Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T06:12:50.684Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Opportunistic Bargaining: Negotiating Distribution in China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 October 2022

Rongbin Han*
Affiliation:
University of Georgia, Athens, GA, USA
Juan Du
Affiliation:
East China Normal University, Shanghai, China,
Li Shao
Affiliation:
Zhejiang University, Hangzhou, China
*
Corresponding author: Rongbin Han, email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Using a detailed case study of house eviction in peri-urban China as well as original data from an online survey experiment, this article explores the opportunistic bargaining phenomenon in China in which citizens leverage the policy priorities of authorities with tactics that are not approved by the state to bargain for goals beyond those promised by the state. We find that opportunistic bargaining is widely accepted by Chinese citizens and that such an inclination is encouraged by successful precedents and clear signals of an opening through which to leverage government policy priorities; however, it is dampened by unclear signals and failed precedents. We also find that opportunistic bargainers tend to hold more negative perceptions of the current regime and are less likely to abide by state rules or social norms. The characteristics of opportunistic bargaining appear to be the opposite of the dominant “rightful resistance” framework.

提要

提要

本文利用对中国城郊房屋拆迁的详细案例研究,以及在线调查实验的原创数据,探讨了中国的机会主义博弈现象。公民利用当局政策优先目标之间的冲突,采用未经国家认可的机会主义博弈以实现超出国家承诺的目标。我们发现,机会主义博弈作为一种博弈策略被中国公民广泛接受,并且这种倾向会受到地方政府明确的机会结构开放信号和成功先例的鼓励,也会被模糊的机会结构开放信号以及失败先例所抑制。我们还发现,倾向于机会主义博弈的中国公民往往对当前政权持有更为负面看法,并且更可能挑战国家规则或社会规范。这种机会主义博弈的特点与“依法抗争”的主流框架相反。

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of SOAS University of London

Can Chinese citizens negotiate with the strong authoritarian state for conditions that are beyond state-sanctioned rules and promises? What factors may shape their bargaining tactics? What are the implications for authoritarian rule? To explore these questions, we conceptualize and empirically examine the “opportunistic bargaining” phenomenon in urbanizing China. Through the ethnographic observation of house demolition in one village, we show how Chinese citizens may take state goals hostage and employ law-breaching tactics to bargain for wins beyond those promised by the state in ways that are similar to those used by their counterparts in freer societies.Footnote 1 Using an online survey experiment, we find that a perceived opening through which citizens can exploit the authorities’ policy priorities as well as successful precedents encourage opportunistic bargaining; however, murky signals of any opening and failed precedents dampen the inclination. Further, citizens who are opportunistic bargainers hold more negative views of the regime and are less likely to abide by state rules or social norms than those who lean towards rightful resistance. Thus, the phenomenon is more detrimental to authoritarian rule than other types of resistance, which essentially reaffirm regime legitimacy.

Rather than focusing on the institutional factors in citizen participation,Footnote 2 we look into the time- and place-sensitive power negotiations between the state and society through non-institutional channels. The bargaining process and outcome are contingent on the interaction between both parties largely deviating from the formal institutions and state policies. By revealing how the bargaining process plays out, we broaden the spectrum of empirical studies on participation in strong authoritarian regimes, showing that disadvantaged social actors do not necessarily rely on state rules or social norms to bargain.Footnote 3 Instead, they can expand the political opening by forcing local authorities to concede. Since the ways in which citizens perceive and make sense of political openings shape their will and strategy to engage in opportunistic bargaining, this research adds to studies on political opportunity structures by highlighting the interaction between structural factors and actors’ agency.

We reveal a different aspect of the debated paradoxical coexistence of popular contention and authoritarian resilience in China. Opportunistic bargaining, despite falling short of open civil resistance or rebellion, defies the righteousness or benevolence of the regime and refuses to play according to its rules. The temporary stability it allows local authorities to buy is only achieved through the informal, inefficient and uncontrollable brokerage between local authorities and citizens – a mechanism defined by Prasenjit Duara as “state involution” – which erodes state power and legitimacy.Footnote 4 Widespread opportunistic bargaining also disables the policy-feedback function,Footnote 5 thus weakening the state's control over both society and its own local agents. The challenge is even further exacerbated given its contagiousness – not because its success encourages opportunistic bargainers to deviate further but because it motivates citizens who had previously been compliant to join the game.

Bargaining with the Authoritarian State

Strong authoritarian states such as China, with their institutional adaptability,Footnote 6 coercive apparatusFootnote 7 and time- and place-sensitive control capacity,Footnote 8 not only effectively contain popular contention but also turn it into policy input to perpetuate authoritarian rule.Footnote 9 Accordingly, contention in repressive settings is often constrained, with citizens either relying on everyday forms of resistanceFootnote 10 or resorting to in-between forms of resistance that comply with rather than challenge state-sanctioned goals and rules.Footnote 11

Featuring a “hegemonic state”Footnote 12 with strong “despotic” and “infrastructural” power,Footnote 13 China serves as an ideal case to study how citizens negotiate with a high-capacity repressive regime. Kevin O'Brien and Lianjiang Li find that Chinese villagers often deploy “rightful resistance” by making claims based on official rhetoric and commitments, exploiting divisions within the state and operating on the periphery of authorized channels.Footnote 14 Yongshun Cai confirms this point, showing that protestors typically behave in accordance with prevailing statutes and gain leverage by appealing to higher authorities or the media.Footnote 15 Studies further find that Chinese citizens have effectively used the quasi-democratic institutions to their advantageFootnote 16 and can go beyond “moderate forms of collective action”Footnote 17 by employing disruptive, opportunistic or disguised tactics.Footnote 18 The plethora of studies helps to map how protestors exploit political opportunities beyond everyday forms of resistance yet implies a specific set of political opportunity structures, bargaining tactics and state–society dynamics, which we argue fall in the “regime-affirming resistance” paradigm.Footnote 19 In this paradigm, the central government or the regime as a whole appears as benevolent and responsive while local state agents are often villainous; citizens, whether they sincerely support the regime or are simply being instrumental (to avoid repression or increase protest effectiveness), tend to pursue causes sanctioned or even promoted by the state, abide by state rules or norms – at least on the surface – and seek state, public or media approval. Even when citizens use law-breaching tactics, their ostensible goal is to help the party-state improve policymaking and implementation, making the protest “constructive.”Footnote 20 In short, by framing negotiation “in officially approved terms,” whether out of intrinsic trust in the regime's benevolence or a strategic calculation to bargain effectively,Footnote 21 citizens arguably affirm rather than challenge the regime by confirming its legitimacy,Footnote 22 restraining from more threatening mobilization formsFootnote 23 and providing the state with policy feedback.Footnote 24 Implying that the state prescribes the goals and means of bargaining in both normative and instrumental senses, such bargained authoritarianism is self-perpetuating.Footnote 25

