Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T08:00:44.493Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Satisfaction with Democracy: The Impact of Institutions, Contexts and Attitudes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2023

Fred Cutler*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of British Columbia, 1866 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z1, Canada
Andrea Nuesser
Affiliation:
Hydro One, 483 Bay St. (South Tower), 8th Floor Reception Toronto, Ontario, M5G 2P5, Canada
Benjamin Nyblade
Affiliation:
UCLA School of Law, 385 Charles E Young Dr E, Los Angeles, CA 90095, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We propose a new, unified approach for comparative research on citizens’ satisfaction with democracy (SWD). It starts with a well-specified individual-level model of the considerations citizens draw upon when answering the SWD survey question. Then we specify the relationship from contextual factors (especially institutions) through these individual-level mediating considerations and on to the SWD attitude. Multilevel structural equation estimation is applied to a merged dataset of European Social Survey (ESS) and country-level contextual data. The results add solidity to theoretical and empirical findings that citizens’ judgments of democracy are driven mostly by policy outputs and lived experience and not much by institutional variation or its political consequences.

Résumé

Résumé

Cet article examine les recherches sur la satisfaction des citoyens envers la démocratie (SCD) et suggère une nouvelle orientation pour la recherche. Nous proposons un modèle théorique global des déterminants institutionnels et individuels de la satisfaction des citoyens envers la démocratie et estimons ce modèle à l'aide d'enquêtes transnationales et de données macroéconomiques. Nous commençons par un modèle de SCD complet et distinct au niveau individuel et élaborons une théorie empirique qui spécifie la relation entre les facteurs contextuels (en particulier les institutions), les médiateurs au niveau individuel et le résultat - la satisfaction envers la démocratie. Nous utilisons ensuite une estimation d'équation structurelle (médiation) multiniveau (Preacher et coll., 2010) pour évaluer notre modèle sur un ensemble de données fusionnées de l'Enquête sociale européenne et de données contextuelles au niveau national. Les résultats fournissent une base théorique et empirique plus solide pour les conclusions selon lesquelles les jugements des citoyens sur la démocratie se fondent principalement sur les résultats et l'expérience vécue, et non sur la variation institutionnelle ou ses conséquences politiques.

Type
Research Article/Étude originale
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial reuse or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Canadian Political Science Association (l’Association canadienne de science politique) and/et la Société québécoise de science politique

Introduction

Evaluating the quality of democracy and why its quality varies across countries are important tasks. But how should we judge the quality of democracy? While some scholarship has taken normative standards from democratic theory and proposed measurement of macro-level indicators of democratic quality (Diamond and Morlino, Reference Diamond and Morlino2005; Merkel et al., Reference Merkel, Buehlmann, Müller, Wessels, Boess, Moeller and Skaaning2013), it is natural instead to measure it more democratically and turn to subjective assessments by citizens themselves. How satisfied are citizens with the way democracy works in their country? What makes them more (and less) satisfied? Pickel (Reference Pickel, Breustedt and Smolka2016) has shown that citizens’ perspectives are complementary to the macro-level measurements (see also Fuchs and Roller, Reference Fuchs and Roller2018), so these judgments are a worthy indicator of the quality of democracy.

Accordingly, a large body of recent scholarship—over 70 published papers in the last two decades—looks to individual characteristics and institutional and economic contexts to explain variation in the standard satisfaction with democracy (SWD) survey question now asked regularly all over the world (“How satisfied are you with the way democracy works in [country]?”). Numerous studies have employed SWD as a dependent variable, but collectively they have not generated robust conclusions about the links between institutions and the quality of democracy. Many of these studies find, not surprisingly, that citizens’ economic well-being and voting (recently) for winning parties lead to greater satisfaction (see, for example, Blais and Gelineau, Reference Blais and Gélineau2007; Henderson, Reference Henderson2008; Blais et al., Reference Blais, Morin-Chassé and Singh2017). Contextual factors consistently linked to SWD are democratic “outputs” such as economic growth and fair, efficient service delivery (Dahlberg and Holmberg, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2012, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2014; Linde and Dahlberg, Reference Linde, Dahlberg, Bågenholm, Bauhr, Grimes and Rothstein2021). But there is nothing approaching a consensus in this literature on the effect of different political institutions. The most stimulating institutional pattern is the one found in the seminal Anderson and Guillory (Reference Anderson and Guillory1997) paper between the various institutions of “consensus democracy” and lower dissatisfaction among citizens who do not support parties in government—“losers” in the parlance of this literature (Curini et al., Reference Curini, Jou and Memoli2012; Dahlberg and Linde, Reference Dahlberg and Linde2016). Other than these findings, knowledge has not cumulated. The field could be called hyper-empirical, with each new study formulating a new model, often including one or two new variables or interactions but not building solidly on a common core of cumulating findings.

We propose a revised theoretical and statistical model of the determinants of citizens’ satisfaction with democracy and test it with cross-national survey and macro data. The key is to start with a comprehensive model of SWD at the individual level. We contend that institutions can only affect citizens’ judgments of democracy through those institutions’ impacts on citizens’ lives, their political experiences, and their judgments of how social and economic structures function around them. These are the considerations citizens draw on when answering the SWD survey question.

Next, in our empirical theory and statistical modelling, in contrast to much existing work, we are not willing to specify an empirical model of satisfaction with democracy where individual-level variables are “controls” and macro context or institutional variables enter the model as independent influences on individual-level satisfaction with democracy. In our model, macro variables influence attitudes and behaviours that then add up in citizens’ heads as they answer the SWD question. We conclude the article by estimating the model as best we can with existing survey data, but we caution that the results are a first step rather than a final statement about the impact of institutions on the quality of democracy.

How Satisfying Is Satisfaction Research?

After reviewing more than 70 studies with the SWD dependent variable, we note three problems that prevent progress toward better understanding of how it varies across countries. The problems are conceptual, theoretical and statistical.

First, studies of SWD are not having the impact they should in mature democracies at least in part because of the legacy of debate about the concept behind it. The SWD measure grew out of a field of study focused on the stability of democratic regimes and was used to gauge regime support and legitimacy (Easton, Reference Easton1965, Reference Easton1975; see also Canache et al., Reference Canache, Mondak and Seligson2001; Linde and Ekman, Reference Linde and Ekman2003; Linde and Dahlberg, Reference Linde, Dahlberg, Bågenholm, Bauhr, Grimes and Rothstein2021). Yet it has become a standard question in surveys in consolidated democracies, and indeed most of the research using the question is now on cross-national datasets from these countries. Most of those working with SWD data from these countries justify the data's use by arguing that it provides a valid measure of how democracy is practised in a specific place, as experienced by the citizen (see, for example, Bernauer and Vatter, Reference Bernauer and Vatter2012; Curini et al., Reference Curini, Jou and Memoli2012). However, there seems to be continuing concern that SWD may measure support for democracy as a form of governance, on the one hand, or measure support for the current government, on the other.

We agree with recent interventions that argue SWD should be interpreted as measuring a concept between these two extremes (Valgarðsson and Devine, Reference Valgarðsson and Devine2022; Norris, Reference Norris and Norris2011). In mature democracies, SWD is not a measure of preference for democracy as against other forms of government, since in nearly all these countries over 90 per cent of citizens think that democracy is best, yet aggregate SWD varies from about 40 per cent to 90 per cent. The other extreme would be to say that SWD is merely a judgment of the current authorities (Linde and Ekman, Reference Linde and Ekman2003), but this can't be, since in most countries aggregate satisfaction moves only glacially as compared with much bigger swings in government support (Christmann, Reference Christmann2018). So the field should be more confident that the SWD question is the clearest and most consistent indicator of the balance sheet for democracy within and across countries (Kölln and Aarts, Reference Kölln and Aarts2021) and the single best indicator for learning about the effects of institutions on the quality of democracy.Footnote 1

The second problem involves the tension between macro-level concerns and individual-level data. The issue is not that analysis proceeds at the macro level, with macro-level determinants linked to macro indicators such as SWD. We do not quarrel with macro work confined to the macro level (Devine and Turnbull-Dugarte, Reference Devine and Turnbull-Dugarte2021) or that includes only socio-demographic controls (Quaranta and Martini, Reference Quaranta and Martini2016). The problem is that many recent studies include individual-level attitudes and characteristics as determinants of SWD right alongside the macro factors. There is often a suggestion that country-level institutions and contextual factors operate causally through individual-level experiences and attitudes. However, these arguments are usually incompatible with the statistical model deployed in the empirical work. Moreover, theory is usually only provided for the one or two novel macro-individual linkages that are the focus of a given paper (for example, direct democracy for Bernauer and Vatter, Reference Bernauer and Vatter2012; or the “party choice set” for Dassonneville and McAllister, Reference Dassonneville and McAllister2020).

