Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T14:44:09.016Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Economics of Intervention: American Overseas Investments and Relations with Underdeveloped Areas, 1890–1950

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 June 2009

Jeffry A. Frieden
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles

Extract

This essay has presented a framework for the analysis of economic factors in political relations between developed and developing areas. The most relevant considerations in this regard are the potential costs of imperial intervention in enhancing the return to metropolitan economic interests, and the potential benefits that intervention might bring to these interests. The essay has emphasized the differential political implications of various types of metropolitan economic activity, and especially of different forms of foreign investment.

Type
The United States in the International Economy
Copyright
Copyright © Society for the Comparative Study of Society and History 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

The author acknowledges with thanks the comments and suggestions of Richard Baum, Leonard Binder, David Dollar, Stephan Haggard, Robert Jervis, Miles Kahler, Paul Kennedy, David Lake, Manuel Pastor, Ron Rogowski, John Ruggie, Richard Sklar, Jack Snyder, Kenneth Sokoloff, Michael Wallerstein, and David Wilkinson.

1 Gallagher, John and Robinson, Ronald, “The Imperialism of Free Trade,” Economic History Review, 2d ser., 6:1 (1953)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, 1–15; for the ensuing debate, see Louis, W. R., ed., Imperialism: The Gallagher and Robinson Controversy (New York: New Viewpoints, 1976)Google Scholar. Treatments of the debates and of the historical evidence include Platt, D. C. M., Finance, Trade, and Politics in British Foreign Policy, 1815–1914 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1968)Google Scholar; Cain, P. J., Economic Foundations of British Overseas Expansion, 1815–1914 (London: Macmillan, 1980)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Smith, Tony, The Pattern of Imperialism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981)Google Scholar; and Doyle, Michael, Empires (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1986)Google Scholar. An important example of the new historical work is Hopkins, A. G., An Economic History of West Africa (New York: Columbia University Press, 1973).Google Scholar

2 Simple calculations of imperialism's net benefit to the imperial nation are not very telling, since the benefits might accrue to powerful groups while the costs are borne by powerless taxpayers or footsoldiers. Differing intensities of interest are so difficult to measure that the calculation of just how important foreign economic policy is to various domestic actors is nearly impossible. Lebergott, Stanley, “The Returns to U.S. Imperialism, 1890–1929,” Journal of Economic History, 40:2 (06 1980), 229252, is a fascinating attempt in this mode; unfortunately, the author pays more attention to the potentially uneven distribution of costs and benefits within the backward areas than he does to the same problem in the United States.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Lipson, Charles, standing Guard: Protecting Foreign Capital in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985), 826, summarizes the nineteenth-century experience. There are obvious free-rider problems raised by one nation's enforcement of property rights that could benefit economic agents from all nations; an exploration of this aspect of nineteenth-century colonial policy is unquestionably needed.Google Scholar

4 Although a variety of explanations of this common observation can be adduced, the one that holds up best to theoretical scrutiny is that competitive producers have more reason to fear retaliation than do uncompetitive producers. Global free trade is attractive to those who would dominate markets under such circumstances, and, although they might benefit even more by exclusive access to a particular market, their desire for exclusiveness in one area will be outweighed by the fear that it would cause other areas to be sealed off to them. On the other hand, less competitive producers could easily calculate that all of one market is better than very little of all markets, and would be more likely to ignore the attractions of global free trade in favor of smaller but protected markets. It should also be noted that annexation makes more sense when the areas involved are complementary rather than competing. A related treatment is Wrigley, C. C., “Neo-mercantile Policies and the New Imperialism,” in The Imperial Impact, Dewey, Clive and Hopkins, A. G., eds. (London: Athlone Press, 1978), 2034. The considerations here assume that socioeconomic rigidities make increasing the profits of existing producers more feasible than the more efficient alternative of movement into new economic activities. The assumption is reasonable, and can be justified either on the sector-specificity of physical or human capital or on the uncertainty attached to the adjustment process.Google Scholar