However, citizens’ hands and minds are not completely tied by the state. China scholars also find that there can be opportunities for citizens to bargain aggressively with the state. For instance, Ching Kwan Lee and Yonghong Zhang identify three micro-foundations of Chinese authoritarianism, namely protest bargaining, legal-bureaucratic absorption and patron-clientelism. In particular, protest bargaining absorbs social unrest using the logic of market exchange, i.e. by buying-off protesters.Footnote 26 The specific mechanism exemplifies the state's ability to control, but it also implies an opportunity for citizens to hold the state's priorities hostage to bargain for goals beyond state promises with a broader array of tactics. However, while Lee and Zhang have described a system of incentives from the state's perspective, they have not explored the agency and motives of citizens.Footnote 27

Inspired by these studies, the following sections first develop the concept of “opportunistic bargaining” and then explore its dynamics empirically as well as its implications for authoritarian rule.

Conceptualizing Opportunistic Bargaining

“Opportunistic bargaining” is the act of citizens leveraging the policy priorities of authorities with tactics that are not approved by the state to bargain for goals beyond state promises. The term “opportunistic” is not a moral assessment but rather a bargaining logic that differs from “regime affirming.” More specifically, opportunistic bargainers bargain because they are able to secure concessions from the authorities; they harness the state's weak points instead of betting on the regime's benevolence; they make threats instead of filing rights- or rules-based petitions; they are not morally or instrumentally bound by state rules and social norms but are open to all tactics; and, consequently, they do not affirm the legitimacy of authoritarian rule. Table 1 compares opportunistic bargaining to the two major in-between forms of resistance in the China studies field with regard to the causes, opportunity structures, bargaining tactics and implications.

Table 1: Opportunistic Bargaining Compared

In their seminal work on the causes of rebellion, Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler find that the opportunity and ability to build a rebellion group provide more explanatory power than severe grievances such as ethnic and religious divisions, political repression and huge inequality.Footnote 28 Similarly, opportunistic bargainers are more driven by the opportunity and their ability to win concessions than by their sense of being wronged, and they are thus more opportunistic and more sensitive to risks but care less about the righteousness of causes.

Opportunistic bargainers not only leverage one state actor against the other (for example, central versus local authorities as in rightful resistance or constructive noncompliance) but also take the state's policy agenda hostage. While local authorities may selectively implement central policies and abuse their power,Footnote 29 citizens can (threaten to) block local authorities’ policy priorities, thereby incurring extra costs for the latter (such as by delayed policy implementation and the risk of revealing official incompetence to upper levels), which in turn may force the authorities to agree to the citizens’ terms. This means a bigger opening, richer bargaining tactics and more mobilization resources than those offered by the state.

While rightful or constructive resisters may opportunistically use trouble-making tactics, as Xi Chen has documented, they often try to ally with the central government and signal to higher authorities or the public.Footnote 30 At least, they would pretend to do so to make the protest more effective or less risky. Opportunistic bargainers, however, work with local authorities by putting forth their own price for cooperationFootnote 31 and focus on private gains instead of policy changes. Subsequently, they do not seek state approval for their causes or justify their actions with state promises or social norms. Thus, they often do not pursue what Charles Tilly terms as WUNC (i.e. worthiness, unity, numbers and commitment) displays.Footnote 32 And, precisely because opportunistic bargainers do not count on the regime (central government) to be on their side, or at least pretend to be so, they do not have to project a benevolent image of the regime and thus do not affirm the regime's legitimacy.

In sum, opportunistic bargaining conceptually differs from rightful resistance and constructive noncompliance in terms of whether citizens base their actions on grievances outside of state promises or their ability to bring authorities to their terms; whether they abide by state rules and/or social norms (no matter if sincerely or instrumentally); and whether their actions affirm authoritarian rule or not (for example, by relying on state rules or the regime's benevolence, sincerely or strategically).

Admittedly, “opportunistic bargaining” is similar to what Jennifer Pan finds in the contention over the “minimum livelihood guarantee” (dibao 低保) programme. Pan reveals that beyond rule-based resistance, citizens may bargain and win concessions by exploiting the state's preoccupation with stability.Footnote 33 Her conceptual framework echoes ours, although there are some nuanced differences. First, the conception of “rule-based resistance” does not capture contention forms like constructive noncompliance very well. Second, we believe opportunistic bargaining is a broader concept that can also capture Pan's bargaining mechanism because: (1) opportunistic bargaining allows citizens to harness any weakness of the state rather than just the state's obsession with stability, thus it implies a bigger opportunity structure, richer mobilization resources and potentially more tactical options; (2) although seemingly a system under which everyone has the opportunity to bargain (in ways similar to opportunistic bargaining with similar implications), dibao as a method to pre-empt disorder is primarily applicable to a “targeted population” already on the state's radar; and (3) bargainers in Pan's study rely on highly visible dissenting tactics to gain attention while we highlight that citizens can adjust tactics based on a perceived opening, make threats rather than actually be disruptive, and seek a tacit agreement with local authorities while avoiding the media or upper levels’ attention.

Opportunistic Bargaining in Eviction: A Case Study

The phenomenon of “opportunistic bargaining” was first observed by one of the authors when conducting fieldwork in a village in City X, Jiangsu province, for another project in 2009. Since it was upgraded to prefectural level in 1996, City X has undergone a massive wave of industrialization and urbanization, with its urban population rising from 613,000 to 1.64 million from 2002 to 2014.Footnote 34 In this process, thousands of rural families on the urban fringe were evicted. When the author was there, villagers were talking excitedly about a coming eviction while taking a series of preparation steps to bargain for more compensation. No one was actually resisting the eviction, other than some elderly residents who were complaining about losing their traditional rural lifestyle.

