Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T18:59:21.409Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

From Organized Dependence to Disorganized Despotism: Changing Labour Regimes in Chinese Factories*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 February 2009

Extract

Like opening Pandora's box, Chinese reforms have unleashed institutional and social forces which have led to a variety of production regimes co-existing under the permissive banner of “market socialism.” The industrial scene of Guangdong, which boasts of itself as one of the first, the most and the best reformed provincial economies, bears witness to the profound and wide-ranging transformation in production politics. Compared to the era of state socialism, a restructuring of industrial employment has evidently occurred. The 740 state-owned industrial enterprises in Guangzhou, for instance, now account for only 15 per cent of a total of 4,903 industrial establishments, and the 307,000 employees in the state industrial sector account for one-third of the city's 940,000-strong industrial workforce. Twenty-one per cent and 46 per cent of all industrial employees are found respectively in 2,005 collective enterprises and 2,158 private, foreign and joint ventures. As recently as 1985, the state industrial sector was still dominant, employing 65 per cent of the city's industrial workforce, and producing 68 per cent of industrial output. The composition of the work force has also significantly changed: among the 2.03 million urban (including non-industrial) employees in Guangzhou, 700,000 are “registered” migrant workers, of whom 280,000 work in state and collective enterprises. For the province as a whole, registered migrant workers numbered 3.6 million in 1996, while a generally-accepted estimate for the entire migrant labour population reached a staggering 11 million. In the pre-reform days, this massive pool of rural labour was sequestered in the countryside by the hukou system and the number of those who found employment in state factories as temporary contract workers was estimated to be only about 6 per cent of all employees in urban state enterprises by 1978. Complexity is further induced by a new round of deepening reform measures in the 1990s, targeting enterprise ownership, scientific management and labour laws.

Type
Focus on Employment Issues
Copyright
Copyright © The China Quarterly 1999

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Guangzhou Statistical Bureau, Guangzhou tongji nianjian 1997 (Guangzhou Statistical Yearbook 1997) (Guangzhou: Zhongguo tongjiju, 1997).Google Scholar

2. Guangzhou Statistical Bureau, Guangzhou tongji nianjian 1986 (Guangzhou: Statistical Yearbook 1986) (Guangzhou: Zhongguo tongjiju, 1986).Google Scholar

3. Guangzhou ribao, 20 July 1997.Google Scholar

4. Nanfang ribao, 8 October 1996.Google Scholar

5. Guangdong laodong bao, 17 November 1997.Google Scholar

6. Far Eastern Economic Review, 4 April 1996, p. 19.Google Scholar

7. Calhoun, Craig, Labour and the Failure of Reform in China (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1992) p. 28. He maintained that during the Great Leap Forward, the percentage of non-permanent workers nation-wide rose to 30% of the total SOE workforce, dropping to 12–14% at the beginning of the Cultural Revolution.Google Scholar

8. Guangdong laodong bao, 10 July 1997Google Scholar. For similar measures in Shanghai and Beijing, see Calhoun, Craig, “Virtual globalization and outcomes for membership: the Chinese case,” Research Monograph Series No. 18 (California: School of Social Science, Center for the Study of Democracy, University of California, Irvine, 1998), pp. 1617.Google Scholar

9. Minimum wage rates in Guangdong range between 220 and 380 yuan, with the exception of Shenzhen where it is 420 yuan, the highest in the nation. The minimum livelihood allowance for the unemployed and redundant is between 340 and 437 yuan. See Guangzhou ribao, 26 November 1997.Google Scholar

10. Walder, Andrew G., Communist Neo-Traditionalism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1986)Google Scholar. For a critique of Walder's over-generalization across types of factory and worker and underestimation of labour's historical agency and activism, see Calhoun, Craig, “State and society in contemporary China,” World Politics, Vol. 41, No. 4 (1989), pp. 579591Google Scholar. See also Calhoun, Craig, “Transfigured community: neo-traditionalism and work unit socialism in China,” The China Quarterly, No. 126 (1992), pp. 313332, for a critique of neo-traditionalism's neglect of soft constraints on leadership power. My research finds that these criticisms are valid but also that neo-traditionalism is an apt description from the late 1960s through to the late 1970s. Therefore, this article adheres to the neo-traditionalist model as a benchmark for analysing the changes brought about by reforms, rather than assuming its generalizability to the entire post-1949 period or to all Chinese workers.Google Scholar