The notable exception to the general lack of attention to the path from macro influences through to SWD is Christmann (Reference Christmann2018), who uses individual-level data to calculate a composite “democracy perceptions index” and shows that “the effect of ‘objective’ performance is almost completely mediated by subjective evaluations of it” (85). This is, in essence, a reduced-form version of the model we present. We take up the challenge he presents in his concluding paragraph: “It would be an interesting contribution to disaggregate the various attributes of democratic quality and test what exactly drives the relationship [of macro factors] with SWD” (88).

It is impossible at present to cumulate findings across studies because the empirical-theoretical specifications—the macro and individual-level factors chosen for inclusion in a particular study—are so varied. Our Appendix Table A1 inventories 21 papers examining contextual or institutional influences on SWD. We show a matrix of theoretically plausible determinants of SWD and catalogue which variables were present in those papers’ empirical specifications. There is little commonality across studies in either the macro variables or the individual-level variables that have substantive attitudinal-behavioural content. This means that conclusions about the macro-level factors will vary across studies because they affect only the residual variance after the individual factors are partialled out. This may sound like a technical concern, but it is in fact deeply theoretical.

Furthermore, a practical problem is that because macro-level variables can only affect country-level averages of individual-level variables, researchers are in a classic cross-national degrees-of-freedom problem that is often under-acknowledged (see Scruggs, Reference Scruggs2001; Stegmueller, Reference Stegmueller2013; also Christmann, Reference Christmann2018: 85, who acknowledges this explicitly). In studies that include a select few macro-level variables, readers are left wondering whether those are the real macro-level influences or if they are merely correlated with other plausible ones (see, for example, Magalhães, Reference Magalhães2014). Solving this problem is a matter of strong but careful theorizing about the causal processes from exogenous macro factors to citizen attitudes. Without a link from a macro factor to an individual consideration that then feeds into satisfaction, the claim about the macro influence has a “black box” quality.

The third issue is that the statistical models used in the literature, even multilevel ones, mirror this lack of careful theorizing of the macro-micro causal structure. Inclusion of individual-level attitudes and behavioural indicators that are themselves caused by contextual factors will typically produce a total effect of context and institutions that is biased downward, as Christmann (Reference Christmann2018) argues. According to the leading statistical researchers in this area: “MLM approaches do not accommodate mediation pathways with Level-2 outcomes and may produce conflated estimates of between- and within-level components of indirect effects” (Preacher et al., Reference Preacher, Zyphur and Zhang2010: 209).

To take but one example: even Wells and Krieckhaus (Reference Wells and Krieckhaus2006), who aimed to modernize the statistical methodology in SWD research, potentially run afoul of this problem. In reanalysis of the Anderson and Guillory (Reference Anderson and Guillory1997) data, they include political interest as a determinant in a model that attempts to find a link between consensus democracy and satisfaction. But it can easily be argued that consensus democracy promotes citizens’ interest in politics by preventing the disaffection produced by majoritarian structures (see, for example, Lijphart, Reference Lijphart1997; Anderson, Reference Anderson, Loewen and Rubenson2019). If so, this specification might conclude that consensus institutions do not increase SWD because those institutions’ total effect on SWD, specifically the portion mediated by interest, is not evident in the results.

In the language of multilevel mediation analysis the appropriate structure for SWD research is a 2-1-1 design (Preacher et al., Reference Preacher, Zyphur and Zhang2010; Fang et al., Reference Fang, Wen and Hau2019). Country context (level 2) affects citizens’ experiences, attitudes and behaviours (level 1), which then affect SWD (level 1).Footnote 2 The individual-level attitudes, experiences and behaviours are mediators of the contextual effects. Preacher et al. (Reference Preacher, Zyphur and Zhang2010) show that the multilevel structural equation model (MSEM) is the appropriate statistical specification.

A Macro-Micro Theoretical Model of SWD

The first step is to start at the end of the chain and specify the relationship between possible mediators and the outcome of interest. What determines how satisfied are citizens with the way democracy works in their country?

According to survey response theory and research, answers to the SWD question represent spontaneous reactions, not deeply considered, crystallized attitudes (Tourangeau et al., Reference Tourangeau, Rips and Rasinski2000). Responses are constructed by sampling from “considerations” (Zaller, Reference Zaller1992). When asked how democracy “works,” then, citizens may think of a variety of different aspects of democracy and their personal experiences with it, as Kölln and Aarts (Reference Kölln and Aarts2021) demonstrate. We should therefore theorize the considerations that might be relevant as respondents answer.Footnote 3

We imagine the considerations have roughly additive effects: any one of them might add or subtract to overall satisfaction irrespective of the levels of the others. For example, if a person feels that government policy is a long distance from their ideal, that person will be somewhat less satisfied, even if they perceive the system as one that is fair, hears their political voice and results in good economic outcomes.

Because we ultimately want to link institutional differences to the quality of democracy, our theoretical specification of intervening individual-level considerations must be exhaustive. We need to account for all the attitudes and behaviours that might have a statistically significant effect on SWD so that it is plausible that all contextual-institutional effects will operate through these individual-level variables.

It is important to note that any particular institutional or contextual factor may have different effects on different individual-level considerations. Institutions are best understood as trade-offs, so the modelling must allow for this. While it may be enlightening to learn about the reduced-form total effect of an institution on SWD, the more satisfying approach we propose will enable researchers to see how a given institution may contribute positively in some respects, while detracting in other ways.

We propose the following exhaustive set of considerations—individual-level criteria for democracy—that may affect SWD. In doing so, we are drawing on a huge literature recently summarized by Linde and Dahlberg (Reference Linde, Dahlberg, Bågenholm, Bauhr, Grimes and Rothstein2021). For each consideration, we provide some representative citations that demonstrate the linkage (or themselves review a literature) to support our claim that these cover the important factors in citizens’ judgments of democracy. Perhaps there are others, but it is at these ten that we drew the line; others can be proposed, but surely most can be subsumed into one of the ten.

Citizens will think democracy works well if the following are present:

  1. 1. Engagement. Citizens understand politics and are engaged with it when they wish to be. Furthermore, engagement indicates participation in what we broadly think of as democratic deliberation—even if this is relatively passive participation—which will likely lead to a better understanding of the rationale for political decisions and policies (Warren, Reference Warren2017). From a psychological perspective, unfamiliar objects, or ones about which there is confusion, are viewed more negatively than familiar ones (Garcia-Marques et al., Reference Garcia-Marques, Prada and Mackie2016). Engagement is also precondition for active participation in the process of representation, even minimally in terms of voting (Quintelier and Van Deth, Reference Quintelier and Van Deth2014; Chang, Reference Chang2018).

  2. 2. Representation. Citizens are represented in the formal representative institutions of parliaments and governments, including the total party system. That is, at least some elite political actors, usually parties and their legislators, are acting in those citizens’ interests. In instrumental terms, this reduces the risk that policy will end up a long way from a citizen's ideal point (Anderson, Reference Anderson and J2010; André and Depauw, Reference André and Depauw2017; Ferland, Reference Ferland2021; Urbaniti and Warren, Reference Urbinati and Warren2008). This consideration is where winner-loser status enters our model (see Nadeau et al. [Reference Nadeau, Daoust and Dassonneville2021] for a review of the literature).

  3. 3. Voice. Citizens’ views are voiced in the political dialogue, including in parliaments but also in the courts, the bureaucracy, the media, and civil society. They feel heard in elite discourse, even if it is others who are speaking (Merkley et al., Reference Merkley, Cutler, Quirk and Nyblade2019; Hoerner and Hobolt, Reference Hoerner and Hobolt2020). Dahlberg and Holmberg (Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2014), Reher (Reference Reher2015) and Ezrow and Xezonakis (Reference Ezrow and Xezonakis2011) find that the closer citizens are to their preferred party, the higher their SWD, irrespective of whether their party is in government.