The observation was surprising, since negotiating land dispossession is anything but easy in China. Indeed, studies show that land dispossession and eviction have become a major source of state–society conflict in China.Footnote 35 Among the scholars examining the “extent and patterns of dispossession, the complex dynamics driving it, the consequences for farmers, as well as the factors shaping resistance or compliance,”Footnote 36 many have highlighted the disadvantaged bargaining position of citizens, who have very limited options particularly because the state and collective ownership provide political and legal justification for predatory land-grabbing rather than for the protection of evictees.Footnote 37 Moreover, when citizens attempt to bargain or protest, local authorities often resort to coercive methods,Footnote 38 or more innovative modes of control such as bureaucratic absorption, strategic favouritism and collective pressure.Footnote 39 Other than in rare cases, such as “minor property housing” (xiao chanquan fang 小产权房) when low-level authorities and entrepreneurs collude with peasants rendering eviction a non-zero-sum game for the latter,Footnote 40 the best citizens can hope for are fair and expeditious compensation payments, transparent processes and procedures, and public participation.Footnote 41

So why would villagers in City X welcome eviction and actually win concessions without being suppressed? They were not colluding with local authorities, as in a “minor property housing” situation. To solve this puzzle, one of the authors made three field trips between 2009 and 2014 to visit eviction sites, interview evictees and officials and observe the negotiations in several villages on the urban fringe of City X.Footnote 42 The fieldwork data are supplemented and triangulated by government sources such as the official compensation scheme and news reports. The observed bargaining mechanism differs from explanatory frameworks of rightful resistance or constructive noncompliance in the following significant ways.

First, evictees overall did not invoke state promises or claims of rights, instrumentally or sincerely, to legitimize their bargaining. This might be because City X offered relatively generous compensation. Besides being incorporated into the urban social security network of unemployment insurance, pension and medical care in exchange for the loss of farmland, evictees in City X were also compensated for their houses. There were two options for house eviction: cash only or property exchange. Property exchange was more popular as relocation apartments were heavily subsidized. During the fieldwork period, relocation apartments were priced at around 700–800 yuan per square metre while commercial apartments were at least 4,000–5,000 yuan per square metre. Families who chose the property exchange option would typically receive two relocation apartments plus additional cash for their houses and miscellaneous items like trees in the courtyard, and a compliance bonus.Footnote 43 From an outsider's view, the compensation might still look unfair considering the appreciation in the value of the land when it is turned into commercial property; the local residents, however, deemed it to be decent. Given the spiralling housing prices and low farming output (which was at the subsistence level owing to the small land size per capita), they were essentially offered an opportunity to gain from land that they technically did not own and which had little cash value, in addition to the social security benefits that would come with urban residency. City X offered a more generous compensation package than nearby cities. According to an official document, before 2014 City X compensated evictees at a rate equivalent to or higher than new commercial apartments, while two adjacent cities only provided compensation of up to 70 per cent and 80 per cent, respectively. Plus, City X provided an extra 18 per cent eviction bonus.Footnote 44

Second, while evictees generally welcomed the eviction and did not complain about the official compensation scheme, they did not simply accept the offer and move either. Instead, they made extra efforts that often deviated from state rules and social norms for extra compensation. One villager explained their shared rationale: “it is the CCP's money, only a fool would not take it!”Footnote 45 Since the compensation depended on the size and quality of a villager's house, evictees upgraded, expanded or furnished their homes upon hearing about the eviction. Because local authorities had stopped issuing permits, these unauthorized projects were technically illegal and thus not eligible for compensation. Nevertheless, most families rushed to complete these projects. Evictees also planted large numbers of ginkgo and other fruit trees in their courtyards, sometimes so densely that the tree saplings looked like bamboo forests. While planting trees in a courtyard needed no authorization, it was prohibited in the official compensation schemes. Entrepreneurial families even changed their dwellings into commercial or industrial properties for a better compensation offer. As it was difficult to obtain licenses via the normal legal avenues, some evictees simply borrowed or fabricated business certificates with or without the acquiescence of local cadres. Some more creative families expanded or set up new (practically defunct) industrial enterprises for extra compensation. Such tactics were in breach of the regulations, or at the very least dubious, as evictees rarely obtained proper licenses and they did not start real businesses.

Since compensation also depended on the size of a family, some large families split into smaller ones (usually a married couple with a child), allowing each new family to construct their own dwellings to gain extra benefits such as a compliance bonus for moving ahead of the deadline and rental subsidies if the relocation apartments were not ready to move into. Although these actions are legal, they are not entirely compatible with the social norms that value family ties and filial piety. For small families, adding an extra member to the family book could bring in more compensation. The practice is not quite lawful and requires the complicity of local officials, thus it was less openly discussed. Yet these practices are by no means rare, as confirmed by open reports across China.Footnote 46

Some of the tactics employed by City X evictees, although seemingly individualistic and covert, were quite widespread among the evictee communities. This is logical since the evictees, who were living within the same community and had close social ties, learned from each other.Footnote 47 The ethnographic evidence shows that almost all evictee families engaged in opportunistic bargaining, albeit to different degrees with various tactics. Their preferred course of action was primarily shaped by resource constraints, including having access to (1) the monetary investment needed for projects such as upgrading homes and planting trees, and (2) the social resources affecting the viability of certain options such as concocting a business. As monetary resources were more readily available to villagers in City X, we observed more families upgrading their homes and planting trees. In fact, as many families started preparing for eviction simultaneously, the prices of tree saplings, construction materials and labour all rapidly increased.Footnote 48 This group behaviour made the evictees feel more assured in using these tactics, as their neighbours were all doing the same. It also increased their bargaining leverage by (1) allowing them to cite others as examples, thus breaking the authorities’ efforts to individualize negotiations with each family, and (2) making it harder for the authorities to turn them down, as refusing one family might trigger the anger of an entire village. After all, “the law fails where violators are legion” (fa bu ze zhong 法不责众).

Third, evictees in City X aimed at reaching a tacit agreement with local authorities instead of drawing the attention of the upper levels or public to local conditions. This was probably why the evictees, despite asking for much more than what the local government was offering, not justifying their claims with rightful causes and often using law-breaching tactics, were still accommodated rather than suppressed. This was not because local officials were colluding with evictees (as in the “minor property housing” case) or were sympathetic to them (deeming their claims or bargaining tactics to be rightful). On the contrary, local officials were clearly unhappy about the evictees “demanding exorbitant prices.”Footnote 49 It was evictees winning a deal with local authorities through opportunistic bargaining. Evictees knew they could ramp up the costs for local authorities to achieve policy goals such as progressing local development projects and stability maintenance (the fact that City X is the hometown of a top national leader makes this even more crucial for local authorities). Although local authorities could have refused the evictees’ demands given that they asked for far more than what the government had promised and the law-breaching tactics were not sanctioned by the state, these policy priorities helped to convince local authorities that concession was more appealing than suppression. Meanwhile, in order to reach a tacit agreement of exchanging cooperation for extra compensation, evictees generally did not attempt to attract the attention of the public or upper levels.