5 Reuber, Grant, Private Foreign Investment in Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1973, 7280), makes a related distinction among “export-oriented,” “market-development,” and “government-initiated” multinational corporations.Google Scholar

6 This tendency is visible both historically and today: One recent study has shown that while extractive industries represented only 15 percent of foreign firms in the developing world in 1967, they accounted for 35 percent of the firms expropriated there between 1960 and 1976 (Kobrin, Stephen J., “Foreign Enterprise and Forced Divestment in LDCs,” International Organization, 34:1 (Winter 1980), 76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 As Kobrin, “Foreign Enterprise and Forced Divestment,” 80–81, demonstrates, where the local affiliate uses somewhat standardized technology or techniques, host-country interference may be more likely, but most branch factories rely enough on their home offices to make their seizure relatively unlikely.

8 The notion that foreign creditors are relatively less prone to invoke home-country intervention than are other investors runs so counter to received historical impressions that it is worth defending at more length. First, it is important to distinguish between true home-country intervention for financial purposes and those instances in which loans were made after metropolitan interventions. In the Caribbean before 1930, it was common for the United States to establish effective military and political control of a country such as Haiti, and then call on a New York investment house to make a small stabilization loan to the new protectorate, generally with the implicit or explicit guarantee of the United States government. These hardly qualify as instances of financial difficulty leading to military occupation. Second, where real debt problems do develop, the almost universal creditor response is some form of creditors' consortium to attempt to enforce market discipline on the errant debtor; the combined power of international financial markets has usually been far easier to muster, and perhaps more convincing, than gunboats. Before World War I, this action generally took the form of financial control committees having representatives of all creditor nations; in the interwar years, these were replaced by consortia organized by the League of Nations; since World War II, the International Monetary Fund has played a similar role. Third, where creditors did use home-country intervention to reinforce claims, the flag was generally shown only briefly to support the creditors' bargaining position. On a few occasions intervention related to local insolvency turned into long-term occupation—Egypt in 1882 is the obvious example—but the reasons the metropolitan power stayed usually had little to do with finance. The more common pattern was a brief period of heightened tension, with or without use of force, after which the debtor agreed to some form of creditor supervision in return for renegotiated terms and, perhaps, new credits. On debtor-creditor relations see, for example, Feis, Herbert, Europe the World's Banker, 1870–1914 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1930)Google Scholar; Meyer, Richard, Banker's Diplomacy (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; and Lipson, Charles, “The International Organization of Third World Debt,” International Organization, 35:4 (Autumn 1981), 603631CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For surveys of the Egyptian case, see Owen, Roger, “Egypt and Europe: From French Expedition to British Occupation,” in Studies in the Theory of Imperialism, Owen, Roger and Sutcliffe, Bob, eds. (London: Longman, 1972), 195209Google Scholar; and Doyle, , Empires, 208–18.Google Scholar

9 It should of course be noted that there are many instances in which colonialism did not accelerate, and may indeed have retarded, local socioeconomic and political development. The former Belgian and Portuguese colonies are obvious examples, and others doubtless exist. The generalization is nonetheless valid, if not universal.

10 Cited in Munro, Dana G., Intervention and Dollar Diplomacy in the Caribbean, 1900–1920 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964), 113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

11 Data in this is from Lewis, Cleona, America's Stake in International Investments (Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1938), passim.Google Scholar