  4. 4. Ideal policy. Actual policy is, or citizens predict it will be, close to citizens’ ideal point in a multidimensional space (Curini et al., Reference Curini, Jou and Memoli2012; Dahlberg and Holmberg, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2014; Ferland, Reference Ferland2021; Mayne and Hakhverdian, Reference Mayne and Hakhverdian2017). This consideration explicitly involves policy outputs, independent of how policy gets made.

  5. 5. Well-being. Citizens are materially secure (Kölln and Aarts, Reference Kölln and Aarts2021; Nadeau et al., Reference Nadeau, Daoust and Arel-Bundock2020). We expect that citizens care primarily about their own and their family's well-being and that they almost universally use their own perceptions of security and well-being as a proxy for a judgment about the political system's effect on them (Quaranta and Martini, Reference Quaranta and Martini2016, Reference Quaranta and Martini2017).Footnote 4

  6. 6. Fairness. Irrespective of policy outputs and representation, democracies are built on fairness, and so we expect perceptions of fair treatment to strongly influence satisfaction with how democracy works, for both selfish and altruistic reasons (Magalhães, Reference Magalhães2016; Magalhães and Conraria, Reference Magalhães and Conraria2018; Mutz and Mondak, Reference Mutz1997). Fairness of the electoral and judicial systems are important elements of this overall judgment. The extent of social protection may be an indicator of fairness that influences SWD (Lühiste, Reference Lühiste2014).

  7. 7. Effectiveness/efficiency/policy output. Citizens believe that the system discourages corruption and waste and is able to produce welfare-maximizing collective goods. That is, citizens have perceptions about the extent to which authorities get things done, whether or not the voter agrees with the things that get done (Adserà et al., Reference Adserà, Boix and Payne2003; Christmann, Reference Christmann2018; Dahlberg and Holmberg, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2014; Magalhães, Reference Magalhães2014; Quaranta and Martini, Reference Quaranta and Martini2017).

  8. 8. Accountability. Citizens believe the system is arranged such that citizens can express their displeasure with government performance so that parties and persons are removed from positions of authority when their performance is wanting (Aarts and Thomassen, Reference Aarts and Thomassen2008; Powell, Reference Powell2000; Przeworski et al., Reference Przeworski, Stokes and Manin1999).

  9. 9. Responsiveness. Citizens believe that politicians respond to changes in citizens’ preferences with good judgment and then suitable legislative and executive action (Armingeon and Guthmann, Reference Armingeon and Guthmann2014; Soroka and Wlezien, Reference Soroka and Wlezien2010; Torcal, Reference Torcal2014; Wlezien and Soroka, Reference Wlezien and Soroka2012).

  10. 10. Transparency. Citizens believe that it is possible to observe the actions of governments and other authorities and that their actions are justified by public reasons (Baume and Papadopoulos, Reference Baume and Papadopoulos2018; Bentham, Reference Bentham and Schofield1990; Hollyer et al., Reference Hollyer, Rosendorf and Vreeland2019). Voters are likely to see a lack of transparency as a shield for corruption, which will diminish satisfaction (Anderson and Tverdova, Reference Anderson and Tverdova2003).Footnote 5

These are concepts, of course, and even the most complete surveys do not have ideal measurement of all of them. Nonetheless, we aim to build an estimation model of satisfaction where these are the only systematic individual-level (attitudinal-experiential-behavioural) causes of feelings of democratic satisfaction. To take one institutional factor, for example: that a proportional electoral system makes each citizen less likely to think their vote is wasted and more likely to feel well represented, not that a proportional system has an effect over and above attitudes about wasted votes and whether the person is represented. We think that this macro-to-micro causal structure is, in fact, what all scholars have in mind when they include macro factors in models of SWD. Doing so more explicitly and using an appropriate statistical representation of that empirical model enables the opening of the black box of the relationship between institutions and SWD.

Model Validation

In order to validate this ten-determinants individual-level model, we estimate an empirical version of it with a simple individual-level regression of SWD on measures of these factors. Later on, we integrate this individual-level model with a macro-model, but for now the idea is simply to show that these are all important determinants of SWD. The data are from round six of the European Social Survey, 2012 (ESS), chosen because it was focused on perceptions of the institutional elements of democratic systems and therefore is the cross-national survey dataset that has the most complete set of our ten individual-level factors.Footnote 6

Table 1 gives the correspondence between the theoretical variables above and the best available measures in the ESS data.

Table 1. Theoretical Variables and Operationalizations

In the online appendix (Table A2), we present correlations to show that these variables measure distinct attitudes. An ordinary least squares (OLS) regression predicting SWD is reported in Table 2. It is estimated using ESS respondents with complete data on all of these 10 measures from the following 23 countries: Belgium, Switzerland, Czech Republic, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Estonia, Finland, France, Hungary, Ireland, Iceland, Israel, Italy, Lithuania, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Sweden, United Kingdom. We excluded Albania, Cyprus, Bulgaria, Kosovo, Russian Federation, and Ukraine because their elections were not sufficiently free or fair to be considered as mature democracies to which our theory applies, and we had concerns with the interpretation of some of the survey questions in these countries.

Table 2. Determinants of SWD (OLS regression)

Note: ESS data 2010–2012. N = 27,819. Standard errors adjusted for country clusters. SWD mean = 0.55; sd = 0.25 (all variables rescaled to 0-to-1). Bold coefficients are more than 1.95 times their standard errors.

Table 2 shows that these are ten important and separable determinants of satisfaction with democracy. System outputs (income, health and education) and fairness, transparency and responsiveness appear to be the stronger influences. We note that the only variable that has no effect is the very poor measure of voice, which asks whether the respondent feels closer to a political party. We expect that a better measure, such as the common question asking if a respondent has a “say in government” (not asked in ESS 2012), would be significantly linked to SWD.

Readers will note that this model contains no so-called control variables, particularly socio-demographics. Socio-demographics are potentially influential at a higher level of causality. Omitting them does not threaten our inferences at either the 2-1 or 1-1 levels, because they are orthogonal to the contextual factors and prior to the individual-level factors that we argue are driving SWD. A bicameral system, for example, cannot affect individuals’ socio-demographic characteristics.

To confirm that the theoretical model of ten major determinants of SWD (at the conceptual level) applies quite generally, we show in online appendix Table A3 an analogous regression estimation on German and Canadian election studies data (not the ESS data). The models include some similar and some different operationalizations, but they are all directed at measuring the theoretically specified categories elaborated above. The results align closely with those in Table 2, showing that these are indeed generally applicable determinants of SWD.

Macro Context and Institutional Influences on the ten Considerations

Then which institutions and contextual factors affect these considerations? Careful theorizing is necessary to justify a statistical model that embodies claims about the causal influence of the many possible institutional and contextual factors on these ten attitudinal-behavioural considerations, especially in this low-degrees-of-freedom situation. Of course, each macro determinant may affect only one or some of the individual-level determinants of SWD. Obviously, the list of institutional and contextual factors is virtually endless, and scholars have covered much ground, so we aim only to paint a panoramic picture of the possibilities. We enumerate what seem to us the most important macro-level influences, grouping them into three broad categories, and list under each one the variables that we ultimately include in the estimation models. We also point out which individual-level determinants the macro factors are likely to affect which of the ten individual-level determinants. For simplicity, we suggest here only the linkages that we included in our final models, limited of course by data availability. Variables that appear in our estimation models are in bold in the text below, and the individual-level variables they affect are in italics.

Political institutions

The character of institutions likely shapes several of the characteristics that citizens value in their democracy, which in turn affect their attitudes about aspects of their democratic experience (Anderson and Guillory, Reference Anderson and Guillory1997; Berggren et al., Reference Berggren, Fugate, Preuhs and Still2004). Majoritarian institutions prioritize effective government with clear lines of accountability, while consensus-oriented ones promote more inclusive decision making and representation of minorities (Dahl, Reference Dahl1956; Lijphart, Reference Lijphart1999; Powell, Reference Powell2000; and in the SWD literature, Christmann and Torcal, Reference Christmann and Torcal2018). Like many scholars, we go deeper than just consensus-versus-majoritarian and examine more nuanced, second-order elements of the political context that are produced by different institutional configurations.

