Published online by Cambridge University Press: 17 February 2009
With the proclamation of Document 1, 1983, reform of marketing became one of the major targets of agricultural policy in China. This official emphasis on the need to liberalize the marketing system was, however, little more than a confirmation of a process which was already taking place. The initial reforms of labour management and prices in 1978 had led to a decentralization of economic authority to the household level. The commune system was in decline and the number of small-scale free markets was increasing rapidly as peasants took advantage of their new-found freedom to trade their surplus production as they wished. Responding to the economic stimulus offered by the new structure of prices and to the organizational flexibility offered by the decentralization of management, some households began to plan at least part of their production for sale on the market, there by initiating a process of specialization and commercialization. Once begun, this process fed backwards into production by encouraging further specialization and diversification and forwards into marketing by stimulating the emergence of longdistance trade carried out by specialist merchants and traders. In effect, the free market began to act as an engine of economic change, shaping both the structure of agricultural production and employment and the network of new economic linkages through the emerging hierarchy of market centres.
1. Document 1, 1983, in Bianjibu, Zhongguo Nongye Nianjian, Zhongguo nongye nianjian 1983 (China Agricultural Yearbook 1983) (Beijing: Nongye chubanshe, 1983), pp. 1–5.Google Scholar
2. “State Council Directive on Strengthening Market Management and Attacking Speculation and Smuggling,” Document 3, 7 01 1981Google Scholar, in Nongcun jingji zhengce huibian 1978–1981 (Collected Rural Economic Policy Documents 1978–1981) (Beijing: Nongcun duwu chubanshe: 1982), Vol. 1, pp. 555–58.Google Scholar
3. Document 1, 1982, in Bianjibu, Zhongguo Nongye Nianjian, Zhongguo nongye nianjian 1982 (China Agricultural Yearbook 1982) (Beijing: Nongye chubanshe, 1982), p. 3.Google Scholar
4. Document 1, 1983, p. 3.
5. Skinner, G. William, “Marketing and social structure in rural China,” Pts 1, 2 and 3, Journal of Asian Studies, Vol XXIV, No. 1 (11 1964)Google Scholar; No. 2 (February 1965); and No. 3 (May 1965), and The City in Late Imperial China (California: Stanford University Press, 1977).Google Scholar
6. For a more comprehensive discussion of these institutions and their operation see Donnithorne, Audrey, China's Economic System (London: Allen and Unwin, 1967), pp. 273–307Google Scholar and Hong, Ma (ed.), Xiandai Zhongguo jingji shidian (An Encyclopedia of the Contemporary Chinese Economy) (Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 1983), pp. 286–300.Google Scholar
7. Ruizhen, Yan, “Dangqian wo guo nongcun liutong lingyu gaige zhong de sange jiben wenti” (“Three basic issues in the current reform of commodity circulation in the Chinese countryside”), Nongye jingji wenti (Problems of Agricultural Economics), No. 7 (1984), pp. 23–26.Google Scholar
8. See, e.g., ibid. and Bianjibu, Zhongguo Nongye Nianjian, China Agricultural Yearbook 1982, p. 3.Google Scholar
9. For a further discussion of this issue see Oi, Jean, “Peasant grain marketing and state procurement: China's grain contracting system,” The China Quarterly (CQ), No. 106 (06 1986), pp. 272–90Google Scholar. Oi argues that the new contract system led to a higher average grain price for the peasants (p. 289). This was only true, however, where the original base sales quota was higher than 30% of total sales.
10. Donnithorne, , China's Economic System, p. 292.Google Scholar
11. Hong, Ma (ed.), An Encyclopedia, p. 292Google Scholar, and State Statistical Bureau, Statistical Yearbook of China 1985 (Hong Kong: Economie Information and Agency, 1985), p. 478.Google Scholar
12. State Industrial and Commercial Administration Bureau, “Wo guo chengxiang jishi maoyi riyi fanrong xingwang” (“Market trade in China's towns and countryside steadily grows more prosperous”), Jingji ribao (Economics Daily), 11 07 1984, p. 2.Google Scholar
13. Interview with Liu Wenxu, vice-director of the Agricultural Products Price Bureau of the State Price Bureau, 27 04 1987.Google Scholar
14. Ibid.
15. Lardy, Nicholas, Agriculture in China's Modern Economic Development (London: Cambridge University Press, 1983), pp. 175–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
16. The free market price index expressed in terms of the base state prices for the years 1980–84 shows that average market prices were consistently over 40% higher. For some goods such as grains and edible oils, prices were between 90 and 100% higher. See State Statistical Bureau, Zhongguo nongcun tongji nianjian 1985 (China Rural Statistics Yearbook 1985) (Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 1986), p. 147.Google Scholar