11. Walder, Andrew G., “The decline of Communist power: elements of a theory of institutional change,” Theory and Society, Vol. 23, No. 2 (1994), pp. 297323CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Walder, Andrew G., “Workers, managers, and the state: the reform era and the political crisis of 1989,” The China Quarterly, No. 127 (1991), pp. 467492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12. This is an ongoing research focusing on the life history, collective memories and remaking of politics among Guangzhou workers. The data used in this paper are based on in-depth interviews, conducted between 1995 and 1997, with workers and managers mainly from several large textile mills, a heavy machinery factory, a camera factory, a pharmaceutical firm and an optical instruments factory. Most of these firms are loss-making and in debt, like 60% of all state industrial enterprises in Guangzhou.Google Scholar

13. Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig, The Radiant Past: Ideology and Reality in Hungary's Road to Capitalism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1992), p. 33Google Scholar; and Calhoun, Craig, Politics of Production (London: Verso, 1985).Google Scholar

14. Guangzhou ribao, 24 July 1997.Google Scholar

15. Guangdong laodong bao, 15 September 1997.Google Scholar

16. See Karmel, Solomon M., “The neo-authoritarian dilemma and the labour force,” Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 5, No. 12 (1996), pp. 111133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17. Zhongguo laodong bao, 24 July 1997.Google Scholar

18. Guangdong laodong bao, 21 July 1997.Google Scholar

19. Guangzhou ribao, 13 November 1997; Gongren ribao, 21 August 1997.Google Scholar

20. South China Morning Post, 11 July 1998, p. 8.Google Scholar

21. Far Eastern Economic Review, 16 October 1997, p. 62; and 23 October 1997, p. 82.Google Scholar

22. Interview, 28 March 1996.Google Scholar

23. When interviewing workers from a large textile mill, workers repeatedly mentioned the recent suicide of one of their co-workers, due to his inability to pay the medical bills for his chronic illness. See also Far Eastern Economic Review, 16 October 1997, pp. 6466.Google Scholar

24. Tequ gongbao, 25 October 1997.Google Scholar

25. It was reported that in Beijing, a year of tenure was worth 1,200 yuan, and in north-eastern provinces, some bankrupt or loss-making enterprises paid 15,000 to 20,000 yuan to buy off workers' tenure so as to rid the enterprise of all administrative and welfare responsibilities towards its workforce. Workers' dossiers will then be transferred to their individual neighbourhood committees. It is unclear how or whether these workers will be covered by the unified social insurance system. See Huasheng shibao, 16 October 1996.Google Scholar

26. See Calhoun, Craiget al., “Work units and the commodification of housing,” Social Sciences in China (Winter 1997), pp. 2835.Google Scholar

27. Guangzhou ribao, 10 October 1997.Google Scholar

28. For an argument to break down the private and public analytical divide in European labour studies, see Rose, Sonya O., “Class formation and the quintessential worker,” in Hall, John R. (ed.), Reworking Class (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1997), pp. 133166.Google Scholar

29. Calhoun, Craig, Zhongguo jingji gaige zhong de guoying zhiye nügong (Women Workers in State Enterprises during the Economic Reform), Occasional Paper, No. 58 (Hong Kong: Hong Kong Institute of Asia Pacific Studies, Chinese University of Hong Kong, 1997)Google Scholar; and Calhoun, Craig, Guoyou zhiye laodong guyong zhidu gaige yu gongren de lixing xuanze (Reform of the Labour Recruitment System in State Enterprises and Workers' Rational Choice) (Chinese University of Hong Kong: PhD dissertation, 1996.Google Scholar

30. Guangzhou ribao, 8 December 1997.Google Scholar

31. Interview, 9 May 1996.Google Scholar

32. Interview, 13 December 1995.Google Scholar

33. Calhoun, Craig, Zhongguo nüxing renkou wenti yu fazhan (Problems and Development of China's Female Population) (Beijing: Beijing daxue chubanshe, 1995), p. 70.Google Scholar