Electoral rules have wide-ranging effects on who gets and feels represented (Taagepera and Shugart, Reference Taagepera and Shugart1989; Carey and Hix, Reference Carey and Hix2011). Average district magnitude (1) affects citizens’ considerations in two principal ways. First, when there is a local representative to parliament, this may make citizens interested in politics, or it may reduce their interest if many feel their votes are wasted. Second, because district magnitude determines the threshold of votes necessary to gain representation in parliament, it affects voters’ perception of accountability—whether governing parties can and do get punished in elections. This is a perfect example of our model being able to detect cross-cutting effects, as opposed to models like the one in Christmann and Torcal (Reference Christmann and Torcal2018), where the effects are not separable: “We should not be able to detect any substantial relationships between the type of the electoral system or the average district magnitude with SWD, since PR-systems and higher district magnitude are related not only to higher levels of electoral proportionality but also to a more fractionalized party/government system” (608). In addition to district magnitude, the size of the assembly (2), as well as the ratio of the voting age population to the number of parliamentary members (3) (MPs), may convey to citizens a sense of how well they are represented in the political process (Farrell and McAllister, Reference Farrell and McAllister2006).

Although they are shaped by electoral rules, party systems are relatively stable, independent entities and can be considered institutions of a sort. One distinguishing feature of party systems is the typical number of campaigning parties (4) (Sartori, Reference Sartori1976). A key function of political parties is to aggregate and voice concerns of the population, and a higher number of parties usually means more diversity in the types of issues that are voiced and enter the political discourse (Merkley et al., Reference Merkley, Cutler, Quirk and Nyblade2019; Hoerner and Hobolt, Reference Hoerner and Hobolt2020). Thus, the number of parties is likely to directly affect how much interest citizens have and whether they feel represented by a party (however, Dassonneville and McAllister [Reference Dassonneville and McAllister2020] find that the number of parties has a negative effect on SWD).

Constitutional arrangements, such as federalism (5) or a separation-of-powers system, shape citizens’ experience with democracy in their countries—in particular, how political decisions are reached (more voice in federal systems), whose interests are considered in the process (ideal policy, responsiveness), how policy is ultimately implemented (government effectiveness) and how clear responsibility is for policy outcomes (accountability and transparency may be weaker in federations, as per Tsebelis [Reference Tsebelis2002]; Cutler [Reference Cutler2004]).

The current political context

A number of more fluid characteristics of the political context are likely to influence citizens’ considerations. Some are shaped by institutions. Most fluctuate within countries even as institutions are unchanged. We treat them as exogenous factors in our models because what matters most in our theoretical-empirical model is that they have direct effects on the individual-level considerations and, ultimately, might be changed by changes in institutional configurations.

The number of parties represented in the legislature (6) is likely to affect how well citizens feel represented and heard (voice) in the political process (Andeweg and Farrell, Reference Andeweg, Farrell, Ham, Thomassen, Aarts and Andeweg2017)—in other words, whether they have a party that represents them (Dassonneville and McAllister, Reference Dassonneville and McAllister2020).

The number of parties in government (7) is related to the share of voters who feel like winners in an election and are thus represented in a direct sense (Nadeau et al. [Reference Nadeau, Daoust and Dassonneville2021] review this huge literature). Yet the more parties in a government, the harder it may be to hold the government accountable. Moreover, a larger number of parties may dampen responsiveness (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Perotti, Tavares, Obstfels and Eichengreen1998; Powell, Reference Powell2000). One special case is a single-party majority government (8), which does not rely on consensus from coalition partners or parliament to pass legislation. We expect single-party majority governments to have direct effects on citizens’ interest in politics (negative), as well as their perception of accountability (positive), transparency (negative) and responsiveness (negative) (Lundell, Reference Lundell2011).

Seeing that governments change regularly in elections (9) (Curini et al., Reference Curini, Jou and Memoli2012; McAllister, Reference McAllister2005) indicates that governments are held accountable for their actions and could increase citizens’ interest in politics and encourage them to develop closer ties to political parties (voice).

In addition to processes, the manner of democratic governance affects how citizens evaluate important aspects of their lives (Dahlberg and Holmberg, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2012, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2014; Linde and Dahlberg, Reference Linde, Dahlberg, Bågenholm, Bauhr, Grimes and Rothstein2021). If governments operate effectively (10) and efficiently (11), voters are likely to think that the government is responsive to the people and they may be more confident about their well-being. Naturally, objective indicators of transparency, corruption and the rule of law (12) should affect citizens’ perceptions of government transparency (Anderson and Tverdova, Reference Anderson and Tverdova2003; Pellegata and Memoli, Reference Pellegata and Memoli2018).

The current social and economic context

The current economic context shapes citizens’ everyday life and their experience with democracy (Farrell and McAllister, Reference Farrell and McAllister2006; Henderson, Reference Henderson2008). Some scholars consider these to be measures of government “output,” but we believe they should be considered measures of context over which governments have only some control.

A country's absolute wealth (13), levels of economic growth (14), social expenditures (15), economic inequality (16) and social inequality (for example, gender inequality [17]) are all likely to influence citizens’ judgments of government effectiveness and efficiency (Christmann, Reference Christmann2018). The level of economic inequality (18) is likely to have a direct effect on perceptions of procedural fairness (Donovan and Karp, Reference Donovan and Karp2017; Magalhães, Reference Magalhães2016).

A Micro-Macro Empirical Model of SWD

Our theoretical model implies that we should construct an empirical model and use an estimation procedure that allows macro-level factors to influence country-level averages of individual-level attitudes and behaviours. These individual determinants then combine additively and probabilistically to determine responses to the SWD survey question.

We employ the framework of multilevel generalized structural equation modelling, or MSEM (Preacher et al., Reference Preacher, Zyphur and Zhang2010). Intuitively, this simply involves two layers of regression equations, where the level 1 (individual) equation is a regression of SWD on its influences:

SWD = f(engagement, representation, voice, ideal policy, well-being, fairness, efficiency/effectiveness, accountability, responsiveness, transparency).

The level 2 equations are, in effect, ten separate regressions of the country averages of these citizen attitudes/behaviours on the country-level factors that theory suggests will influence them. Each regression has an n of 23 (countries). For example:

Beliefs about Accountability = f(electoral system, government alternation, federalism)

It should be noted that this approach is more similar to “two-step” multilevel methods (Jusko and Shively, Reference Jusko and Phillips Shively2005) than to most of the multilevel modelling on multi-country survey datasets. Crucially, the degrees of freedom are low and estimates likely not very robust, as Bryan and Jenkins (Reference Bryan and Jenkins2016) carefully demonstrate.

One issue is the causal structure at the higher, macro level. Electoral systems are causal influences on party systems, for example, but we think both are potential determinants of some of the individual-level factors. To simplify, we separated hard, constitutional-institutional factors, which change only rarely or glacially, from contingent political, social and economic factors whose average levels may be affected by institutions but which also show a great deal of variation even when institutions are stable. The electoral system falls in the first category and the number of electoral parties in the second. In general, we included measurements from the second category because they show more variation and because the links between institutions and these more contingent factors are the subject of voluminous research by other scholars. We suggest that even more detailed theoretical work should accompany subsequent efforts to model the influences of these factors on SWD.

Our quantitative analysis began with models with a greater number of independent variables than those described above, but it became clear that only a few macro factors had significant effects on country levels of the various individual determinants. With only 23 countries, models of this kind cannot include extraneous variables. We do not have space to narrate our process of elimination, but it was informed by a review of the literature on each factor separately. In the results below, then, we present country-level models that include significant macro influences as well as ones for which there was very strong theoretical justification to expect an effect.

As a preliminary, Figure 1 gives the country means on satisfaction with democracy for the countries in our main dataset (ESS 2010–2012). It shows that the range in which macro factors can have their impact in the countries in the estimation sample is .38: from .36 (Slovenia) to .74 (Switzerland).

Figure 1. Satisfaction with democracy by country, 11-point scale 0–1

Source: European Social Survey

Macro-Level Estimates

The presentation of our results here is atypical, but we could not think of a more economical way to present ten estimations, with different combinations independent variables, and still allow the reader to read the text alongside the results, avoiding ten separate tables. The unusual thing to note is that standard errors appear as superscripts above the coefficient.

(Measurement details are in the online appendix. For these country-level averages of individual-level survey questions, the concept appears underlined to begin the subsection, with the operationalized individual-level variable in italics and the range of national averages in parentheses. Coefficients are presented in line, with standard errors as superscripts. Note that all of the dependent variables here are scaled zero to one.)