The case of City X is not idiosyncratic. In addition to the cases recorded by scholars,Footnote 50 searching two specific law-breaching tactics, “unauthorized building” (weijian 违建) and “fake divorce” (jialihun 假离婚) with “eviction” (chaiqian 拆迁) in the China Core Newspapers Full-Text Database yields over 7,200 reports between 2000 and 2017 across China (Appendix 2). While this does not mean evictees succeed in all these cases, it does imply that many evictees expect such tactics to work. As one local official from Chongqing put it:

Villagers want to push their luck. They believe that as long as they make it a fait accompli, the government would have to compensate them regardless. More building means more compensation; less building means less compensation; no building means zero compensation. With such a rationale, villagers compete with each other, leading to massive illegal buildings.Footnote 51

The Survey Experiment

While the analysis of eviction negotiation in City X and elsewhere reveals the mechanism of opportunistic bargaining nicely, it suffers from limited external validity. Therefore, we conducted a survey experiment, which we first piloted among college students in Beijing in March 2018 and then fully implemented online from 15 November to 15 December 2018 using a survey company to recruit respondents across China.Footnote 52 With 1,998 complete responses, the survey yields an analytical sample of 1,824 observations after dropping rushed survey responses (completed in less than four minutes, n = 97) and any that failed manipulation check questions (n = 77).

The survey experiment is primarily designed to test if opportunistic bargaining as an eviction negotiation strategy is indeed broadly accepted and, if so, which conditions encourage or dampen the inclination. For this purpose, we designed a house eviction vignette, randomly exposing respondents to eight hypothesized scenarios in which their relatives were facing eviction.Footnote 53 We measured the opportunistic bargaining inclination in eviction (hereafter OBE) by asking if respondents would recommend such a strategy (definitely not = 1; maybe not = 2; maybe yes = 3; definitely yes = 4). We probe the conditions that may dampen or encourage OBE by manipulating signals of the opening to leverage local authorities and the perceived prospect of success. We expect that clearer signals of the opening and successful precedents will increase OBE while murkier signals of opening and failed precedents will reduce the inclination.

In addition to the experiment, we also asked further questions in our survey to explore whether OB is applicable beyond eviction, whether it is associated with certain socioeconomic and attitudinal traits, and whether it differs empirically from other patterns of resistance, as discussed in Table 1. We measured the general inclination to opportunistic bargaining, rightful resistance, and constructive noncompliance. As Table 2 shows, respondents were asked to rate four general statements, two on opportunistic bargaining (OB1 and OB2), and one each on rightful resistance (RR) and constructive noncompliance (CNC).

Table 2: Measurements of the Key Concepts

Notes: All variables are measured on a 1–4 scale and standardized to 0–1 for analysis.

Based on the earlier discussion in Table 1, opportunistic bargaining, rightful resistance and constructive noncompliance imply different socio-political attitudes and behaviour. To examine the reasoning, we included the following variables in our survey in addition to regular demographic variables. First, we measured respondents’ political attitudes such as political trust and confidence in the government performance. Second, opportunistic bargaining implies readiness to deviate from social norms or state rules while rightful resistance suggests the opposite; constructive noncompliance shall fall in-between. We asked a set of questions to measure respondents’ inclination to abide by social norms and the inclination to play with state rules. Finally, aiming at a tacit agreement with local authorities, opportunistic bargainers shall avoid media or public attention rather than try to attract it. We asked whether respondents would advise their relatives to accept a media interview request if local cadres were found to be gaining extra compensation with unlawful tactics. For a full list of the variables and summary statistics, see Appendix 6.

Treatment design in the experiment

The case study and the literature suggest that opportunistic bargaining may be conditional on two types of factors: the example of others and the perceived opening to leverage government policy priorities. Thus, we constructed the treatments by citing one or more of the following five conditions: the neighbours of the respondents’ relatives were engaging in opportunistic bargaining (neighbours); some opportunistic bargainers had failed (lose); some opportunistic bargainers had succeeded (win); local authorities intended to maintain social stability (government's stability need); and local authorities hoped to complete the project sooner to generate economic benefits and avoid losses (project need).

In total, we have seven treatment groups. With Treatment 1 (including only the “neighbour” condition), we intend to see whether respondents will be emboldened upon learning about other opportunistic bargainers. We expect this to be the case because (1) opportunistic bargaining is often a group behaviour, and (2) more participants often signal richer mobilization resources and a greater opening for bargaining.Footnote 54 The impact may not be that strong because the control group was also exposed to a latent treatment as all respondents were asked if they would recommend opportunistic bargaining tactics to their relatives – we have to refer to such behaviour to measure a respondent's inclination. We deem this acceptable because while this problem weakens our treatment effects in all testing groups, it does not invalidate our findings. We also included the “neighbour” condition in all other six treatments because it makes little sense to say some failed or won without mentioning that there were people actually engaging in opportunist bargaining in the first place. In addition to “neighbour,” Treatments 2 and 3 included information about the prospect of losing or winning, and we expect strongly negative (T2) and positive (T3) effects, respectively. In Treatments 4 and 5, besides the “neighbour” factor, we introduced local authorities’ stability maintenance and project needs to test whether citizens will leverage authorities’ policy priorities. We do not expect a strong impact from T4 or T5 because each of the two treatments alone sends only a murky signal of the opportunity. While the stability maintenance or project needs may incentivize authorities to pay citizens off, they may also induce suppression.Footnote 55 The murkiness is designed to imitate the reality that citizens do not possess explicit information about authorities’ intentions or capacity. To reveal citizens’ choices in different informational conditions, we combined local authorities’ stability and project needs in Treatment 6, expecting a strong positive impact as the two conditions together make the signal of an opening clearer. We combine all conditions except the prospect of losing in Treatment 7, expecting a strong positive impact with both explicit signals of an opening and successful precedents.

Table 3 summarizes the treatment assignments and the expected outcomes. For the detailed setup of control and treatment groups, see Appendix 7.

Table 3: Treatments and Expected Effects

Before presenting the findings, it is important to address two concerns with the design. First, one may question if an online survey is sufficient to elicit a representative sample. While this concern is justified, the experimental design enables us to test the impact of treatments, so even non-representative samples can generate valid findings.Footnote 56 Second, there is the question of whether respondents would answer the questions honestly, since using law-breaching tactics is sensitive. We believe this shall not invalidate our findings given the experimental design. We further alleviate this issue by introducing the scenarios in which not the respondents but rather their relatives are experiencing eviction.

Experiment results

Figure 1 illustrates the experiment results. Merely knowing of the existence of OB (T1) did not significantly increase the tendency to engage in OB. Respondents exposed to failed cases (T2) are less likely to recommend opportunistic bargaining than the control group (a drop of 6.9 per cent). For respondents exposed to successful cases (T3), OBE increases by 5.3 per cent compared to the control group. Signals of an opening through which to leverage policy priorities work as expected, showing a positive impact when combined (T6) compared to the control group (increases by 4.6 per cent), but not separately (T4 and T5). When the opening signals are combined with winning cases (T7), OBE significantly increases by 7.3 per cent compared to the control group.

Figure 1: Experimental Treatment Effects on OBE

Notes: Means of OBE; 95% confidence intervals. The DV is recoded to 0–1. The dashed line indicates the control group as the baseline for comparison.

As expected, respondents are more inclined to engage in opportunistic bargaining if they learn that others are doing so, if such a strategy works and when they can exploit local authorities’ policy concerns. The results also show that it is important for respondents to receive clear and explicit signals about a political opening for bargaining. When respondents are only told that local authorities want to maintain stability (T4) or finish the project sooner (T5), in each scenario it was not self-evident to respondents whether the authorities would accommodate opportunistic bargaining or deal with it forcefully. Such uncertainty helps to amplify silence.Footnote 57 When the two conditions appear together in T6, the political opening signals are clearer to respondents, encouraging opportunistic bargaining. The inclination further increases when clear political opening signals are accompanied by successful precedents (T7). Overall, while citizens are quite risk averse, explicit opening signals and successful precedents can effectively mobilize them to choose opportunistic bargaining.

To check the robustness of the experiment findings, we conducted regression analysis with additional data from our survey by controlling for demographics, political attitudes and the inclination to abide by social norms or state policies. The results remain consistent. For details, see Appendix 8.

Since we have multiple treatment groups, some of which are closely related, we compute Romano-Wolf adjusted p-values to correct for the probability of making a false discovery among multiple comparisons.Footnote 58 Our findings are generally robust to the test: respondents exposed to failed cases (T2) / successful cases (T3) are less / more likely to choose opportunistic bargaining than respondents in the control group; respondents are more inclined to engage in opportunistic bargaining if there are clear opening signals and successful precedents (T7). The only differences are that T3 and T6 now occasionally have positive but insignificant effects.Footnote 59 We have also explored if our treatments have heterogeneous effects across respondents’ demographics. The findings suggest that more resourceful citizens are more willing to take risks, while those who are less resourceful are more risk averse in opportunistic bargaining.Footnote 60

Opportunistic Bargaining, Rightful Resistance and Constructive Noncompliance

The experiment confirms that opportunistic bargaining as an eviction-negotiation strategy is broadly accepted among Chinese citizens and is affected by signals of a political opening and precedents. Then, as a broader concept, does opportunistic bargaining go beyond eviction? How does it compare to rightful resistance and constructive noncompliance? To answer these questions, we turned to an exploratory analysis by running 70 ordinary least-squares regression models involving each of the 14 attitudinal and behavioural variables we collected with control variables on our five dependent variables. We restricted the sample of analysis to the control group to avoid post-treatment bias (N = 194). We have visualized the results in Figure 2 with each subplot showing the results of five models, i.e. the coefficients with 95 per cent confidence intervals of each attitudinal and behavioural variable on all five dependent variables.Footnote 61

Figure 2: Comparing OB, CNC and RR

Notes: The shapes of dots represent the dependent variables (detailed in Table 2); each spike maps the coefficient and 95% CI of the independent variable (the title of the respective subplot); control variables included.

The results confirm that opportunistic bargaining bears a different set of attitudes from rightful resistance while showing similar features to constructive noncompliance. As far as the political attitude variables are concerned, OB and CNC are in general associated negatively with trust in the central and local governments, preference for the regime, confidence in regime stability or its economic prospects, and belief in public interests over private interests. RR presents an opposite pattern on many of these variables. Those who agree more with RR have more trust in the central government and a higher evaluation of the regime's performance, while at the same time showing more confidence in regime stability and its economic prospects. Regarding the norms-deviating measures, OB and CNC are positively associated with evading fares, defaulting on reservations and paying bribes, while RR shows opposite traits consistently. Regarding political participation, RR is associated with more institutional participation like lawsuits and petitions while OB is more associated with protests (the result for CNC is not statistically significant). Finally, neither OB nor CNC welcome publicity, while RR is ready for a media interview.

Contrary to our expectations, constructive noncompliance has shown highly similar results with opportunistic bargaining. This might be because our CNC variable failed to differentiate the two concepts properly because opportunistic bargainers may also agree with the CNC statement that “law-breaching protest is acceptable if one's lawful rights are violated.”Footnote 62 Nevertheless, although the comparison between opportunistic bargaining and constructive noncompliance is inconclusive, the differentiation between opportunistic bargaining and rightful resistance is explicit and systematic. Opportunistic bargainers, while focusing primarily on private gains rather than openly contesting state policies or demanding democracy, are not regime-affirming as they hold negative views of the regime and deviate from state rules. Building on previous studies,Footnote 63 we can safely conclude that opportunistic bargaining situates at the intersection between open and hidden activism as well as that between regime-affirming and regime-challenging.Footnote 64

Conclusion

Since the 1989 Tiananmen movement, China has gradually created “a multiagency juggernaut” of stability maintenance with a formidable coercive apparatus,Footnote 65 a huge amount of resources and cadre incentives,Footnote 66 as well as highly innovative strategies and techniques to defuse social unrest.Footnote 67 This has created a dire situation for citizens who wish to bargain for benefits. However, we articulate that even in such a highly repressive setting, citizens can bargain for promises beyond those on offer by the state through opportunistic bargaining. Unlike regime-affirming resisters who sincerely count on or strategically exploit state rules or the regime's benevolent image, opportunistic bargainers do not seek state or social approval for their means and goals in bargaining. Instead, they take local authorities’ policy priorities hostage in order to “extort” benefits. As Kevin O'Brien notes, citizens do not just “fill spaces that the state and its reforms create, but also push against boundaries in ways that cannot be read straight off an opportunity structure” and may create their own opportunities by persistently probing the limits.Footnote 68 Through a case study on eviction and a broader survey experiment, we have empirically confirmed that opportunistic bargaining is widely embraced by Chinese citizens, especially when there are clear signals of political openings and successful precedents. In addition, opportunistic bargainers demonstrate opposite traits to rightful resisters, as they harbour negative perceptions towards the regime and are ready to deviate from state rules or social norms. Our findings add to the burgeoning literature on China's bargained authoritarianism by probing the conditions and mechanisms through which citizens may aggressively bargain with government as well as the subsequent implications.

