defense of Abortion.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 1:4766.Google Scholar
Tietze, Christopher, Jacqueline Darroch, Forrest, and Henshaw, Stanley K.. 1988. “United States of America.” In International Handbook on Abortion, edited by Paul, Sachdev, pp. 473–94. New York: Greenwood Press.Google Scholar
Varian, Hal. 1984. Microeconomic Analysis, 2nd ed. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. 1961. “The Valuation of Human Capital.” journal of Political Economy 69:425–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willig, Robert. 1976. “Consumer's Surplus Without Apology.” American Economic Review 66:589–97.Google Scholar