Political Engagement (Interest, .29 [Lithuania] to .64 [Denmark]) = .49 -.12(.037) Majority Government -.07(.021) Government Alternation  + .01(.011) Effective Number of Parties (ENP) votes + .001(.0003) district magnitude (DM) + .001(.0004) Population per MP. Root mean squared error (rmse) =.33

A country's level of political interest is affected negatively by both the presence of a single-party majority government and by low district magnitude. Surprisingly, interest is higher where governments have not been recently changed by elections, measured as the number of alternations over the last three elections. Interest is higher in countries with a higher number of citizens per member of parliament.Footnote 7

Policy Representation (Voted for a Party in Government, .16 [Portugal] to .47 [Finland]) = .26  +.16(.061) Parties in Government. rmse=.47

The proportion of citizens who are winners varies, sensibly and strongly, with the number of parties in government. As the parties in government measure ranges from under .07 in the United Kingdom, Spain and Portugal to over .65 for Slovakia, Czech Republic, Israel and Belgium, the effect reaches a maximum of about .13. More encompassing government coalitions allow more voters to feel like winners. No other variables affect the proportion of winners.

Voice Representation (Closer to a Political Party, .27 [Poland] to .71 [Denmark]) = .35 -.03(.057) ENP votes +.11(.004) ENP seats -.004(.003) ENPseats*ENPvotes − .05(.026) Government Alternation. rmse=.49

The proportion of citizens who feel closer to one of the political parties increases with the effective number of campaigning parties. It declines as governments are changed more regularly in national elections. Unfortunately, the measure of voice representation is the weakest of the 10 determinants; we expect a better measure might be linked to more macro factors.

Well-Being (Feeling about Household Income , .42 [Hungary] to .87 [Denmark]) = .32 -.76(.401) Economic Growth -.01(.003) Social Expenditure  +.005(.0009)GDP per capita$‘000 -.002(.004) GINI. rmse=.13

Not surprisingly, subjective economic well-being is related to the national economy, static and dynamic, as well as to social expenditure, but not to inequality.

Fairness (Courts Treat Everyone the Same, .30 [Portugal, Slovakia] to .91 [Denmark, Norway]) = .10  +.09(.01) Corruption -.01(.004) GINI +.50(.300) Gender Equality. rmse=.27

Feelings about procedural and legal fairness are related predictably to the presence of corruption and also to social (gender) inequality. Economic inequality is also linked to more negative perceptions of fairness.

Accountability (Are Governments Punished in Country , .31 [Italy] to .77 [Denmark]) = .69  +.00(.000) DM -.04(.029) Gov't Alternation -.02(.001) Gov't Non-electoral Change -.02(.041) Federal., rmse=.29

Macro factors are only weakly related to feelings about whether governments are punished for doing a bad job. We detect an effect in a counterintuitive direction, where countries that experience more government turnover have citizens who are less likely to agree that governments are punished for doing a bad job.

Responsiveness (Governments Change Policy in Response to People, .30 [Spain] to .65 [Switzerland]) = .49 -.03(.021) Majority Government -.06(.013) Gov't't Alternation  +.17(.049)Parties in Gov't -.01(.025) Federal. rmse=.24

Government alternation is strongly related to perceptions of responsiveness, but negatively, such that more frequent changes are linked to perceptions that government does not change policy. While perhaps this is counterintuitive, it is quite possible that citizens change governments frequently when they think governments do not respond to public opinion. We note that, so far, government turnover is associated with the negative side of four individual-level determinants (engagement, voice, accountability, responsiveness). The number of parties in government (measured 0 to 1) is positively linked to perceptions of responsiveness across countries (Dassonneville and McAllister, Reference Dassonneville and McAllister2020). Federalism and majority government make no difference to feelings about government responsiveness.

Transparency (Governments Explain Decisions, .33 [Spain, Italy] to .69 [Switzerland]) = .25 -.03(.046) Majority Gov't -.06(.025) Gov't Alternation  +.005(.002) Transparency -.02(.042) Federal. rmse=.26

Countries with more frequent government alternation have citizens less likely to feel that their government explains its decisions. As we would expect, one-party majorities are perceived as explaining their decisions less fully. Countries rated high on overall transparency by experts have citizens that share that view. Again, federal countries are no different.

Effectiveness (State of Health and Education , .42 [Portugal] to .74 [Denmark, Finland]) = .52 -.007(.004) GINI +.003(.001) GDPper capita $‘000  +.005(.004) Social Expenditure. rmse=.19

Judgments of effective government provision of services are linked, negatively, to inequality, positively to the country's wealth, and weakly positively to the amount of social spending.

Policy Proximity (Average absolute distance from country L-R mean , .12 [Ireland] to .23 [Israel]) = .19  +.05(.028) Parties in Gov't -.001(.003) ENPvotes -.04(.011) Federal -.001(.0004) Transparency -.0003(.0001) Population per MP. rmse=.14

Greater citizen polarization, surprisingly, is influenced by having more parties in government but not with more parties getting votes. Federal countries and more transparent ones turn out to have citizens more tightly clustered around the centre. And the more people per legislator, the closer the average citizen is to the country's mean citizen policy position.

Table 3 presents a summary of these findings. The results show how our empirical model permits the same macro factors to have separate, even opposite, effects on SWD through different intervening individual factors. We note, for example, that the number of parties in government has a positive effect on mean feelings about representation and responsiveness but a negative effect on citizens’ average closeness to the ideological centre of the country (polarization). Since feelings of representation and responsiveness increase SWD but polarization decreases it, the total effect of the number of parties in government on SWD is in the combination of these mediating effects. And this, of course, accords with previous research and theory about multi-party proportional systems versus two- (or two-plus) party systems.

Table 3. Summary of Macro Effects on Country Averages of Individual Determinants of SWD

A Multilevel Structural Equation Mediation Model for SWD

We now put the two halves of the model together. The macro part and the individual-level part of the model are estimated concurrently using the ten individual-level determinants and then separate equations for the macro-micro relationships from the previous section (Preacher et al., Reference Preacher, Zyphur and Zhang2010). Estimates are from a multilevel structural equation model with free country-level variance. The MSEM is computation-intensive but is now conveniently estimated natively in Stata and also in R using the ‘lavaan' library.

We provide results in the online appendix (Table A4). The model performs well. The country-level variance of this model conditional on the macro factors influencing SWD through the individual-level attitudes is a scant .0011, which is one-tenth the country-level variance of a constant-only model, and the p-value from the likelihood ratio test for the necessity of the multilevel structure is an insignificant .18, up from .0007 in the constant-only model. We conclude that specification of the structural model obviates the multilevel model, in effect trading the multilevel model's description of variance across levels for the more satisfying substantive account of country-level variation as influenced by theoretically specified determinants.

Readers may hope for a comparison of this MSEM with the typical random-effects multilevel model that includes macro and individual factors together. This is not possible because we have 17 candidate macro factors and only 23 countries. We entered all 17 in a standard random-effects model, and the estimates were all over the place, with very high t-statistics and unreasonably large coefficient values. When we enter those same 17 macro variables one by one, as the only macro factor on top of our ten individual-level determinants, 16 are statistically insignificant; only economic growth shows a positive relationship with SWD. That further corroborates our claim that the ten individual-level determinants are exhaustive and sit between macro factors and SWD.

Table A4, presented in the online appendix, is hardly worth a look, as the macro-level regressions are essentially identical to those presented above in the body of the article. And the individual-level model coefficients are nearly identical too.Footnote 8 This result reflects our theoretical model of a two-step path of influence.Footnote 9 Instead, we present in Table 4 the calculations of the total indirect effects of the macro variables on SWD through the individual-level determinants. For ease of interpretation, we also give the estimate (in bold) of their maximum effect—that is, from the minimum to the maximum of the macro/institutional variable. This is the most movement in SWD we can expect from the “worst” to the “best” country on a given macro variable.Footnote 10 The table shows the most powerful macro influences at the top, descending to the non-influential factors—that is, ranked by absolute value.

Table 4. Maximum Total Indirect Macro Effects

Note: Calculated from Stata SEM procedure's post-estimation total effects; country range of SWD is .38 (.36 to .74); estimates are from a non-multilevel model—see note 10.