Without any intention to make a moral judgement, we deem opportunistic bargaining to be an important part of Chinese citizens’ continuous endeavour to define, defend and demand their social, economic and political interests. For Kevin O'Brien, Chinese villagers are “occupying an intermediate position between subjects and citizens.”Footnote 69 Greg Distelhorst and Diana Fu identify three types of citizenship in China: subjecthood (citizens positioning themselves as subalterns before benevolent rulers), authoritarian legal citizenship (citizens appealing to the state's formal legal commitments) and socialist citizenship (citizens appealing to officials’ moral duties).Footnote 70 Since opportunistic bargainers make claims not out of “rules consciousness”Footnote 71 or “rights consciousness,”Footnote 72 but because they have the ability to bargain, they are not compliant subjects that define their goals and the means within state rules, nor rights conscious actors pursuing a more complete citizenship. They are hardly “villains” or “victims” – the stereotypical images of evictees and protesters at large that are often portrayed by the media, state and academics.Footnote 73 Rather, they are rational, cunning actors exploiting existing opportunities under the regime to the maximum. Also, as opportunistic bargaining does not intend to attract the media's attention or to signal local conditions to upper levels, it is more a form of “destructive superficial compliance.” While it helps to buy stability for now, the process resembles the “state involution” of early 20th-century China where the state's fiscal and functional growth gave rise to the informal, inefficient and uncontrollable brokerage structure of tax collectors, clerks, middlemen and bullies,Footnote 74 which in turn eroded the state's capacity to rule. Indeed, opportunistic bargainers’ negative perception of the regime and their reluctance to follow the state rules are already telling in this regard.

Admittedly, our research has some limitations. First, as mentioned above, further studies may look further into the conceptual differences between opportunistic bargaining and constructive noncompliance since our design has not achieved this goal. Second, we are not looking at more difficult spaces where citizens may not aim at winning private gains while both local and central authorities are unlikely to make concessions (for example, Uyghur independence or Falun Gong). While our survey experiment has shown that opportunistic bargaining is widely observable among citizens out of the context of eviction and some existing studies echo our findings,Footnote 75 it will be productive for future studies to map out the realm where opportunistic bargaining happens and where it does not.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S0305741022001370

Acknowledgements

The authors thank Jeremy Wallace, Martin Dimitrov, Jiangnan Zhu, Lynette Ong and Juan Wang for their constructive feedback. The authors are also grateful for comments from Kevin O'Brien, Yanhua Deng, Yongnian Zheng, Wenfang Tang, H. Christoph Steinhart and Dongtao Qi on an earlier partial draft of the article. Yuan Wang, Jenica Moore, Linan Jia and Steve Kaszycki have provided valuable research assistance to this project.

Conflicts of interest

None.

Rongbin HAN is an associate professor in the department of international affairs at the University of Georgia. His research interests include contentious politics, media and cyber politics, and civic participation in China. He is the author of Contesting Cyberspace in China: Online Expression and Authoritarian Resilience (Columbia University Press, 2018) and has recently published in The China Quarterly, Journal of Contemporary China and Political Research Quarterly, among others.

Juan DU is an associate professor at the School of Public Administration, East China Normal University. Her research focuses on governance, policy process and policy analysis. Her research has been published in Public Administration, Environmental Policy and Governance and Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, among others.

Li SHAO is an assistant professor in the department of political science, School of Public Affairs at Zhejiang University. His research interests include political communication, political behaviour and political attitude. He has recently published in Political Research Quarterly, Journal of Contemporary China, Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies and Political Studies.

Footnotes

1 See Holland Reference Holland2016; Grossman, Phillips and Rosenzweig Reference Grossman, Phillips and Rosenzweig2017.

14 O'Brien and Li Reference O'Brien and Li2006.

15 Cai, Yongshun Reference Cai2010.

18 Chen, Xi Reference Chen2009b; Cai, Yongshun Reference Cai2010; Fu, Diana Reference Fu2017.

19 We acknowledge that the term “rule-based resistance” is often used to capture these studies (e.g. Perry Reference Perry2008; Pan Reference Pan2020). However, “regime-affirming” fits our purpose better because it covers not only “rule-based resistance” but also contention such as “constructive noncompliance,” which involves law-breaching protest tactics.

26 Lee and Zhang Reference Lee and Zhang2013.

28 Collier and Hoeffler Reference Collier and Hoeffler2004.

30 Chen, Xi Reference Chen2009b.

31 Chinese citizens often work with local authorities to seek “justice from below.” See Michelson Reference Michelson2008.

34 Data from City X's Statistical Reports on Socio-Economic Development. Original sources are not provided for reasons of anonymity but are available upon request.

35 Chen, Chih-Jou Jay Reference Chen2020; Luo, Andreas and Li Reference Luo, Andreas and Li2016.

40 Paik and Lee Reference Paik and Lee2012. Note that this implies an unequal power relationship in which evictees depend on local officials and elites, thus showing less agency than that prescribed by opportunistic bargaining.

42 The opportunities, bargaining strategies and outcomes of eviction negotiation vary dramatically depending on the location. For an excellent study on the different dynamics of urban expansion in the urban core, urban fringes and rural fringes, see Hsing Reference Hsing2010.

43 See Appendix 1 in the online supplementary material for a sample compensation scheme.

44 Source available upon request.

45 Interview with an evictee from Village C, T City, 15 February 2010.

46 For instance, see “Chaiqianhu weizao hukou pian chaiqian kuan” (Evictee family fabricated household registration to swindle compensation). Jinghua shibao, 16 November 2006, https://news.sina.com.cn/c/2006-11-16/030410512942s.shtml. Accessed 22 March 2022.

47 This, again, shows that opportunistic bargaining is more inclusive than the bargaining over dibao, which is restricted mostly to the “targeted population.” See Pan Reference Pan2020.

48 Interview with a villager, T City, 28 January 2010.

49 News source is available upon request.

51 “Ruhe youxiao ezhi tuji qiangjian” (How to contain rush construction projects). Zhongguo guotu ziyuan bao, 23 November 2009, http://www.360doc.com/content/11/0809/12/7293128_139116668.shtml. Accessed 22 March 2022.

52 For respondents’ geographic distribution, see Appendix 3 in the online supplementary material; Appendix 4 compares our sample with that of the 43th Statistical Report of Internet Development in China (February 2019) and the internet-active sample from the 2008 China Survey, which represents state-of-the-art sampling.

53 Appendix 5 (in the online supplementary material) shows that all covariates except “eviction experience” are perfectly balanced among the eight groups, indicating successful randomization.