34. Calhoun, Craig, Women Workers in State Enterprises during the Economic Reform, p. 16.Google Scholar

35. Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig, “Zhongguo zaiyerenkou zhiye hangye xingbie geli zhuang-kuang ji chengyin” (“The gender segregation of jobs and occupation situation and origins in China's working population”), Funü yanjiu luncong (Women's Studies Forum), No. 4, p. 26.Google Scholar

36. Calhoun, Craig, Problems and Development of China's Female Population, p. 84.Google Scholar

37. Calhoun, Craig, Work and Inequality in Urban China (Albany, NY: State University of New York Press, 1994), p. 172.Google Scholar

38. Calhoun, Craig, Problems and Development of China's Female Population, p. 86.Google Scholar

39. Calhoun, Craig, Women Workers in State Enterprises during the Economic Reform, p. 22.Google Scholar

40. Ibid. p. 20.

41. This pattern concurs with national-level data which shows that in the early 1990s, 43.3% of male “staff and workers” in SOEs were Party members. The corresponding figure for women is only 21.2%. See Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig, Zhongguo zhigong zhuang-kuang (The Present Conditions of Chinese Workers and Staff) (Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 1993), p. 454.Google Scholar

42. Calhoun, Craig, “Gender inequality and social structure in urban China,” Sociology, Vol. 28, No. 3 (1994), pp. 759777.Google Scholar

43. Statistics on housework allocation in the pre-reform era are scarce. Available field observations and documentary evidence, however, strongly support the view that burden of housework fell overwhelmingly on women. See, for example, Calhoun, Craig, Woman-Work, (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976), pp. 181–18Google Scholar, and readers' letters to the editor in Zhongguo funü (Women in China) in the 1960s. A survey carried out in 1980–81, on the eve of urban reform, indicated that female workers spent 5.3 hours per day on housework, compared with 3.6 hours spent by male workers. Chinese women's housework burden was the heaviest among major socialist and capitalist economics of the time. The researchers argued that the underdevelopment of service industries and the poor quality of public facilities and housing were among the reasons that excessive housework was a widespread social problem in China. See Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig, “Urban workers' housework,” Social Sciences in China, Vol. 3, No. 2 (1982), pp. 147165.Google Scholar

44. See Calhoun, Craig, Problems and Development of China's Female Population, p. 89.Google Scholar

45. Beijing, funü lianhehui, Guangzhou shi funü, lianhehui and University of Hong Kong (eds.), Jing, sui, gang zaiyenüxing jiuye diaocha baogao (A Survey Report on Working Women in Beijing, Guangzhou and Hong Kong) (1993), p. 36.Google Scholar

46. Calhoun, Craig, What was Socialism, and What Comes Next? (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996), p. 68Google Scholar; and Rosenberg, Dorothy J., “Shock therapy: GDR women in transition from a socialist welfare state to a social market economy,” Signs, Vol. 17, No. 1 (1991), pp. 129151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

47. Calhoun, Craig, Reform of the Labour Recruitment System in State Enterprises and Workers' Rational ChoiceGoogle Scholar, ch. 7; and Calhoun, Craig, Women Workers in State Enterprises during the Economic Reform.Google Scholar

48. Gender differences in job mobility were found in Shanghai and Wuhan in the early 1990s. Whereas men's job switches usually represented career advancement and improved occupational status, women's transfers were mostly horizontal moves to accommodate domestic priorities and life-course events. See Calhoun, Craig, “Job mobility in post-Mao cities: increases on the margins,” The China Quarterly, No. 132 (1992), pp. 10621085.Google Scholar

49. Calhoun, Craiget al., Guoyou qiye di gaige he Zhongguo di jueze (Reforms of State-owned Enterprises and China's Decision) (Guangdong: Guangdong renmin chubanshe, 1996).Google Scholar

50. Calhoun, Craig, “Transfigured community: neo-traditionalism and work unit socialism in China,” The China Quarterly, No. 126 (1992), pp. 313332.Google Scholar