The biggest influences on citizens’ judgments of their democracy are not political institutions, just as most recent SWD studies have shown. Even contingent political factors (number of parties, single-party government) are not terribly powerful. The top of the list is populated by socio-economic contextual factors (see also Dahlberg and Holmberg, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2014), topped by wealth and clean government (see also Quaranta and Martini, Reference Quaranta and Martini2016; Dassonneville and McAllister, Reference Dassonneville and McAllister2020; Nadeau et al., Reference Nadeau, Daoust and Arel-Bundock2020). For the countries in the data furthest apart on these measures, we expect a difference in satisfaction of nearly one-quarter of the range of satisfaction across countries. If we add the effect of economic inequality (GINI) and of government social expenditure, these four macro factors account for two-thirds of the difference in satisfaction with democracy between, say, Sweden and Lithuania (across only 300 km of the Baltic Sea!). Of course, these factors don't necessarily travel together, as we find Hungary or the Czech Republic relatively low on wealth and transparency but not among the countries high in income inequality. Notable also, as we saw above, is that the influence of these economic and output measures comes, sensibly, mostly through citizens’ feelings about their well-being and the quality of health and education.

The first contingent political factor to appear is the measure of government change through elections—government alternation. It has perhaps a counterintuitive total effect whereby countries that have changed governments in all of the last three elections are less satisfied with democracy than countries that have had less alternation. The obvious explanation is, in fact, that the causal arrow goes the other way, and government alternation is a result of feelings of dissatisfaction, as Ezrow and Xezonakis’ (Reference Ezrow and Xezonakis2016) findings strongly suggest. We note that the implied endogeneity mandates further model development in future research.

The political results of institutional differences have smaller effects but usually in the expected direction. The number of parties in government has a net positive effect on SWD and is even stronger given that the majority government variable is a special case of the number of parties in government, so the combined effect is that more parties in government lead to more satisfied citizens. Even this, the most important political factor, is in truth not hugely influential given its relatively small variation; this is partly because we saw that it has a positive effect through responsiveness and representation but a negative effect through ideological distance from the centre, illustrating the trade-offs inherent in many institutional alternatives.

Discussion and Conclusion

The theoretical and empirical aims of this article are ambitious, so the results are provisional. We sought to characterize the satisfaction with democracy question as the best indicator of citizens’ judgments of the quality of their democracies. The argument is strengthened by the strong and clear influence of distinct, theoretically-justified democratic criteria on citizens’ judgments (SWD). This gives us some confidence that macro factors—institutions and contextual features of countries—will influence judgments of the quality of democracy exclusively through these ten criteria, but of course scholars can propose other factors to be used in a model such as ours.

For the most part, the influence of contextual and institutional factors on these mediating attitudes is predictable. But degrees of freedom are low, which is simply a function of the limited number of countries—probably less than 50—that should be considered within the scope of the theory invoked in this article. A large number of macro-level factors might be relevant and measurable, and they will always overlap to a great extent. Nor is time-series much of solution, as much of this macro data changes too slowly (Ezrow and Xezonakis, Reference Ezrow and Xezonakis2016; Quaranta and Martini, Reference Quaranta and Martini2016). The degrees-of-freedom problem mandates three things: the first is to create strong and careful theory; the second is to develop empirical modelling that is meticulous and demonstrates robustness (we have not had the space to do so in this article); the third is to interpret results with caution.

Nevertheless, we hope to have steered scholarship on macro-level influences on democratic quality in the direction of greater care to include all relevant individual- and macro-level variables. The cost of not doing so is, at best, missing some of the story of how institutions affect democratic satisfaction, and is, at worst, leaving us unconvinced about the influence of a given macro factor because others with which it might be correlated are omitted from the model or not channelled through the multiple individual-level factors it might affect (possibly in opposite directions). We have also championed the MSEM framework, applicable to many questions where institutions and context can affect the determinants of a summary attitude.

Our most important provisional substantive finding confirms recent work showing that institutions do not have a powerful contemporaneous effect on the quality of democracy in this set of mostly mature democracies (see also Dahlberg and Holmberg, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2012, Reference Dahlberg and Holmberg2014; Linde and Dahlberg, Reference Linde, Dahlberg, Bågenholm, Bauhr, Grimes and Rothstein2021). Instead, the outputs of government, fairness and the economic context drive most of the variation in SWD.Footnote 11 Of course, institutions may have a longer-term effect on establishing conditions for some of the salutary policy outputs that citizens seem to respond to.

Perhaps the relative unimportance of institutions, context, and outputs is a function of something that scholars of public opinion and elections already know about citizens: few pay enough attention to politics to be affected by how many parties are in parliament and government, how many people are represented by their MP, and whether they have multiple levels of government to deal with. We know that they are far more aware of their own income, how it compares to others around them, how much the government provides in core social services, whether they can expect corruption in relationships with authorities and whether the government is transparent. Our more explicit, comprehensive macro-micro model of the determinants of SWD indicates that citizens judge democracy mostly through their lived experience rather than through the machinery of representation and policy making.

Supplementary Material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S0008423922000853

Acknowledgments

This research was supported by funding from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada's Major Collaborative Research Initiatives program as part of the Making Electoral Democracy Work (MEDW) project. The authors thank André Blais for leadership of that project, MEDW research team members, participants at seminars at the political science departments of the University of British Columbia and the University of Calgary, and participants at the European Consortium for Political Research annual meeting, 2013. We thank Vaishnavi Panchanadam for excellent research assistance.

Footnotes

1 Conceptual concerns are separate from the measurement properties of the SWD indicator. For the latter, see Poses and Revilla (Reference Poses and Revilla2022).

2 Ours is not the first multilevel structural equation model for SWD. Papp (Reference Papp2022) uses an MSEM, but the model is 2-2-1 rather than our 2-1-1. That is, Papp's mediation is at the country level, where electoral institutions affect the average legislator's constituency orientation and the proportionality of election results in the country, which then go on to affect SWD.

3 The question very clearly asks about processes of democracy, using the word works rather than outputs, though it likely evokes considerations of both processes and outputs for most citizens. For the most fully developed individual-level model focusing on democratic outputs and individual characteristics, see Kölln and Aarts (Reference Kölln and Aarts2021).

4 This is different than a sociotropic economic effect on voting behaviour. It may be rational to consider the country's economic fortunes separate from one's own when deciding whether to support the government. But when answering a “how democracy works” question, one's own well-being should be paramount. However, see point 6 (on fairness) for how altruistic considerations can affect SWD.

5 We do not include corruption in our factors, as most of the countries in the scope of our theory have relatively little corruption and attitudes to it overlap with transparency.

6 The ESS round 6 (2012) is the dataset most often used in comparative SWD research. The Comparative Study of Electoral Systems (CSES) data is a close second but did not have a complete enough set of our independent variables to be used here.

7 Political interest is especially difficult to compare across countries; this is because of linguistic differences in the understanding of the question and the fact that citizens probably report their interest relative to what they see around them in their country.

8 This is with the exception of the substitution of left/right absolute distance from the country mean for the quadratic form used above. The quadratic form is better, but the higher level of the model, predicting ideological spread from macro factors, cannot be estimated in that form.

9 For completeness, we estimated a structural equation mediation model that allowed so-called direct effects of the macro variables. They were generally only marginally significant. If our theoretical model of a two-step process were correct and measurement were perfect, we would expect no direct influence whatsoever from these variables. Seeing these relatively weak results on the macro variables lends some support to our theory.

10 These estimates are taken from a re-estimation without the multilevel structure, because then we can take advantage of Stata's built-in calculations of total effects.

11 Even Daoust et al. (Reference Nadeau, Daoust and Arel-Bundock2021), who find that political factors matter more as gross domestic product (GDP) goes up, show no clear evidence that political efficacy matters more than economic purchasing power for any set of countries.