55 Lee and Zhang Reference Lee and Zhang2013.

56 For more discussion on the online survey, see Li, Xiaojun, Shi and Zhu Reference Li, Shi and Zhu2018.

57 Stern and Hassid Reference Stern and Hassid2012.

58 Clarke, Romano and Wolf Reference Clarke, Romano and Wolf2020.

59 For detailed results, see Appendix 9 (available online).

60 For details, see Appendix 11 (available online).

61 For the full tables, see Appendix 10 (available online).

62 Tsai Reference Tsai2015, 264–65.

63 Tsai (Reference Tsai2015, 255–58) provides a nice summary and comparison of subtypes of resistance.

64 Appendix 11 provides additional analysis examining if treatments have heterogeneous effects across respondents’ demographics.

68 O'Brien Reference O'Brien2013, 1053.

69 O'Brien Reference O'Brien2001, 426.

70 Distelhorst and Fu Reference Distelhorst and Fu2019.

75 See Pan Reference Pan2020. There is even evidence of the state “buying stability” in minority regions (see, e.g., Fischer Reference Fischer2015), suggesting that opportunistic bargaining may work should minorities intend to achieve material gains.

References

Andreas, Joel, Kale, Sunila S., Levien, Michael and Zhang, Qian Forrest. 2020. “Rural land dispossession in China and India.Journal of Peasant Studies 47(6), 1109–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellin, Eva. 2004. “The robustness of authoritarianism in the Middle East: exceptionalism in comparative perspective.Comparative Politics 36(2), 139157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biddulph, Sarah. 2015. The Stability Imperative: Human Rights and Law in China. Vancouver, BC: UBC Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blecher, Marc. J. 2002. “Hegemony and workers’ politics in China.The China Quarterly 170, 283303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brownlee, Jason. 2007. Authoritarianism in an Age of Democratization. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cai, Meina, Murtazashivili, Jennifer Brick, Murtazashvili, Ilia and Wang, Hui. 2020. “Sugarcoating the bitter pill: compensation, land governance, and opposition to land expropriation in China.Journal of Peasant Studies 47(6), 1371–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cai, Yongshun. 2003. “Collective ownership or cadres’ ownership? The non-agricultural use of farmland in China.The China Quarterly 175, 662680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cai, Yongshun. 2010. Collective Resistance in China: Why Popular Protests Succeed or Fail. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Chen, Chih-Jou Jay. 2020. “Peasant protests over land seizures in rural China.Journal of Peasant Studies 47(6), 1327–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jidong, Pan, Jennifer and Xu, Yiqing. 2016. “Sources of authoritarian responsiveness: a field experiment in China.American Journal of Political Science 60(2), 383400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Xi. 2009a. “Between defiance and obedience: protest opportunism in China.” In Perry, Elizabeth J. and Goldman, Merle (eds.), Grassroots Political Reform in Contemporary China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 253281.Google Scholar
Chen, Xi. 2009b. “The power of ‘troublemaking’: protest tactics and their efficacy in China.Comparative Politics 41(4), 451471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Xi. 2012. Social Protest and Contentious Authoritarianism in China. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Chuang, Julia. 2014. “China's rural land politics: bureaucratic absorption and the muting of rightful resistance.The China Quarterly 219, 649669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, Damian, Romano, Joseph P. and Wolf, Michael. 2020. “The Romano–Wolf multiple-hypothesis correction in stata.Stata Journal 20(4), 812843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Paul, and Hoeffler, Anke. 2004. “Greed and grievance in civil war.Oxford Economic Papers 56, 563595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deng, Yanhua. 2017. “‘Autonomous redevelopment’: moving the masses to remove nail households.Modern China 43(5), 494522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deng, Yanhua, and O'Brien, Kevin J.. 2013. “Relational repression in China: using social ties to demobilize protesters.The China Quarterly 215, 533552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deng, Yanhua, O'Brien, Kevin J. and Zhang, Li. 2020. “How grassroots cadres broker land taking in urbanizing China.The Journal of Peasant Studies 47(6), 1233–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamant, Neil J. 2000. “Conflict and conflict resolution in China: beyond mediation-centered approaches.Journal of Conflict Resolution 44(4), 523546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Distelhorst, Greg. 2017. “The power of empty promises: quasi-democratic institutions and activism in China.Comparative Political Studies 50(4), 464498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Distelhorst, Greg, and Fu, Diana. 2019. “Performing authoritarian citizenship: public transcripts in China.Perspectives on Politics 17(1), 106121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duara, Prasenjit. 1988. Culture, Power, and the State: Rural North China, 1900–1942. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Edin, Maria. 2003. “State capacity and local agent control in China: CCP cadre management from a township perspective.The China Quarterly 173, 3552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, Andrew M. 2015. “Subsidizing Tibet: an interprovincial comparison of western China up to the end of the Hu–Wen administration.The China Quarterly 221, 7399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fu, Diana. 2017. “Disguised collective action in China.Comparative Political Studies 50 (4), 499527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fu, Hualing, and Gillespie, John (eds.). 2014. Resolving Land Disputes in East Asia: Exploring the Limits of Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer. 2010. Political Institutions under Dictatorship. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gao, Jie. 2015. “Political rationality vs. technical rationality in China's target-based performance measurement system: the case of social stability maintenance.Policy and Society 34(1), 3748.Google Scholar
Göbel, Christian. 2011. “Uneven policy implementation in rural China.The China Journal 65, 5376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Shelby, Phillips, Jonathan and Rosenzweig, Leah R.. 2017. “Opportunistic accountability: state–society bargaining over shared interests.Comparative Political Studies 51(8), 9791011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hassid, Jonathan, and Sun, Wanning. 2015. “Stability maintenance and Chinese media: beyond political communication?Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 44(2), 315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hess, Steve. 2013. “From the Arab Spring to the Chinese Winter: the institutional sources of authoritarian vulnerability and resilience in Egypt, Tunisia, and China.International Political Science Review 34 (3), 254272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heurlin, Christopher. 2016. Responsive Authoritarianism in China: Land, Protests, and Policy Making. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ho, Peter. 2005. Institutions in Transition: Land Ownership, Property Rights, and Social Conflict in China. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holland, Alisha C. 2016. “Forbearance.American Political Science Review 110(02), 232246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hornsey, Matthew J., Blackwood, Leda, Louis, Winnifred, Fielding, Kelly, Mavor, Ken, Morton, Thomas, O'Brien, Anne, Paasonen, Karl Erik, Smith, Joanne and White, Katherine M.. 2006. “Why do people engage in collective action? Revisiting the role of perceived effectiveness.Journal of Applied Social Psychology 36(7), 1701–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsing, You-tien. 2010. The Great Urban Transformation: Politics of Land and Property in China. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, Andrew. 2011. “Chinese authorities keep unrest at bay.” New York Times, 1 March.Google Scholar