17. Interviews Xi'an and Fenghuo Brigade.
18. Survey notes.
19. Xuecan, Wu, “We must continue to relax policies in order to develop agriculture at high speed,” Jingjixue zhoubao (Economics Weekly), No. 44 (1 11 1982), p. 1.Google Scholar
20. Bianjibu, Zhongguo Jingji Nianjian, Zhongguo jingji nianjian 1982 (China Economic Yearbook 1982) (Hong Kong: Commercial Press, 1982), pp. 276–78.Google Scholar
21. Jiyuan, Wang, “Several problems in urban and rural market trade,” Jingjixue zhoubao, No. 100 (28 11 1983), p. 5.Google Scholar
22. Zhongguo nongmin bao (China Peasant Daily), 24 02 1983, p. 2Google Scholar. A translation is available in British Broadcasting Corporation, Summary of World Broadcasts, Pt 3Google Scholar, The Far East (hereafter SWB FE), FE/7270/BII/3–9, 1 03 1983.Google Scholar
23. Zhongguo nongmin bao, 13 03 1984, p. 3Google Scholar. Translated in SWB FE/7595/C/1–3, 19 03 1984.Google Scholar
24. Statistical Yearbook of China 1985, p. 479.Google Scholar
25. Interview with Wenxu, Liu, 27 04 1987.Google Scholar
26. State Statistical Bureau, A Statistical Survey of China in 1986 (Beijing: New World Press, 1986), p. 93.Google Scholar
27. The Industrial and Commercial Administration and Management Bureau of the State Council (Gongshang Xingzheng Guanli Ju) maintains a continuous survey of 208 rural markets and 70 urban markets and has published quarterly reports on them. It may be that this survey is used when calculating the national figures. See, e.g., Jingji ribao, 15 01 1983, p. 1 and 6 August 1983, p. 2Google Scholar; and Zhongguo nongmin bao, 4 12 1983, p. 1 and 4 November 1984, p. 1.Google Scholar
28. Bianjibu, Zhongguo Nongye Nianjian, China Agricultural Yearbook 1983, p. 121.Google Scholar
29. Bianjibu, Zhongguo Jingji Nianjian, China Economic Yearbook 1983, p. IV–129Google Scholar and Jingji ribao, 11 07 1984, p. 2.Google Scholar
30. Bianjibu, Zhongguo Jingji Nianjian, China Economic Yearbook 1983, p. IV–129.Google Scholar
31. Jingji ribao, 11 07 1984, p. 2.Google Scholar
32. Skinner, G. William, “Marketing and social structure,” and The City in Late Imperial China.Google Scholar
33. See, e.g., Xiandao, Liu, “Shiying shangpin shengchan xuyao jianli nongcun nongfu chanpin pifa shichang” (“It is necessary to establish rural product wholesale markets to suit commodity production”), Nongye Jingji wenti, No. 7 (1984), pp. 38–40Google Scholar and Fengshan, Sun and Wufeng, Zhang, “Chengxiang jishi maoyi de fazhan qushi” (“Developmental trends in urban and rural market trade”), Caimao Jingji (Finance and Trade Economics), No. 2 (1986), pp. 60–62.Google Scholar
34. See, e.g., Hefei City Industrial and Commercial Administration and Management Bureau, “Jiasu nongfu chanpin liutong, wei chengxiang renmin fuwu” (“Accelerate the circulation of agricultural products, serve the people of town and countryside”), Nongye jingji wenti, No. 2 (1984), pp. 42–45Google Scholar; Xiandao, Liu, “It is necessary to establish rural product wholesale markets;” Zuo Zhaoyi, “Chongqingshi nongmao shichang diaocha” (“A survey of agricultural markets in Chongqing”), Nongye jingji wenti, No. 12 (1984), pp. 9–13Google Scholar; Fang, Cai, “Dazhong chengshi nongfu chanpin pifa shichang taolunhui jianjie” (“A brief summary of the conference on wholesale markets for agricultural products in large and medium cities”), Nongye jingji wenti, No. 6 (1985), p. 49Google Scholar; Quanxin, Zhang, “Shenyangshi nongfu chanpin pifa shichang diaocha” (“A survey of wholesale markets for agricultural products in Shenyang”), Zhongguo nongcun jingji (China's Rural Economy), No. 7 (1985), pp. 9–14Google Scholar and “Nong chanpin pifa shichang yanjiu” (“A study of wholesale markets for agricultural products”), Zhongguo nongcun jingji, No. 2 (1986), pp. 42–45Google Scholar; Yalai, Zhang and Xiaodong, Kuang, “Xin lishi tiaojianxia de ‘jingjiren’” (“The role of ‘market intermediaries’ under the new historical conditions”), Zhongguo nongcun jingji, No. 7 (1985), pp. 5–8 and 55Google Scholar; Xincui, Mao, “Ba nongfu chanpin pifa shichang gaohuo guanhao” (“Enliven wholesale markets for agricultural products and run them well”), Zhongguo nongcun jingji, No. 7 (1985), pp. 1–4Google Scholar; Wu, Zhan et al. , “Lun nong chanpin pifa shichang” (“On wholesale markets for agricultural products”), Renmin ribao (People's Daily), 23 09 1985, p. 5Google Scholar; Liuzheng, Zhang et al. , “Jin yibu fazhan nong chanpin pifa shichang de ruogan wenti” (“Some issues in the further development of wholesale markets for agricultural products”), Nongye jingji wenti, No. 12 (1985), pp. 41–43Google Scholar; Fengshan, Sun and Wufeng, Zhang, “Developmental trends”Google Scholar; Liye, Luo, “Lun nongcun zhuanye shichang” (“On specialized rural markets”), Jiang-Huai luntan (Jiang-Huai Forum), No. 4 (1986), pp. 11–17Google Scholar (cited in Zhongguo Renmin Daxue Shu Bao Ziliao Zhongxin, Nongye jingji (Agricultural Economics), F2, No. 10 (1986), pp. 143–49)Google Scholar; Jinxing, Lu and Moqing, Hua, “Banhao pifa jiaoyi shichang, gaohuo chengshi shucai liutong” (“Run wholesale markets well, enliven urban vegetable trade”), Caimao jingji, No. 9 (1986), pp. 42–44Google Scholar; Shengjun, Ding, “Yao jianquan he wanshan nongcun shichang tixi” (“Strengthen and perfect the rural market structure”), Nongye jishu jingji (Agricultural Technical Economics), No. 8 (1986), pp. 4–7Google Scholar; and Yaling, Wei, “Nong chanpin pifa shichang riyi xingwang” (“Wholesale markets for agricultural products continue to thrive”), Renmin ribao, 11 06 1986, p. 2.Google Scholar
35. SWB FE/7831/BII/11–12, 20 12 1984.Google Scholar
36. The following description is based on Zhaoyi, Zuo, “A survey of agricultural markets in Chongqing” and Rural Development Research Institute, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (ed.), Nong chanpin pifa shichang yanjiu (Studies of Wholesale Markets for Agricultural Products) (Beijing: Rural Development Research Institute, 1985), pp. 103–122.Google Scholar
37. Zhaoyi, Zuo, “A survey,” p. 9.Google Scholar
38. In an obvious error, the value is given in the source as 116.12 million yuan, the same as the volume. The more likely figure of 52.20 million yuan is calculated from Zuo's note that the per capita transaction value was 116 yuan. Ibid.
39. Ibid.
40. Rural Development Research Institute, Studies of Wholesale Markets, p. 106.Google Scholar
41. Ibid. p. 107.
42. Ibid. pp. 150 and 111.
43. See Xiandao, Liu, “It is necessary to establish rural product wholesale markets”.Google Scholar
44. Quanxin, Zhang, “A survey of wholesale markets for agricultural products in Shenyang,”Google Scholar and Jinxing, Lu and Moqing, Hua, “Run wholesale markets well, enliven urban vegetable trade.”Google Scholar
45. Interview with Zhou Wang, manager of Beitaipingzhuang Wholesale Market, 29 04 1987.Google Scholar
46. Xincui, Mao, “Enliven wholesale markets for agricultural products and run them well.”Google Scholar
47. Interview, 29 April 1987.
48. Yufei, Mao, “Guanyu nongchanpin de xubei wenti” (“On the question of stocks of agricultural products”), Caimao jingji, No. 8 (1986), pp. 58–60.Google Scholar
49. Renmin ribao, 25 11 1986, p. 2.Google Scholar
50. Xinhua ribao (New China Daily), 2 01 1987, p. 1.Google Scholar
51. State Council, “Regulations governing the management of peasant market trade,” 5 02 1983Google Scholar, SWB FE/77270/BII/4.Google Scholar
52. Jingji ribao, 11 07 1984, p. 2.Google Scholar
53. Zhongguo Jingji Nianjin Bianjibu, China Economic Yearbook 1983, p. IV–129.Google Scholar
54. See, e.g., the discussion in Jingjixue zhoubao, No. 131 (2 07 1984), pp. 1 and 7Google Scholar; No. 137 (13 August 1984), p. 3; and No. 144 (1 October 1984), p. 3.
55. For a discussion of that system see Qingwu, Zhang, Hukou dengji changshi (General Facts about the Household Registration System) (Beijing: Falu chubanshe, 1983).Google Scholar
56. Renmin ribao, 22 10 1984, p. 1Google Scholar. For a discussion of early changes in local regulations see Solinger, Dorothy, “Temporary residence certificate regulations in Wuhan, May 1983,” CQ, No. 101 (03 1985), pp. 98–103.Google Scholar
57. For a discussion of the earlier impact of this change see Donnithorne, , China's Economic System, pp. 307–309.Google Scholar
58. Hongqi (Red Flag), 01 1987Google Scholar, reported in SWB FE/8492/BII/7–14, 14 02 1987.Google Scholar