References

Aarts, Kees and Thomassen, Jacques. 2008. “Satisfaction with Democracy: Do Institutions Matter?Electoral Studies 27 (1): 518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adserà, Alícia, Boix, Carles and Payne, Mark. 2003. “Are You Being Served? Political Accountability and Quality of Government.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 19 (2): 445–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, Perotti, Roberto, Tavares, José, Obstfels, Maurice and Eichengreen, Barry. 1998. “The Political Economy of Fiscal Adjustments.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1998 (1): 197266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Christopher J. 2010. “Electoral Supply, Median Voters, and Feelings Of Representation in Democracies.” In Citizens, Context, and Choice: How Context Shapes Citizens' Electoral Choices, ed. J, Russell. Dalton and Christopher J. Anderson. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Anderson, Christopher J. 2019. “How Electoral Systems Shape What Voters Think about Democracy.” In Duty and Choice: The Evolution of the Study of Voting and Voters, ed. Loewen, Peter John and Rubenson, Daniel. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Anderson, Christopher J., Blais, André, Bowler, Shaun, Donovan, Todd and Listhaug, Ola. 2005. Loser's Consent: Elections and Democratic Legitimacy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Christopher J. and Guillory, Christine. 1997. “Political Institutions and Satisfaction with Democracy: A Cross-National Analysis of Consensus and Majoritarian Systems.” American Political Science Review 91 (1): 6681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Christopher J. and Tverdova, Yuliya V.. 2003. “Corruption, Political Allegiances, and Attitudes Toward Government in Contemporary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (1): 91109. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/ajps.2003.47.issue-1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andeweg, Rudy and Farrell, David. 2017. “Legitimacy Decline and Party Decline.” In Myth and Reality of the Legitimacy Crisis: Explaining Trends and Cross-National Differences in Established Democracies, ed. Ham, Caroline van, Thomassen, Jacques, Aarts, Kees and Andeweg, Rudy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
André, Audrey and Depauw, Sam. 2017. “The Quality of Representation and Satisfaction with Democracy: The Consequences of Citizen-Elite Policy and Process Congruence.” Political Behavior 39 (2): 377–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armingeon, Klaus and Guthmann, Kai. 2014. “Democracy in Crisis? The Declining Support for National Democracy in European Countries, 2007–2011.” European Journal of Political Research 53 (3): 423–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baume, Sandrine and Papadopoulos, Yannis. 2018. “Transparency: From Bentham's Inventory of Virtuous Effects to Contemporary Evidence-Based Scepticism.” Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy 21 (2): 169–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy. 1990. Securities against Misrule and Other Constitutional Writings for Tripoli and Greece, ed. Schofield, Patrick. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Berggren, Heidi M., Fugate, Gregory A., Preuhs, Robert R. and Still, Dennis R.. 2004. “Satisfied? Institutional Determinants of Citizen Evaluations of Democracy.” Politics and Policy 32 (1): 7297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernauer, Julian and Vatter, Adrian. 2012. “Can't Get No Satisfaction with the Westminster Model? Winners, Losers and the Effect of Consensual and Direct Democratic Institutions on Satisfaction with Democracy.” European Journal of Political Research 51 (4): 435–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, André and Gélineau, François. 2007. “Winning, Losing and Satisfaction with Democracy.” Political Studies 55 (2): 425–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, André, Morin-Chassé, Alexandre and Singh, Shane P.. 2017. “Election Outcomes, Legislative Representation, and Satisfaction with Democracy.” Party Politics 23 (2): 8595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bryan, Mark L. and Jenkins, Stephen P.. 2016. “Multilevel Modelling of Country Effects: A Cautionary Tale.” European Sociological Review 32 (1): 322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canache, Damarys, Mondak, Jeffrey J. and Seligson, Mitchell A.. 2001. “Meaning and Measurement in Cross-National Research on Satisfaction with Democracy.” Public Opinion Quarterly 65 (4): 506–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, John M. and Hix, Simon. 2011. “The Electoral Sweet Spot: Low-Magnitude Proportional Electoral Systems.” American Journal of Political Science 55 (2): 383–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, Wen-Chun. 2018. “Media Use and Satisfaction with Democracy: Testing the Role of Political Interest.” Social Indicators Research 140 (3): 9991016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christmann, Pablo. 2018. “Economic Performance, Quality of Democracy and Satisfaction with Democracy.” Electoral Studies 53: 7989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christmann, Pablo and Torcal, Mariano. 2018. “The Effects of Government System Fractionalization on Satisfaction with Democracy.” Political Science Research and Methods 6 (3): 593611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Curini, Luigi, Jou, Willy and Memoli, Vincenzo. 2012. “Satisfaction with Democracy and the Winner/Loser Debate: The Role of Policy Preferences and Past Experience.” British Journal of Political Science 42 (2): 241–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cutler, Fred. 2004. “Government Responsibility and Electoral Accountability in Federations.” Publius: The Journal of Federalism 34 (2): 1938.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Robert. 1956. A Preface to Democratic Theory. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dahlberg, Stefan and Holmberg, Sören. 2012. “Understanding Satisfaction with the Way Democracy Works: Democracy versus Bureaucracy.” Working Paper Series 2012:8. The Quality of Government Institute, Department of Political Science, University of Gothenburg.Google Scholar
Dahlberg, Stefan and Holmberg, Sören. 2014. “Democracy and Bureaucracy: How Their Quality Matters for Popular Satisfaction.” West European Politics 37 (3): 515–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahlberg, Stefan and Linde, Jonas. 2016. “Losing Happily? The Mitigating Effect of Democracy and Quality of Government on the Winner–Loser Gap in Political Support.” International Journal of Public Administration 39 (9): 652–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dassonneville, Ruth and McAllister, Ian. 2020. “The Party Choice Set and Satisfaction with Democracy.” West European Politics 43 (1): 4973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devine, Daniel and Turnbull-Dugarte, Stuart J.. 2021. “Economic Interventions, Economic Perceptions and Political Support during the Eurozone Crisis.” Political Science Research and Methods. FirstView. DOI: 10.1017/psrm.2021.71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Larry and Morlino, Leonardo, eds. 2005. Assessing the Quality of Democracy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donovan, Todd and Karp, Jeffrey. 2017. “Electoral Rules, Corruption, Inequality and Evaluations of Democracy.” European Journal of Political Research 56 (3): 469486. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/ejpr.2017.56.issue-3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easton, David. 1965. A System Analysis of Political Life. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Easton, David. 1975. “A Re-assessment of the Concept of Political Support.” British Journal of Political Science 5 (4): 435–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ESS Round 6: European Social Survey Round 6 Data. 2012. Data file edition 2.1. Norwegian Social Science Data Services, Norway—Data Archive and distributor of ESS data. https://ess-search.nsd.no/en/study/7ccf7f30-fd1a-470a-9b90-4c91b0bc7438.Google Scholar
Ezrow, Lawrence and Xezonakis, Georgios. 2011. “Citizen Satisfaction With Democracy and Parties’ Policy Offerings.” Comparative Political Studies 44 (9): 11521178. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0010414011405461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ezrow, Lawrence and Xezonakis, Georgios. 2016. “Satisfaction with Democracy and Voter Turnout: A Temporal Perspective.” Party Politics 22 (1): 314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fang, Jie, Wen, Zhonglin and Hau, Kit-Tai. 2019. “Mediation Effects in 2-1-1 Multilevel Model: Evaluation of Alternative Estimation Methods.” Structural Equation Modeling: A Multidisciplinary Journal 26 (4): 591606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, David M. and McAllister, Ian. 2006. “Voter Satisfaction and Electoral Systems: Does Preferential Voting in Candidate-Centred Systems Make a Difference? European Journal of Political Research 45 (5): 723–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferland, Benjamin. 2021. “Policy Congruence and Its Impact on Satisfaction with Democracy.” Electoral Studies 69: 102204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuchs, Dieter and Roller, Edeltraud. 2018. “Conceptualizing and Measuring the Quality of Democracy: The Citizens’ Perspective.” Politics and Governance 6 (1): 2232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcia-Marques, Teresa, Prada, Marília and Mackie, Diane M.. 2016. “Familiarity Increases Subjective Positive Affect Even in Non-affective and Non-evaluative Contexts.” Motivation and Emotion 40 (4): 638–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grynaviski, Jeffrey D. and Corrigan, Bryce E.. 2006. “Specification Issues in Proximity Models of Candidate Evaluation (with Issue Importance).” Political Analysis 14 (4): 393420. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/pan/mpl003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henderson, Ailsa. 2008. “Satisfaction with Democracy: The Impact of Winning and Losing in Westminster Systems.” Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 18 (1): 326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoerner, Julian M. and Hobolt, Sarah B.. 2020. “Unity in Diversity? Polarization, Issue Diversity and Satisfaction with Democracy.” Journal of European Public Policy 27 (12): 1838–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollyer, James R., Rosendorf, B. Peter and Vreeland, James Raymond. 2019. “Transparency, Protest and Democratic Stability.” British Journal of Political Science 49 (4): 1251–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jusko, Karen Long and Phillips Shively, W.. 2005. “Applying a Two-Step Strategy to the Analysis of Cross-National Public Opinion Data.” Political Analysis 13 (4): 327–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karp, Jeffrey A. and Bowler, Shaun. 2001. “Coalition Governments and Satisfaction with Democracy: An Analysis of New Zealand's Reaction to Proportional Representation.” European Journal of Political Research 40 (1): 5779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kölln, Ann-Kristin and Aarts, Kees. 2021. “What Explains the Dynamics of Citizens’ Satisfaction with Democracy? An Integrated Framework for Panel Data.” Electoral Studies 69: 102271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1997. “Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma.” American Political Science Review 91 (1): 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Linde, Jonas and Dahlberg, Stefan. 2021. “Quality of Government and Political Support.” In The Oxford Handbook of the Quality of Government, ed. Bågenholm, Andreas, Bauhr, Monika, Grimes, Marcia and Rothstein, Bo. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Linde, Jonas and Ekman, Joakim. 2003. “Satisfaction with Democracy: A Note on a Frequently Used Indicator in Comparative Politics.” European Journal of Political Research 42 (3): 391408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lühiste, Kadri. 2014. “Social Protection and Satisfaction with Democracy: A Multi-level Analysis.” Political Studies 62 (4): 784803.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lundell, Krister. 2011. “Accountability and Patterns of Alternation in Pluralitarian, Majoritarian and Consensus Democracies.” Government and Opposition 46 (2): 145–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magalhães, Pedro C. 2014. “Government Effectiveness and Support for Democracy.” European Journal of Political Research 53 (1): 7797.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magalhães, Pedro C. 2016. “Economic Evaluations, Procedural Fairness, and Satisfaction with Democracy.” Political Research Quarterly 69 (3): 522–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magalhães, Pedro C. and Conraria, Luís Aguiar. 2018. “Procedural Fairness, the Economy, and Support for Political Authorities.” Political Psychology 40 (1): 165–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayne, Quinton and Hakhverdian, Armen. 2017. “Ideological Congruence and Citizen Satisfaction: Evidence from 25 Advanced Democracies.” Comparative Political Studies 50 (6): 822–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAllister, Ian. 2005. “Accountability, Representation and Satisfaction with Democracy.” International Journal of Public Opinion Research 17 (3): 371–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merkel, Wolfgang, Buehlmann, Marc, Müller, Lisa and Wessels, Bernard. 2013. “The Democracy Barometer: A New Instrument to Measure the Quality of Democracy and Its Potential for Comparative Research.” In Developing Democracies: Democracy, Democratization, and Development, ed. Boess, Michael, Moeller, Joergen and Skaaning, Svend-Erik. Aarhus: Aarhus University Press.Google Scholar
Merkley, Eric, Cutler, Fred, Quirk, Paul J. and Nyblade, Benjamin. 2019. “Having Their Say: Authority, Voice, and Satisfaction with Democracy.” Journal of Politics 81 (3): 848–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mutz, Diana. C. and Jeffrey J. Mondak. 1997. “Dimensions of Sociotropic Behavior: Group-Based Judgements of Fairness and Well-Being.” American Journal of Political Science 41 (1): 284308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nadeau, Richard, Daoust, Jean-François and Arel-Bundock, Vincent. 2020. “The Market, the State and Satisfaction with Democracy.” West European Politics 43 (1): 250–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nadeau, Richard, Daoust, Jean-François and Dassonneville, Ruth. 2021. “Winning, Losing, and the Quality of Democracy.” Political Studies. OnlineFirst. https://doi.org/10.1177/003232172110261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, Pippa. 2011. “The Conceptual Framework.” In Democratic Deficit: “Critical Citizens” Revisited, ed. Norris, Pippa. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papp, Zsófia. 2022. “The Indirect Effect of Electoral Rules on Citizens’ Satisfaction with Democracy: A Comparative Study.” Swiss Political Science Review 28 (1): 120. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/spsr.12497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pellegata, Alessandro and Memoli, Vincenzo. 2018. “Corruption and Satisfaction with Democracy: The Conditional Role of Electoral Disproportionality and Ballot Control.” European Political Science Review 10 (3): 393416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pickel, Susanne, Breustedt, Wiebke and Smolka, Theresia. 2016. “Measuring the Quality of Democracy: Why Include the Citizens’ Perspective?International Political Science Review 37 (5): 645–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poses, Carlos and Revilla, Melanie. 2022. “Measuring Satisfaction with Democracy: How Good Are Different Scales across Countries and Languages?European Political Science Review 14 (1): 1835.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, G. Bingham. 2000. Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian Proportional Versions. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Preacher, Kristopher J., Zyphur, Michael J. and Zhang, Zhen. 2010. “A General Multilevel SEM Framework for Assessing Multilevel Mediation.” Psychological Methods 15 (3): 209–33.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Przeworski, Adam, Stokes, Susan C. and Manin, Bernard. 1999. Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quaranta, Mario and Martini, Sergio. 2016. “Does the Economy Really Matter for Satisfaction with Democracy? Longitudinal and Cross-Country Evidence from the European Union.” Electoral Studies 42: 164–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quaranta, Mario and Martini, Sergio. 2017. “Easy Come, Easy Go? Economic Performance and Satisfaction with Democracy in Southern Europe in the Last Three Decades.” Social Indicators Research 13 (12): 659–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quintelier, Ellen and Van Deth, Jan W.. 2014. “Supporting Democracy: Political Participation and Political Attitudes. Exploring Causality Using Panel Data.” Political Studies 62: 153–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reher, Stefanie. 2015. “Explaining Cross-National Variation in the Relationship Between Priority Congruence and Satisfaction with Democracy.” European Journal of Political Research 54 (1): 160181. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12077.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, Giovanni. 1976. Parties and Party Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Scruggs, Lyle. 2001. “Is There Really a Link Between Neo-Corporatism and Environmental Performance? Updated Evidence and New Data for the 1980s and 1990s.” British Journal of Political Science 31 (4): 686–692. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0007123401220262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soroka, Stuart N. and Wlezien, Christopher. 2010. Degrees of Democracy: Politics, Public Opinion, and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stegmueller, Daniel. 2013. “How Many Countries for Multilevel Modeling? A Comparison of Frequentist and Bayesian Approaches.” American Journal of Political Science 57 (3): 748–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taagepera, Rein and Shugart, Matthew. 1989. Seats and Votes: The Effects and Determinants of Electoral Systems. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Torcal, Mariano. 2014. “The Decline of Political Trust in Spain and Portugal: Economic Performance or Political Responsiveness?American Behavioral Scientist 58 (12): 1542–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tourangeau, Roger, Rips, Lance and Rasinski, Kenneth. 2000. The Psychology of Survey Response. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Urbinati, Nadia and Warren, Mark E.. 2008. “The Concept of Representation in Contemporary Democratic Theory.” Annual Review of Political Science 11: 387412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valgarðsson, Viktor Orri and Devine, Daniel. 2022. “What Satisfaction with Democracy? A Global Analysis of ‘Satisfaction with Democracy’ Measures.” Political Research Quarterly 75 (3): 576–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warren, Mark. E. 2017. “A Problem-Based Approach to Democratic Theory.” American Political Science Review 111 (1): 3953.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wells, Jason M. and Krieckhaus, Jonathan. 2006. “Does National Context Influence Democratic Satisfaction? A Multi-Level Analysis.” Political Research Quarterly 59 (4): 569–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wlezien, Christopher and Soroka, Stuart N.. 2012. “Political Institutions and the Opinion–Policy Link.” West European Politics 35 (6): 1407–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaller, John. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Theoretical Variables and Operationalizations

Figure 1

Table 2. Determinants of SWD (OLS regression)

Figure 2

Figure 1. Satisfaction with democracy by country, 11-point scale 0–1Source: European Social Survey

Figure 3

Table 3. Summary of Macro Effects on Country Averages of Individual Determinants of SWD

Figure 4

Table 4. Maximum Total Indirect Macro Effects

Supplementary material: File

Cutler et al. supplementary material

Cutler et al. supplementary material

Download Cutler et al. supplementary material(File)
File 44.6 KB