Kan, Karita. 2013. “Whither weiwen? Stability maintenance in the 18th Party Congress era.China Perspectives 1, 8793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Ching Kwan, and Zhang, Yonghong. 2013. “The power of instability: unraveling the microfoundations of bargained authoritarianism in China.American Journal of Sociology 118 (6), 14751508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Lianjiang. 2004. “Political trust in rural China.Modern China 30 (2), 228258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Lianjiang. 2010. “Rights consciousness and rules consciousness in contemporary China.The China Journal 64, 4768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Lianjiang. 2013. “The magnitude and resilience of trust in the center: evidence from interviews with petitioners in Beijing and a local survey in rural China.Modern China 39(1), 336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Xiaojun, Shi, Weiyi and Zhu, Boliang. 2018. “The face of internet recruitment: evaluating the labor markets of online crowdsourcing platforms in China.Research and Politics 5(1), 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lora-Wainwright, Anna. 2014. “Grassroots reactions to relocation: the diffusion of compensation strategies.” In Teets, Jessica C. and Hurst, William (eds.), Local Governance Innovation in China: Experimentation, Diffusion, and Defiance. New York: Routledge, 4259.Google Scholar
Lorentzen, Peter. 2013. “Regularizing rioting: permitting public protest in an authoritarian regime.Quarterly Journal of Political Science 8(2), 127158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luo, Qiangqiang, and Andreas, Joel. 2020. “Mobilizing compliance: how the state compels village households to transfer land to large farm operators in China.Journal of Peasant Studies 47(6), 11891210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luo, Qiangqiang, Andreas, Joel and Li, Yao. 2016. “Grapes of wrath: twisting arms to get villagers to cooperate with agribusiness in China.The China Journal 77, 2750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and Its Demise in Mexico. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manion, Melanie. 2016. Information for Autocrats: Representation in Chinese Local Congresses. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mann, Michael. 1984. “The autonomous power of the state: its origins, mechanisms and results.European Journal of Sociology 25(02), 185213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meng, Tianguang, Pan, Jennifer and Yang, Ping. 2014. “Conditional receptivity to citizen participation: evidence from a survey experiment in China.Comparative Political Studies 50(4), 399433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelson, Ethan. 2008. “Justice from above or below? Popular strategies for resolving grievances in rural China.The China Quarterly 193, 4364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nathan, Andrew. 2003. “Authoritarian resilience.Journal of Democracy 14(1), 617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin J. 2001. “Villagers, elections, and citizenship in contemporary China.Modern China 27(4), 407435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin J. 2013. “Rightful resistance revisited.Journal of Peasant Studies 40(6), 1051–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin J., and Deng, Yanhua. 2015. “The reach of the state: work units, family ties and ‘harmonious demolition’.The China Journal 74, 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin J., and Li, Lianjiang. 1999. “Selective policy implementation in rural China.Comparative Politics 31(2), 167186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin J., and Li, Lianjiang. 2006. Rightful Resistance in Rural China. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paik, Wooyeal, and Lee, Kihyun. 2012. “I want to be expropriated! The politics of xiaochanquanfang land development in suburban China.Journal of Contemporary China 21(74), 261279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pan, Jennifer. 2020. Welfare for Autocrats How Social Assistance in China Cares for Its Rulers. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perry, Elizabeth J. 2008. “Chinese conceptions of rights: from Mencius to Mao – and now.Perspectives on Politics 6(1), 3750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perry, Elizabeth J. 2009. “China since Tiananmen: a new rights consciousness?Journal of Democracy 20(3), 1724.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piles, Eva. 2014. “Contending conceptions of ownership in urbanizing China.” In Fu, Hualing and Gillespie, John (eds.), Resolving Land Disputes in East Asia: Exploring the Limits of Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 115172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, Benjamin L., and Michelson, Ethan. 2008. “Mediating the mediation debate: conflict resolution and the local state in China.Journal of Conflict Resolution 52(5), 737764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rozelle, Scott, and Li, Guo. 1998. “Village leaders and land-rights formation in China.The American Economic Review 88(2), 433438.Google Scholar
Sargeson, Sally. 2012. “Villains, victims and aspiring proprietors: framing ‘land-losing villagers’ in China's strategies of accumulation.Journal of Contemporary China 21(77), 757777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sargeson, Sally. 2013. “Violence as development: land expropriation and China's urbanization.Journal of Peasant Studies 40(6), 1063–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, James C. 1985. Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Shambaugh, David L. 2008. China's Communist Party: Atrophy and Adaptation. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Stern, Rachel E., and Hassid, Jonathan. 2012. “Amplifying silence: uncertainty and control parables in contemporary China.Comparative Political Studies 45(10), 1230–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straughn, Jeremy Brooke. 2005. “‘Taking the state at its word’: the art of consentful contention in the German Democratic Republic.The American Journal of Sociology 110(6), 15981650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 2004. Social Movements, 1768–2004. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers.Google Scholar
Truex, Rory. 2016. Making Autocracy Work: Representation and Responsiveness in Modern China. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Truex, Rory. 2019. “Focal points, dissident calendars, and preemptive repression.Journal of Conflict Resolution 63(4), 1032–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsai, Lily L. 2007. Accountability Without Democracy: Solidary Groups and Public Goods Provision in Rural China. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsai, Lily L. 2015. “Constructive noncompliance.Comparative Politics 47(3), 253279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turton, Andrew. 1986. “Patrolling the middle-ground: methodological perspectives on ‘everyday peasant resistance’.Journal of Peasant Studies 13(2), 3648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verba, Sidney, and Nie, Norman H.. 1972. Participation in America: Political Democracy and Social Equality. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Wang, Yuhua, and Minzner, Carl. 2015. “The rise of the Chinese security state.The China Quarterly 222, 339359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wedeman, Andrew. 2012. Double Paradox: Rapid Growth and Rising Corruption in China. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Xie, Yue. 2013. “Rising central spending on public security and the dilemma facing grassroots.Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 42(2), 79109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1: Opportunistic Bargaining Compared

Figure 1

Table 2: Measurements of the Key Concepts

Figure 2

Table 3: Treatments and Expected Effects

Figure 3

Figure 1: Experimental Treatment Effects on OBENotes: Means of OBE; 95% confidence intervals. The DV is recoded to 0–1. The dashed line indicates the control group as the baseline for comparison.

Figure 4

Figure 2: Comparing OB, CNC and RRNotes: The shapes of dots represent the dependent variables (detailed in Table 2); each spike maps the coefficient and 95% CI of the independent variable (the title of the respective subplot); control variables included.

Supplementary material: File

Han et al. supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Han et al. supplementary material(File)
File 416.7 KB