12 U.S. Department of State, Papers Relating to the Foreign Relations of the United States 1919 [Hereafter cited as FRUS] (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office); I, 873Google Scholar. On the environment, see Munro, , Intervention and Dollar Diplomacy, 426–48Google Scholar. On Mexico, the standard study is Lorenzo, Meyer MéxicoEstados Unidos en el conflicto petrolero (1917–1942) (México City: Colegio de México, 1968)Google Scholar; see also FRUS 1915, 870–91Google Scholar; FRUS 1916, 741–53Google Scholar; FRUS 1918, 687751Google Scholar; and FRUS 1920, III, 200226Google Scholar. On Venezuela, see Rabe, Stephen G., The Road to OPEC: United States Relations with Venezuela, 1919–1976 (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1982), 2242Google Scholar. Two good general overviews are Randall, Stephen J., U.S. Foreign Oil Policy, 1919–1948: For Profits and Security (Kingston: McGill-Queen's University Press, 1985)Google Scholar, and Chester, Edward, United States Oil Policy and Diplomacy (Westport, Conn.: Greenwood, 1983)Google Scholar. The relevant volumes of the multivolume history of Standard Oil of New Jersey are of course crucial: Gibb, George and Knowlton, Evelyn, The Resurgent Years, 1911–1927 (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1956)Google Scholar, and Larson, Henrietta, Knowlton, Evelyn and Popple, Charles, New Horizons, 1927–1950 (New York: Harper and Row, 1971)Google Scholar. See also Wilkins, Mira, “Multinational Oil Companies in South America in the 1920s,” Business History Review, 48:3 (Autumn 1974), 414–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 Fanning, Leonard M., American Oil Operations Abroad (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1947), 204–7.Google Scholar

14 Croly, Herbert, Willard Straight (New York: Macmillan, 1925), 269454Google Scholar; Hunt, Michael, The Making of a Special Relationship (New York: Columbia University Press, 1983).Google Scholar

15 See, for example, United States Senate, Special Committee Investigating Petroleum Resources, Diplomatic Protection of American Petroleum Interests in Mesopotamia, Netherlands East Indies, and Mexico (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1945), 151Google Scholar; FRUS 1919, II, 250–62Google Scholar; FRUS 1920, II, 649–75Google Scholar; Chester, United States Oil Policy, 214–76Google Scholar; Fanning, American Oil Operations Abroad, 8599Google Scholar; and Gibb, and Knowlton, , Resurgent Years, 247317.Google Scholar

16 Bairoch, Paul, The Economic Development of the Third World since 1900 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975), 149–51.Google Scholar

17 Figures calculated from Lewis, America's Stake, 654–55Google Scholar; and United States Department of Commerce, American Direct Investments in Foreign Countries (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1930), 1828, 29–50, et passim.Google Scholar

18 See, for example, Tulchin, Joseph, The Aftermath of War (New York: NYU Press, 1971), 238–41Google Scholar; Smith, Robert F., The United States and Revolutionary Nationalism in Mexico, 1916–1932 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1972), 244–50Google Scholar; and Gardner, Richard, Sterling-Dollar Diplomacy in Current Perspective (New York: Columbia University Press, 1980), 49.Google Scholar

19 Nicolson, Harold, Dwight Morrow (New York: Macmillan, 1935), 264–65.Google Scholar

20 Smith, , United States and Revolutionary Nationalism, 246Google Scholar. For a related argument, see Rosenberg, Emily and Rosenberg, Norman, “From Colonialism to Professionalism: The PublicP?vate Dynamic in United States Foreign Financial Advising, 1898–1929,” Journal of American History, 74:1 (06 1987), 5982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

21 Nicolson, , Dwight Morrow, 294347Google Scholar; Smith United States and Revolutionary Nationalism, 244–65Google Scholar; and FRUS 1930, 462–95Google Scholar, all summarize the episode. See also Kane, N. Stephen,“Corporate Power and Foreign Policy: Efforts of American Oil Companies to Influence United States Relations with Mexico, 1921–1928,” Diplomatic History, 1:2 (Spring 1977), 170–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

22 See, for example, Alejandro, Carlos Díaz, Essays on the Economic History of the Argentine Republic (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1970), 32Google Scholar. On the Brazilian and Argentine experiences, see Abreu, Marcelo de Paiva, “Argentina e Brasil na dcada de 30: O impacto das polítcas econômicas internacionais da Gra-Bretanha e dos EUA,” Revista Brasileira de Economia, 38:4 (10 1984), pp. 309326.Google Scholar