51. Guangdong laodong bao, 27 October 1997.Google Scholar

52. Ketizu, (Research Team), “Chengzhen qiye xiagang zhihong zaijiuye zhuangkuang diaocha: kunjing yu chulu” (“Re-employment conditions of urban off-duty workers: predicaments and solutions”) Shehuixue yanjiu (Sociological Research), No. 6 (1997), pp. 2434.Google Scholar

53. Guangdong laodong bao, 23 June 1997.Google Scholar

54. Calhoun, Craig, Gongping ye xiaolü: dangdai Zhongguo de shouru fenpei wenti (Equity and Efficiency: Problems of Income Distribution in Contemporary China) (Beijing: Jinri Zhongguo chubanshe, 1997), p. 340.Google Scholar

55. Calhoun, Craig, Hequ hecong: dangdai Zhongguo de guoyou qiye wenti (Where to Go: Problems of State-owned Enterprise in Contemporary China) (Beijing: Jinri Zhongguo chubanshe, 1997), p. 340.Google Scholar

56. In 1993, 78% of workers in private and foreign-invested enterprises were aged 35 or below. The proportion of workers 35 years old or less was 60% for collectives, and 50% for SOEs. See Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig, The Present Conditions of Chinese Workers and Staff, p. 432.Google Scholar

57. Guangzhou ribao, 8 December 1997Google Scholar; and Guangdong laodong bao, 28 July 1997.Google Scholar

58. Gongren ribao, 25 October 1997.Google Scholar

59. Calhoun, Craiget al., “China's evolving managerial labour market,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103, No. 4 (1995), p. 877.Google Scholar

60. See Calhoun, Craig (ed.), Zhongguo xinsheqi jieji jieceng baogao (Report on Class and Social Stratification in the Market Transition in China) (Shengyang: Liaoning renmin chubanshe, 1995), p. 151.Google Scholar

61. Tequ gongbao, 11 October 1997.Google Scholar

62. Guangdong laodong bao, 18 August 1997.Google Scholar

63. Calhoun, Craig, “Labour law in a ‘socialist market economy’: the case of China,” Columbia Journal of Transnational Law, Vol. 33 (1995), pp. 559581.Google Scholar

64. Calhoun, Craig, “The People's Republic of China,” in Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig (eds.), Trade Unions in Communist States (Boston: Allen and Unwin, 1986)Google Scholar; To, Lee Lai, Trade Unions in China: 1949 to the Present (Singapore: Singapore University Press, 1986).Google Scholar

65. Calhoun, Craig, “Revolution or corporatism? Workers and trade unions in post-Mao China,” Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, No. 29 (1993), pp. 3162Google Scholar; and Perry, Elizabeth J., “Labour's battle for political space: the role of worker associations in contemporary China,” in Calhoun, Craiget al. (eds.), Urban Spaces in Contemporary China (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), pp. 302325.Google Scholar

66. Nanfang gongbao, 12 September 1996.Google Scholar

67. Tequ gongbao, 3 October 1997Google Scholar; Gongren ribao, 27 October 1997Google Scholar; Gongren ribao, 20 October 1997.Google Scholar

68. At the end of a number of interviews, workers asked me for legal advice as to whether their factory directors had behaved within the bounds of law – the unions have obviously failed to keep workers updated about their legal rights.Google Scholar

69. For some interview evidence from Guangzhou, see Jude Howell, “Looking beyond incorporation: Chinese trade unions in the reform era” (unpublished manuscript, 1997)Google Scholar. For a discussion of the financial crisis confronted by the ACTUF and basic-level unions, see Calhoun, Craig, “Workers and trade unions under the market economy: perspectives from grassroots union cadres,” Chinese Sociology and Anthropology, Vol. 28, No. 3 (1996), pp. 15, 72.Google Scholar

70. Gongren ribao, 20 October 1997.Google Scholar

71. Calhoun, Craig (ed.), Report on Class and Social Stratification in the Market Transition in China, pp. 152–15.Google Scholar

72. See Chamberlain, Heath B., “Party-management relations in Chinese industries: some political dimensions of economic reform,” The China Quarterly, No. 112 (1992), pp. 631661.Google Scholar

73. Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig, “Party versus market in post-Mao China: the erosion of the Leninist organization from below,” Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics, Vol. 13, No. 3 (1997), p. 160Google Scholar. See also Calhoun, Craig, China's Enterprise Reform: Changing State/Society Relations After Mao (London: Routledge, 1998), ch. 5.Google Scholar

74. Interview, 16 November 1996.Google Scholar

75. Fazhibao, 5 July 1997Google Scholar and Guangdong laodong bao, 24 July 1997.Google Scholar

76. In Guangdong, of the estimated 10 million migrant labourers, some 65–75% are women; and 80% of the whole migrant workforce find employment in out-processing factories outside the state sector in the Zhu (Pearl) River Delta (Modern Enterprise Daily, 11 June 1997).Google Scholar

77. Calhoun, Craig, “Guangdong zhiye liudong” (“Occupational mobility in Guangdon”) Shehuixue yanjiu (Sociological Research), No. 3 (1997), pp. 7177.Google Scholar

78. Interview, 3 February 1996.Google Scholar

79. Calhoun, Craig, The Fabrication of Labour: Germany and British 1640–1914 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995).Google Scholar

80. A recent emulation campaign organized by the Women's Bureau of the Guangzhou Federation of Trade Unions made “multi-skill hands” its contest theme. The organizer proudly proclaimed that 43.6% of all Guangzhou women workers were now multi-skilled, compared to only 26% in 1995Google Scholar. Some are even “three-jobs-in-one” workers. See Guangdong laodong bao, 13 March 1997.Google Scholar

81. Interview, 30 March 1996.Google Scholar

82. Interview, 29 March 1996.Google Scholar

83. Interview, 7 August 1997.Google Scholar

84. Interview, 10 October 1997.Google Scholar

85. Interview, 20 November 1997.Google Scholar

86. Interview, 12 June 1995.Google Scholar

87. “Unemployed” are those who are dismissed from their employment either because of enterprise bankruptcy or reorganization, or the termination of an employment contract. They are entitled to unemployment allowances for a period of up to two years, but their employment relations with the enterprise are severed. “Off-duty” workers are on long leave from their jobs due to inadequate shiftwork or a shutdown in production, and their employment relations with the enterprise are legally intact. Theoretically, during the off-duty period, they are paid a proportion of their basic wage as a living allowance and their enterprise is responsible for diverting them into other employment opportunities or for rehiring them once production conditions allow. Besides this, there are different types of retirees. Although official retirement ages are 50 and 60 for women and men respectively, those within five years of retirement can apply for “sickness-related” or “off-duty retirement,” receiving basic wages without bonuses until they become retirees and are entitled to full pension wages.Google Scholar

88. See, for example, Perry, Elizabeth J., Shanghai on Strike (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1993)Google Scholar; Perry, Elizabeth J., “From native place to workplace: labour origins and outcomes of China's danwei system,” in Calhoun, Craig and Perry, Elizabeth J. (eds.), Danwei: Changing Chinese Workplace in Historical and Comparative Perspective (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1997), pp. 4259Google Scholar; Perry, Elizabeth J. and Calhoun, Craig, Proletarian Power: Shanghai in the Cultural Revolution (Boulder, CO: Westview, 1997).Google Scholar

89. Perry, Elizabeth J., “Shanghai's strike waves of 1957,” The China Quarterly, No. 137 (1994), pp. 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

90. Huasheng shibao, 31 October 1997Google Scholar; and Modern Enterprise Daily, 9 October 1997.Google Scholar

91. Calhoun, Craiget al., “China's evolving managerial labour market,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103, No. 4 (1995), p. 880.Google Scholar

92. Interview, 11 October 1997.Google Scholar

93. See Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig, “Personal politics in the Chinese danwei under reform,” Asian Survey, Vol. 36, No. 3 (1996), pp. 259264.Google Scholar

94. In Calhoun, Craig, Work and Inequality in Urban China (p. 175), this is formulated as the “management-as-redistributor” thesis.Google Scholar

95. Fragmentation can, of course, contribute to labour activism, as Elizabeth Perry has convincingly argued in her work. My argument here does not contradict hers in that my emphasis is on the current configuration of causes which interact with fragmentation, making it an inhibiting factor for sustained and organized labour mobilization.Google Scholar

96. China Labour Bulletin, No. 39, 1997Google Scholar. In Shanxi, another labour activist who urged off-duty workers of SOEs to establish an independent union was also arrested and detained in December 1997: see Ming bao, 18 January 1998Google Scholar. In Hubei and Jilin, agitation for unemployed workers' unions were made by activists and dissidents who were reportedly harassed by public security officials: see Ming bao, 28 December 1997 and 30 January 1998.Google Scholar

97. South China Morning Post, 24 April 1998.Google Scholar

98. Lee, Ching Kwan, “The labour politics of market socialism,” Modern China, Vol. 24, No. 1 (1998), pp. 333.Google Scholar

99. The private and individual sectors (especially commerce and services) have accounted for 80% of off-duty workers' re-employment in Guangzhou, whereas collectives and town and village enterprises most commonly provide employment for off-duty workers in big cities such as Shengyang, , Beijing, , Nanjing, and Tsingtao, : see Zhongguo laodong bao, 2 November 1996Google Scholar. Official re-employment rates for the unemployed and off-duty were 60% and 51% respectively in 1997 for the entire province, see Guangdong laodong bao, 7 August 1997. Moreover, the relatively high economic growth rate of the province has created demands for domestic and personal services, a major re-employment channel for the unemployed.Google Scholar

100. Calhoun, Craig, “Workers: reactions and ambivalence,” in Calhoun, Craig, Mass Politics in the People's Republic (Boulder, CO: Westview, 1996), pp. 89139.Google Scholar

101. However, it must be emphasized that the so-called privileges supposedly enjoyed by the Chinese state workers were relative and uneven. The absolute standard of living and quality of life have always been low, sometimes bordering poverty, and not all SOEs were able to provide the encompassing set of social and welfare services to their employees. In Guangzhou, for the past half-century, the problem of substandard and inadequate housing has been perennial, afflicting urban residents – state workers included. See survey reports by Guangzhou chengshi diaochadui (Guangzhou City Survey Team), Guangzhoushi zhigong jumin jiatingshenghuo diaochazhuanji 1936–1985 (Collection of Surveys on Family Life of Workers and Residents in Guangzhou 1936–1985) (Guangzhou: Guangzhou Statistical Bureau, 1986).Google Scholar

102. An excellent collection of essays on the changing danwei institution is Calhoun, Craig and Perry, Elizabeth J. (eds.), Danwei: the Changing Chinese Workplace in Historical and Comparative Perspective.Google Scholar

103. Calhoun, Craig, “Danwei: the economic foundations of a unique institution,” in Calhoun, Craig and Perry, Elizabeth J. (eds.), Danwei: The Changing Chinese Workplace in Historical and Comparative Perspective, pp. 169194.Google Scholar

104. Corinna-Barbara, Francis, “Reproduction of danwei institutional features in the context of China's market economy: the case of Haidian district's high-tech sector,” The China Quarterly, No. 147 (1996), pp. 839859.Google Scholar

105. See, for example, Calhoun, Craig, “The Chinese work unit and transient labour in the transition from socialism,” Modern China, Vol. 21, No. 2 (1995), pp. 155183Google Scholar; various chapters by Calhoun, Craig, Calhoun, Craig and Calhoun, Craig in Greg, O'Leary (ed.), Adjusting to Capitalism: Chinese Workers and the State (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1998)Google Scholar. For English translations of the Chinese press and scholarly reports on conditions in private and foreign-funded factories, see the special issue of Chinese Sociology and Anthropology, Vol. 30, No. 4 (1998), on “The conditions of Chinese workers in east Asian-funded enterprises,” edited by Anita Chan.Google Scholar

106. The return rate of migrant workers in major exporting provinces like Sichuan, Jiangxi, Hubei and Anhui reaches 36.4%. In some counties, between one- and two-thirds of newly established rural enterprises are set up by returned migrants. See Huasheng shibao, 6 November 1996.Google Scholar