23 Chester, , United States Oil Policy, 121. See especially Meyer, México y Estados Unidos, 198264Google Scholar, and Cronon, E. David, Josephus Daniels in Mexico (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1960).Google Scholar

24 Rabe, Road to OPEC, 5152.Google Scholar

25 Ibid., 64.

26 Ibid., 73–93; see also Chester, , United States Oil Policy, 144–48.Google Scholar

27 Anderson, Irvine, Aramco, the United States, and Saudi Arabia (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1981)Google Scholar, is the best single source on the Saudi case; on the fifty-fifty agreement, for example, see pp. 179–97. See also Stoff, Michael B., Oil, War, and American Security (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1980)Google Scholar; and Miller, Aaron, Search for Security (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1980).Google Scholar

28 For a suggestive study, see Anderson, Irvine, The Standard Vacuum Oil Company and United States East Asian Policy, 1933–1941 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975).Google Scholar

29 A neo-realist variant might look at regional geopolitical conditions of a hegemonic and nonhegemonic nature. This, however, raises as many questions as it answers, primarily concerning the relevance of regional balances, the evaluation of extraregional challenges, and the determinacy of the regional response. While the regional approach gives a reasonable account of how rising American hegemony in Latin American in the 1930s might have led to loosened control, it does very poorly at explaining why American control over the Philippines was being loosened at the same time despite serious regional challenges to the American position. For a more detailed evaluation, see my “Oil and the Evolution of U.S. Policy toward the Developing Areas, 1900–1950,” in Oil in the World Economy, Ferrier, R. W., ed. (London: Croom Helm, forthcoming).Google Scholar

30 This point is related to that made in a different context by Krasner, Stephen, “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics, 28 (04 1976), 317347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

31 Lustick, Ian, State-Building Failure in British Ireland and French Algeria (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, 1985).Google Scholar

32 On trade, see Wrigley, “Neo-mercantile Policies”; on investments, see Fieldhouse, David, “‘A New Imperial System’? The Role of Multinational Corporations Reconsidered,” in Imperialism and After, Mommsen, Wolfgang and Osterhammel, Jurgen, eds. (London: Allen and Unwin, 1986), 225–40Google Scholar; for a comparison, see Kahler, Miles, “Political Regime and Economic Actors: The Response of Firms to the End of Colonial Rule,” World Politics, 33:3 (04 1981), 383412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

33 See, for example, Hynes, William G., The Economics of Empire (London: Longman, 1979)Google Scholar; and Newbury, C. W., “The Tariff Factor in Anglo-French West African Partition,” in France and Britain in Africa, Gifford, Prosser and Louis, William Roger, eds. (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971), 220–59Google Scholar. An excellent general essay is Cain, P. J. and Hopkins, A. G., “The Political Economy of British Expansion Overseas, 1750–1914,” Economic History Review, 2d. ser., 33:4 (11 1980), 463490Google Scholar; an important collection of essays is British Imperialism in the Nineteenth Century, Eldridge, C. C., ed. (London: Macmillan, 1984).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

34 Slinn, Peter, “Commercial Concessions and Politics during the Colonial Period,” African Affairs, 70 (1971), 365–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 Fieldhouse, D. K., Unilever Overseas (London: Croom Helm, 1978).Google Scholar

36 Hopkins, , Economic History of West Africa, 166, 124–66, 276–79Google Scholar; idem, Property Rights and Empire-Building,” Journal of Economic History, 40:4 (12 1980), 777–98.Google Scholar

37 Tomlinson, B. R., The Political Economy of the Raj, 1914–1947 (London: Macmillan, 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Tomlinson, B. R., “Foreign Private Investment in India, 1920–1950,” Modern Asian Studies, 12:4 (1978), 655–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar