Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T07:23:35.221Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

“The Mother of Combines”: Representations of the United States in Early Canadian Discourse on the Combines Problem and the Formation of Canadian National Identity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 March 2021

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In 1887, Canada was in a fervour over so-called “combines,” a term used to cover price-fixing schemes, pool agreements, trusts, and other cartel arrangements. The public debate led to the passage in 1889 of the Anti-Combines Act, the world’s first modern competition statute, enacted a year prior to the United States’ Sherman Antitrust Act. But while Canada acted before its neighbour to the south, the United States was omnipresent in the Canadian debates in four ways: as a benchmark against which the Canadian economy and the combines problem should be judged; as a model for potential legal action; as a potential economic liberator; and as the very source and propagator of the combines problem. Canadians thus alternately presented the United States as saviour or devil, as paragon or antithesis. The result was a paradox of a sort: Canadians borrowed American ideas in order to avoid becoming American.

Résumé

Résumé

En 1887, les soi-disant « coalitions », un terme utilisé pour désigner les systèmes de fixation des prix, les accords de mise en commun, les fiducies et les autres ententes, était un sujet de débat proéminent au Canada. Le débat public a d’ailleurs conduit à l’adoption, en 1889, de l’Acte à l’effet de prévenir et supprimer les coalitions formées pour gêner le commerce, la première loi moderne sur la concurrence au monde, promulguée un an avant a Loi Sherman (également appelé Sherman Anti-Trust) aux États-Unis. Or, bien que le Canada ait agi avant son voisin du sud, les États-Unis ont été omniprésents dans les débats canadiens sur le sujet, et ce, de quatre manières : 1) comme le point de repère par rapport auquel l’économie canadienne et le problème des coalitions devraient être jugés ; 2) comme modèle pour une action juridique potentielle; 3) en tant que libérateur économique potentiel; 4) et comme la source du problème des coalitions. Les Canadiens ont ainsi tour à tour présenté les États-Unis comme un sauveur ou un antagoniste, comme un parangon ou un miroir noir. Le résultat est en quelque sorte un paradoxe : les Canadiens ont emprunté des idées américaines pour éviter de devenir Américains.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Canadian Law and Society Association

In late 1887, Canada was swept up in a fervour over the impact and scope of so-called “combines,” a blanket term used to cover price-fixing schemes, pool agreements, trusts, and other cartel and monopoly arrangements. The public debate that ensued ultimately led to the passage in May 1889 of the world’s first modern competition statute, An Act for the Prevention and Suppression of Combinations Formed in Restraint of Trade—better known at the Anti-Combines Act or sometimes the Wallace Act after its sponsor, Nathaniel Clarke Wallace.Footnote 1 The Act came almost exactly a year prior to the United States’ more famous Sherman Antitrust Act. Footnote 2 But while in this case Canada acted before its neighbour to the south, the United States remained omnipresent in public and parliamentary discourse on the combines problem. Canadian legislators, businessmen, and journalistsFootnote 3 made constant reference to the United States, the American economy, the treatment of combines under American law, and proposed American solutions to the combines problem.Footnote 4 Though it would be a mistake to say that the Canadian discourse surrounding combines was wholly derivative of that going on south of the border, the shadow of the United States remained ever-present in the Canadian debates.

This article will explore the manner in which and extent to which the United States was present in and influenced Canadian legal discourse on the combines problem, and what this discourse reveals about Canadian national identity. While much of this discourse took place in the Canadian Parliament, this article treats Parliament and its members as legal actors engaged in a fundamentally legal act. As such, this article approaches the Anti-Combines Act from the perspective of legal, rather than political, history. Part I will outline the background to the combines debate and the events leading up to the passage of the Anti-Combines Act, including the ongoing debates about trade reciprocity with the United States. Part II will then explore the four major ways in which Canadian politicians, businessmen, and journalists referred to the United States during the combines debates: first, as a benchmark against which Canadian businesses could be judged; second, as a model for potential legal action; third, as a potential economic liberator through the power of free trade; and, fourth, as the ultimate source and propagator of the combines problem.

I. The Background and Passage of the Anti-Combines Act

In 1887, when the combines debate began in earnest, Canada was going through the latest salvo in a years-long dispute over the structure of the Canadian economy and its level of integration with the United States. The overarching question was whether to maintain the National Policy of steep tariffs or instead seek some form of free trade with the United States. While the question had been percolating since Sir John A. Macdonald’s return to power in the 1878 election, it rose to a fever pitch in 1887–1888, was briefly replaced by questions of national and sectarian identity from 1888 to 1890, and then reached its apex during the 1891 election, which Macdonald’s Conservatives won after framing the opposition Liberals as traitors intent on annexing Canada to the United States.

Because the combines problem arose in the context of the extended debate on trade policy, the two issues were from the beginning intertwined in Canadian public discourse, and both issues were likewise intermingled with questions of Canadian national identity and Canada’s place in North America. Thus, before turning to the rise of the “combines problem” within Canada and the parliamentary response culminating in the Anti-Combines Act of 1889, I will begin with a brief history of the National Policy and its alternatives.

1. The National Policy and the Unrestricted Reciprocity Debate

The National Policy was a system of high tariffs designed to promote the development of Canadian industry while simultaneously providing funding for the infrastructural investments necessary to settle Canada’s western provinces and territories.Footnote 5 Introduced in 1879, it became “the single most important political issue in the country,” into the first decade of the twentieth century.Footnote 6 According to Edward Porritt in 1917, “In the thirty-five years from 1879 to 1914, and in particular from 1879 to 1897, there was no phrase in political discussion in Canada in more frequent use than the phrase, ‘the National Policy of the Dominion.’”Footnote 7 Indeed, it was so omnipresent in Canadian political discourse that it was often referred simply as “the NP.”Footnote 8

From its introduction by Macdonald’s Conservative government, the opposition Liberals had been staunchly opposed to the NP. While Liberal critiques had little traction in the NP’s early years—whether because it was difficult to run against the patriotic-sounding “National Policy”Footnote 9 or because it initially worked to increase Canadian investment and developmentFootnote 10 —that changed in the mid-1880s as the Long Depression devastated the economy. From 1883 to 1890, over one thousand businesses failed every year, including seven banks.Footnote 11 The country also experienced significant emigration to the United States, which was, in the words of Michael Bliss, “a basic sign of national failure.”Footnote 12 The situation was perhaps worst in the West: a combination of falling land prices (a speculative bubble burst in 1883), high tariffs on both sides of the Canadian–American border, and monopoly freight rates on the new Canadian Pacific Railway defeated Canadian dreams of quickly settling the Prairies.Footnote 13

In this economic and political climate, “Macdonald should have lost the 1887 election.”Footnote 14 Macdonald and the Conservatives survived in large part because of the weakness of the Liberal Opposition under Edward Blake, who offered no alternative to the National Policy, had offended many Protestants in Ontario with his support of Louis Riel during the 1885 rebellion, and, on top of that, was a poor campaigner. When he stepped down in 1887, Blake made what might be his most lasting contribution to Canadian politics: he personally selected his successor, future Prime Minister Wilfrid Laurier.Footnote 15

Though seen by many within the party as an interim leader who would serve only until someone more suitable could be found, Laurier recognized the need for new policies to offer reasons for Canadians to vote for Liberals over the incumbent Conservatives. At the same time, Canadian expatriate millionaire Erastus Wiman began a massive campaign in both Canada and the United States for so-called “commercial union” between the two countries—in essence, a customs union with common external tariffs and limited internal trade barriers. Commercial union proved a step too far for Laurier, who recognized it could open Liberals up to claims that they were laying the grounds for annexation to the United States; instead, when the 1888 parliamentary session began, Laurier’s Liberals endorsed a scheme of “unrestricted reciprocity” (or “UR”), whereby trade barriers between Canada and the United States would be eliminated, but each state would continue to set its own external tariff.Footnote 16

“The Great Free Trade Debate” that ensued dominated the 1888 parliamentary session. Beginning on March 14, the Commons debated the issue for a full three weeks, to the point where “newspapers on both sides called for an end to the debate on the grounds of excessive boredom.”Footnote 17 In the end, the Liberals’ motion in favour of unrestricted reciprocity failed by 67 to 124,Footnote 18 but the proceedings set the stage for an extended debate that would only be resolved in the 1891 election.Footnote 19

2. The Rise of the Combines Problem

While the debates on trade policy were ongoing, the so-called “combines problem” percolated up into Canadian public consciousness, before exploding in late 1887. Combines had, to some extent, always existed in Canada. As elsewhere, local producers, distributors, and retailers had, from an early date entered into informal agreements setting the prices to be charged for products and the terms of service to be offered. More formal agreements on a broader scale came later, beginning with the short-lived Ottawa Lumber Association in 1836. In the ensuing decades, combines would appear in industry after industry, typically following declines in price caused by overproduction, increased competition from the United States, or economic depressions.Footnote 20 The Canadian Salt Association, formed among the salt producers of Goderich, Ontario, is a prime example—faced with inexpensive imports from the United States and increasing costs because of the need to replace expensive equipment, the salt manufacturers of Goderich, Ontario, agreed in 1871 to appoint a joint sales agent that would sell their salt at a uniform price.Footnote 21 Though the agreement quickly broke down, it resulted in the first—and most famous—Canadian judicial case centred on the combines question, in which Strong VC refused to enjoin the agreement as an unreasonable restraint of trade.Footnote 22

The number and scope of Canadian combines increased dramatically in the 1880s, however. Strong economic growth and the protection offered by the National Policy encouraged over-investment in industries seen as particularly profitable; the resurgence of the Long Depression in 1883 resulted in a collapse in demand and a corresponding collapse in prices. The situation was made worse by improvements in transportation and communications infrastructure; businesses that once had local monopolies found themselves undercut by competitors in distant cities that could sell via catalogue and ship via rail.Footnote 23 In some instances, the increased labour unrest also contributed to the decision to combine, in order to collectively crush upstart unions before they gained a foothold in the industry.Footnote 24 In this environment, the incentives to combine to fix prices and terms of sale were overwhelming.

Initially, Canadians showed little interest in the combines problem—to the point that papers reported on combine activity as if it were regular business newsFootnote 25 —until the issue broke into public consciousness in mid-1887 with revelations of a cartel formed by the Dominion Wholesale Grocers’ Guild to fix the wholesale price of granulated sugar. The combine scheme was composed of three related provisions: first, it established a uniform wholesale price that Guild members were to charge for sugar; second, it prohibited Guild members from themselves engaging in retail sales; and third, it pressured sugar refiners (through threat of a coordinated boycott by Guild members) to charge a premium to non-members.Footnote 26

Although initial reports on the sugar combine were brief and did little more than report the agreement as business news,Footnote 27 it quickly gained further attention for three reasons. First, the combine dealt with a commodity purchased and used by all Canadian households. Second, the means by which the combine was enforced were relatively novel, at least in Canada. While price-fixing agreements were known,Footnote 28 this was the first vertical hub-and-spoke conspiracy between manufacturers and wholesalers to gain public attention. Third, the story neatly fit the existing Liberal critique of the National Policy, as it seemed a perfect example of a domestic industry taking advantage of high tariffs to overcharge Canadians for a necessity.Footnote 29 Unsurprisingly, the sugar combine became a cause célèbre within a matter of weeks, and reports of other combines quickly followed.Footnote 30 One particularly shocking revelation—that coal merchant Elias Rogers had been instrumental in a combine to fix the price of anthracite coal in Toronto—appears to have changed the outcome of the Toronto mayoral election in January 1888, which Rogers had been expected to win. The combine was discovered and revealed by a Conservative backbencher best known for his role as Grand Master of the Orange Order of British America: Nathaniel Clarke Wallace.Footnote 31

While many things contributed to the furore over combines, three are worth mentioning. First, at a time when even the worst cartel agreements and attempts to monopolize were not criminal (though they might be unenforceable),Footnote 32 combines did little to keep their actions secret, making it quite easy for journalists to learn and report of conduct perceived as shocking.Footnote 33 Second, as the United States was also going through an extended debate on combines and trusts, journalists could readily reprint horror stories from south of the border.Footnote 34 Finally, Wallace’s discovery and revelation of the Toronto coal combine led by mayoral candidate Elias Rogers seems to have led directly to Wallace’s interest in the combines question, as well as to have shifted the political discourse around combines so that it was no longer defined wholly by the National Policy, thereby encouraging other Conservatives to engage in the debate.

3. The Common Law Restraint of Trade Doctrine in 1888–1889

Before proceeding to parliamentary consideration of the combines problem, however, it is worth briefly laying out both why the combines problem was not sufficiently addressed under the common law restraint of trade doctrine and why legislators in both Canada and the United States would nonetheless use it as the basis for legislative solutions.

Prior to the House of Lords’ judgments in Mogul Steamship v McGregor, Gow & Co (1892)Footnote 35 and Nordenfelt v Maxim Nordenfelt Guns & Ammunition (1894),Footnote 36 the restraint of trade doctrine under British (and thus Canadian) common law was still largely defined by Mitchel v. Reynolds, decided by the Queen’s Bench in 1711.Footnote 37 Under Mitchel and its progeny, courts applied a three-part test: to be valid, a restraint (1) must be particular, or partial (that is, limited to a specific geographic place), rather than “general” (without geographic limits); (2) must be reasonable; and (3) must be given for lawful consideration, even if the promise was made under seal.Footnote 38 Under Mitchel, all general restraints of trade were unenforceable, as they encouraged monopoly, but partial restraints limited to a particular place did not raise the same risk “if done fairly, and upon a good and lawful consideration, and with no [ill] intention.”Footnote 39

For partial restraints of trade, validity hinged on whether the restriction was reasonable. In Horner v Graves, Tindal, CJ, of the Court of Common Pleas laid out a standard that would be used throughout the nineteenth century and was endorsed by the Judicial Committee of the Privy Council in Collins v Locke in 1879:Footnote 40

[W]e do not see how a better test can be applied to the question whether reasonable or not, than by considering whether the restraint is such only as to afford a fair protection to the interests of the party in favour of whom it is given, and not so large as to interfere with the interests of the public. Whatever restraint is larger than the necessary protection of the party, can be no benefit to either, it can only be oppressive; and if oppressive, it is, in the eye of the law, unreasonable. Whatever is injurious to the interests of the public is void, on the grounds of public policy.Footnote 41

The default rule was that contracts in partial restraint of trade were presumed unreasonable until proven otherwise,Footnote 42 but it was generally quite easy to prove reasonableness under the Horner standard. Indeed, by the late nineteenth century, courts and treatise writers had moved strongly in favour of findings of reasonableness.Footnote 43 Ancillary agreements would generally be sustained as reasonable, barring exceptional circumstances. Combine agreements, however, were more likely to be found unreasonable.

In an earlier article, I surveyed nineteenth-century “combines-type” restraint of trade cases decided by courts in Canada, England, and Wales, or by the Judicial Committee of the Privy Council, finding thirteen such cases—four arising out of Canada, eight out of England and Wales, and one out of an appeal from the colony of Victoria to the Judicial Committee of the Privy Council.Footnote 44 Of these cases, five (38%) were found to be unreasonable or partially unreasonable restraints of trade, although only one of the Canadian combines (25%) was found to be unreasonable. Of the four most recent combines cases prior to 1888, however, all but one (75%) were found unreasonable, including the Judicial Committee of the Privy Council decision in Collins v Locke Footnote 45 and Mineral Water Bottle Exchange & Trade Protection Society v Booth. Footnote 46 Based on this review of case law, I concluded that “the restraint of trade doctrine remained alive, if perhaps not vibrant, in 1889” and that “combines with severe potential impacts on commerce were invalidated with some regularity.”Footnote 47

And yet, the restraint of trade doctrine was also ill-suited to prevent the propagation of combines—at least, not without some additional teeth. Because the restraint of trade doctrine originated as a defence against the enforcement of an otherwise valid contract, it could only be raised by the parties themselves; there was no accepted means by which injured third parties could challenge combine agreements, such as through tort actions or criminal prosecutions. Indeed, nineteenth-century judges often distinguished between the questions of enforceability and criminality—that a combine agreement was unenforceable did not make entering into it criminal, nor did legislation barring indictment make an agreement enforceable.Footnote 48

Despite these deficiencies, it is unsurprising that reformers in both Canada and the United States both turned to restraint of trade doctrine when constructing legislative solutions to the combines problem. As a doctrine that already addressed these issues and offered existing standards in judging between legal and illegal, restraint of trade offered a ready-made body of law that could simply be expanded into other types of legal actions, whether they be civil or criminal.

4. The Wallace Select Committee and the Anti-Combines Act

When the 1888 parliamentary session began in February, Wallace introduced a motion to create a Select Committee to “examine into the nature, extent and effect of certain combinations said to exist with reference to the purchase and sale in Canada of any foreign or Canadian products.”Footnote 49 Over the next two months, Wallace’s Select Committee held twenty-six hearings, in which it heard evidence from sixty-three witnesses as to possible combines in sugar and groceries, anthracite coal, biscuits and confectionery, watch mechanisms and cases, barbed wire, binder twine, agricultural implements, stoves, oatmeal millers, egg, barley, fire underwriting, and coffins and undertaking, and on May 16, 1888, issued its report with over 700 pages of testimony and other evidence.Footnote 50 The report detailed the existence and scope of combines in practically all areas of investigation; only sales of barley and of agricultural implements were found to be free of combines.Footnote 51 Two days later, Wallace introduced a private member’s bill that would, after amendment, become the Anti-Combines Act. Footnote 52

Due to the lateness of the parliamentary calendar, no action was taken during the 1888 session. At the first opportunity, Wallace reintroduced the bill during the 1889 session of Parliament.Footnote 53 Although second reading of Wallace’s bill was initially scheduled for the next day (February 7, 1889), it did not occur until early April.Footnote 54 The reasons for the delay are unclear, but Wallace himself likely had some role, as at the time of second reading, he moved to replace his initial bill with an amended version.Footnote 55 The bill was then referred to the Committee on Banking and Commerce, where “large deputations” representing Canada’s business community appeared to attack the bill.Footnote 56 Wallace later accused the Liberal Opposition of trying to kill his bill in committee: “[T]hey came down before the Banking and Commerce Committee at its last meeting with a great array of lawyers from Montreal and Toronto, and with amendments carefully considered, to legislate this Bill out of existence.”Footnote 57 Unfortunately, the records of the Banking Committee hearings have not survived.

Wallace’s bill, on the other hand, did survive the committee process and, indeed, came out stronger in at least one respect: when third reading occurred on April 22, 1889, the bill had gained the full support of the Government and was shepherded through the Commons by Minister of Justice (and later Prime Minister) John Sparrow David Thompson.Footnote 58 At this point, debate centred not on whether anti-combines legislation was necessary, but on whether Wallace’s bill would do anything to combat the alleged evil.Footnote 59 In the end, however, the bill passed the Commons unanimously and was referred to the Senate, where it faced more substantial opposition from senators who believed the bill inadequately defined what conduct was prohibited, putting legitimate business behaviour at risk.Footnote 60 The Senate passed the bill only after further amendments reintroducing the terms “unduly” and “unreasonably” earlier deleted by Wallace.Footnote 61 After a short debate as to whether the Senate amendments had fatally undermined the bill, Wallace—and the Commons—accepted the revised bill as a tentative first step to resolving the combines problem.Footnote 62

As passed, Section 1 of the Act provided:

  1. 1. Every person who conspires, combines, agrees or arranges with any other person, or with any railway, steamship, steamboat or transportation company, unlawfully

    1. (a) to unduly limit the facilities for transporting, producing, manufacturing, supplying, storing or dealing in any article or commodity which may be a subject of trade and commerce; or

    2. (b) to restrain or injure trade or commerce in relation to any such article or commodity; or

    3. (c) to unduly prevent, limit, or lessen the manufacture or production of any such article or commodity, or to unreasonably enhance the price thereof; or

    4. (d) to unduly prevent or lessen competition in the production, manufacture, purchase, barter, sale, transportation or supply of any such article or commodity, or in the price of insurance upon person or property;

    is guilty of a misdemeanor and liable on conviction, to a penalty not exceeding four thousand dollars and not less than two hundred dollars, or to imprisonment for any term not exceeding two years; and if a corporation, is liable on conviction to a penalty not exceeding ten thousand dollars and not less than one thousand dollars.Footnote 63

At the time of final passage, however, Wallace reserved the right to revisit the matter in the future: “if after the experience of a year it should be proved that further amendments are necessary and that it is desirable to restore the Bill to its original shape, then that should be done.”Footnote 64 Indeed, during the 1890s, Wallace and his allies repeatedly attempted to do just that, but each effort failed upon reaching the Senate.Footnote 65 While the Anti-Combines Act ultimately proved a failure, that had far more to do with subsequent judicial decisions in the United Kingdom than with bad faith on Wallace’s part or a conspiracy by the Conservative government.Footnote 66

II. The United States in the Combines Debates of 1888-1889

Having briefly explained the background to the combines debates, I turn now to how the shadow of the United States influenced the rhetoric used by both proponents and opponents of Wallace’s bill. I will look in turn at how the United States was used (1) as a benchmark against which the Canadian economy could be judged, (2) as a model for potential legal action, (3) as an economic liberator through the power of free trade, and (4) as the ultimate source and propagator of the combines problem.

1. The United States as Benchmark

Least surprisingly, Canadian politicians, businessmen, and journalists repeatedly referenced the United States as a benchmark for the Canadian economy and for the proliferation of combines. That Canadians would look to the United States is unsurprising—it shared Canada’s only land border, a common language with Canada’s English-speaking community, Canada’s common law heritage, had a currency set at parity, and Canadians had easy access to American periodicals and catalogues. And, at a time when north–south trade across the border was much greater than east–west trade between Canadian provinces,Footnote 67 Canadian businesspeople and consumers were acutely aware of economic conditions and prices south of the border. Much more than the United Kingdom, which was across the sea, had no tariffs of significance, and used a different currency, the United States was the natural comparison for economic matters in Canada, though references to the mother country remained relatively common.Footnote 68

Most frequently, Canadians used the United States as a pricing benchmark, as there was an implicit assumption that if the Canadian price of goods was roughly equivalent to the price in the United States, then the price was “fair.” In one notable example, the Wallace Select Committee concluded that a combine in the binder twine industry did not increase consumer prices, as “prices paid in Canada are no higher than in United States and Great Britain.”Footnote 69 The Select Committee instead attributed higher prices to the increased cost of raw materials, particularly manilla, distribution of which had been monopolized by an American syndicate.Footnote 70 Similar cross-border price comparisons were made with other goods, including stoves,Footnote 71 anthracite coal,Footnote 72 and barley.Footnote 73

Divergence in prices between the United States and Canada, on the other hand, was used as evidence of combine activity. In the case of sweetened biscuits, for instance, Montreal retail grocer Walter Paul testified that “Prices here are from 25 to 50 per cent higher than in the United States,” despite the fact that “we ought to be able to produce biscuits as cheap in Canada as in any other country in the world” because of similar raw material costs.Footnote 74 This, the Select Committee concluded, was the result of a combine amongst confectioners designed to maintain prices despite falling costs.Footnote 75

Differential pricing policies in Canada and the United States were also seen as proof of a combine in the insurance industry. Throughout 1888, the Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World ran a series of articles attacking the Canadian fire insurance industry for charging double premiums to insure buildings with gasoline stoves, when many of the same insurers offered coverage in the United States at normal cost.Footnote 76 The Canadian Manufacturer repeated its critique often enough that eventually a competing journal, The Monetary Times and Trade Review published an editorial mocking its obsession.Footnote 77 Obsessed or not, the Canadian Manufacturer was on to something; in its report, the Select Committee concluded that an insurance industry combine imposed a uniform schedule of rates on its members, resulting in higher prices “in nearly every instance” and rates that did not take into account the actual risks of the enterprise.Footnote 78 As in the case of biscuits, higher prices than those across the border were evidence of the malfeasance of Canadian combines.

Of course, cross-border uniformity of prices proved little, as transnational combines could be setting a single price, separate combines could have fixed the same price, or a wholly Canadian combine could have fixed prices at the American market price. But, given the relatively unsophisticated understanding of combines and cartel activity at the time compared with contemporary competition law scholarship, this was a point largely missed by Wallace, the Select Committee, and others. In the case of binder twine mentioned above, for instance, the Select Committee failed to consider that uniform prices in Canada, the United States, and the United Kingdom were the result of combine activity in all three nations, despite extensive testimony about an American combine. Indeed, the testimony of John Connor, a New Brunswick rope manufacturer, supports the conclusion that an American combine fixed the price of binder twine within the United States (but not the price for export), while a Canadian combine, protected by the National Policy tariff, separately fixed the price at a roughly similar rate.Footnote 79 As noted above, the Select Committee, however, attributed price increases not to the Canadian combine, but to an increase in raw material costs,Footnote 80 a dubious conclusion to say the least.

Regardless of whether comparing Canadian prices with those in the United States proved anything about combine activity, however, one thing is clear: Canadian politicians, businessmen, and journalists repeatedly used American prices as a benchmark and judged the existence and effects of Canadian combines on how prices compared with those on the other side of the border.

2. The United States as a Model for Legal Action

The United States also appeared in the combines debates as a potential model for legal action and legal reform. Though Canada ultimately acted before the United States in response to the combines problem, the contemporaneous nature of the debates in both states offered Canadian politicians, businessmen, and journalists a chance to look to what steps the United States had tentatively taken or had under consideration.

First, there is evidence that Canadians looked to American case law for guidance on the limits of acceptable conduct. George Lightbound, a wholesale grocer who protested the sugar combine, testified to the Select Committee that he had been advised by his solicitor of an American case holding a combine to be an illegal conspiracy, though he was uncertain of the particulars. Based on the decision, his solicitor advised that “all the parties to this [sugar combine], including the refiners, were open to indictment for conspiracy.”Footnote 81 Lightbound did not pursue the matter, however, as “[m]ost of these gentlemen, although I differ from them in this matter, are my friends, and we do not want to bring the matter into the criminal courts if it can be avoided.”Footnote 82 Although Canadian judges and lawyers of the late nineteenth century were moving increasingly away from citations to American law,Footnote 83 it is nonetheless likely that other attorneys would likewise have referenced American jurisprudence concerning combines due to the confused state of English and Canadian precedent.Footnote 84

More immediate to the Anti-Combines Act itself, Canadians were also watching the ongoing debates in Congress and in the state legislatures about combines and trusts. Wallace himself closely followed American news on the issue, basing his initial draft of the Anti-Combines Act on a bill under consideration by the New York legislature.Footnote 85 The American legislative debates were also raised during the Select Committee’s hearings. When asked how to remedy the effect of American combines in Canada, watch distributor Charles Stark responded that Parliament could criminalize combine activity within Canada, and that the United States was then considering its own legislation on the matter. “They are making a law now in the United States and they are enforcing that in different States. The thing has got to be such an abuse and nuisance that they are taking it up, and it is only a question of time when it will be general in the States that these things will be squashed.”Footnote 86 Though Canada ultimately came to act first (beating the United States’ Sherman Antitrust Act by a year and New York’s Donnelly Act by a decade), the prospect of American legislative action gave inspiration to Wallace and other proponents of a Canadian response to the combines problem.

Wallace and his fellow Conservatives may not have been the only ones to borrow ideas from the United States, however. As the combines/trusts issue rose in American consciousness in 1887–1888, American Democrats—like Canadian Liberals—tried to tie the problem to the nation’s high tariff wall. In January 1888, Republican Senator John Sherman proposed a then novel solution in a reply to a speech by Democratic President Grover Cleveland. According to Sherman, “When such combinations to prevent a reduction of price by fair competition exist I agree that they may and ought to be met by a reduction of duty.” Sherman repeated similar sentiments over the following months, going so far as to suggest that it might be appropriate to adjust the tariff on sugar in response to the “dangerous” Sugar Trust.Footnote 87 Sherman remained a staunch protectionist, however, making it difficult to determine whether he genuinely believed it appropriate to reduce the tariff temporarily to combat the effects of combines or whether he simply raised the issue in order to shift discourse away from free trade.

During the 1888 Canadian debates on the Anti-Combines Act, the Liberal Opposition proposed an almost identical solution: permitting the Governor-in-Council to reduce or eliminate the tariff on goods found to be subject to combines. Although there is no direct evidence that the Liberals were inspired by Sherman, the timing makes it highly likely. Unlike Sherman, however, the Liberals were genuinely opposed to high tariffs, and in 1897, the Wilfrid Laurier government enacted the tariff reduction proposal into law, though it proved unsatisfactory, as it had no effect on combines in local markets (e.g., those among retailers and wholesalers) and did not discriminate in its effects between combining and non-combining firms.Footnote 88

It is not wholly surprising that both Conservatives and Liberals were willing to look to the United States for a potential solution to the combines problem. After all, the two nations shared a common legal heritage, and both were then caught up in nearly identical debates on the role of combines and trusts in their respective economies. More importantly, because the combines question was not prominent in British discourse until much later,Footnote 89 Canadians were largely unable to look to the United Kingdom for a solution. If Canadians hoped to find some international precedent, they would have to look to the United States.

3. The United States as Economic Liberator through Free Trade

Given the Liberal Opposition’s focus on trade reciprocity with the United States during the period in which the combines problem first arose, it is unsurprising that the United States also appeared in political discourse as a potential economic liberator. For Liberals intent on dismantling the National Policy tariffs, the solution to the combines problem was not Canadian-specific legislation, which they believed would have little (if any) effect, but instead was opening the border to free trade with the United States.Footnote 90

From the very beginning, the Liberal Opposition tied the combines problem to the National Policy. Sir James David Edgar, the first Liberal to speak after Wallace moved for the creation of the Select Committee, argued “that the only real remedy for combines which are protected by a high tariff, is to reduce the duty,” though he did admit that other remedies might be necessary for “some combines which are affected by the tariff.”Footnote 91 Liberal MP James Frederick Lister was more clear: Wallace and other Conservatives could not “condemn the combine and at the same time attempt to sustain the so-called National Policy or high tariff policy of this Administration,” since combines were “the natural and inevitable outcome of a high protective tariff.”Footnote 92 Though Liberal MPs may not always have referred to the United States by name, given their simultaneous push for trade reciprocity, it is impossible to interpret the repeated references to reducing tariffs or repealing the National Policy in any other light.Footnote 93

Similar ideas also appeared in the testimony before the Select Committee. J. A. Matthewson, a wholesale grocer who protested the Dominion Wholesale Grocers’ Guild’s sugar combine, testified that he attempted to purchase sugar from the United States, but it was impossible because of the high tariff. “We were practically told: ‘You cannot get that from the United States, because our friends the refiners have a tariff in their favor,’ knowing that we had got hold of the idea that sugars could not be got from other countries.”Footnote 94 Likewise, The Globe reported on August 25, 1887, that American sugar could be purchased in England for less than half the price prevailing in Canada and called for a reduction in the tariff, though the editorialist despaired that any action was unlikely, as “the people have three times endorsed [the National Policy] at the polls,” such that “to purchase foreign refined sugar is a crime not to be named among ‘patriots,’ and one that must be suppressed at all hazards.”Footnote 95 The United States offered hope of escape from the worst Canadian combines.

In the meantime, the Liberal Opposition in the House of Commons appear to have realized that the combines problem could serve as a stalking horse for their broader goal of repealing the National Policy tariffs. But while any repeal bill was doomed to failure due to the Conservative majority, Liberals pressed a compromise proposal, whereby the Governor-General-in-Council could reduce the tariff on goods subject to combines, as noted above. The failure of the Liberals’ article-specific remedy illustrates the chief flaw in their approach to resolving the combines problem: free trade with the United States could only mitigate the effects of Canadian combines where the relevant market was larger than Canada. Where markets were local, regional, or even national—as was the case especially in the wholesale distribution and retail sale of goods—free trade could do little to remedy the effects of combines. It made little difference, for instance, if American refiners sold granulated sugar for less than Canadian refiners if higher consumer prices were the result of a combine among wholesale grocers. While some Liberals (such as Sir James David Edgar) recognized that trade reciprocity with the United States was not a universal panacea,Footnote 96 they offered no alternative policy.

Two other factors made free trade with the United States an unlikely solution to the Canadian combines problem, despite Liberal rhetoric. First, the political situation in the United States made any agreement unlikely. Although the Democratic administration of Grover Cleveland made repeated attempts to step back from the protectionist policies of his Republican predecessors, Republicans in the Senate were able to block most of his efforts, including the proposed Bayard-Chamberlain Treaty that would have resolved the long-festering Canadian–American fisheries dispute.Footnote 97 Indeed, the Liberal calls for unrestricted trade reciprocity with the United States coincided with a period of heightened American annexationist rhetoric. For instance, in mid-1888, Republican Senator John Sherman of Ohio, a former proponent of commercial union with Canada, came out against free trade with Canada on the grounds that it would hurt the cause of annexation. Instead, America’s best interests were served by refusing trade deals with Canada in order to starve the nation into surrender.Footnote 98 Senator Sherman is, of course, most remembered now as the sponsor of the American Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890.

This brings us to the second factor making free trade with the United States an unlikely solution to the combines problem: the American economy was by no means free of the combines problem. While this point was largely lost on the Liberal Opposition, it was not missed by Wallace and other Conservatives.

4. The United States as “Mother of Combines”

In response to Liberal claims that the combines problem could be solved through free trade with the United States, Wallace and other Conservatives constructed a discourse that instead portrayed the American economy as dominated by combines and claimed that opening up the border would subject Canadians to something far worse than the status quo.

Although combines had existed in Canada for approximately two decades, they had not reached the sophistication or scale of those of their siblings in the United States. There was simply no Canadian equivalent of the large, centralized trusts such as Standard Oil that had come to dominate the American economy and the headlines.Footnote 99 This is borne out in the contemporaneous news reports. Though it would later take a more moderate stance,Footnote 100 in 1888 during the height of the combines fervour, the Canadian Manufacturer took a decidedly anti-combines stance, regularly reporting on the evils of combines on both sides of the border. The reporting reached a high point in the April 6, 1888, issue, which featured articles and editorial notes on nine combines—five in the United States, three in Canada, and one in Europe. But while the three Canadian combines were certainly troubling—the binder twineFootnote 101 and fire insurance combinesFootnote 102 discussed above, as well as an agreement by the merchants of Granby, Quebec, to divide their lines of businessFootnote 103 —they did not compare with the five American combines, which included a proposal under consideration by the American Stove Association to consolidate the industry into a trustFootnote 104 and the formation by the Western Paper Manufacturers’ Association of a pool arrangement that allowed the Association to order the shutdown of some or all member mills.Footnote 105 These two American combines were unquestionably unenforceable restraints of trade under English and Canadian law because they deprived the parties of the ability to run their businesses according to their own best judgment;Footnote 106 the Canadian combines did not even begin to approach them in either their effects upon the public or their restrictions upon the combine members. The same holds true writ large—some features not uncommon in American combines, including the trust holding structure and the cession of control to a central entity, simply did not exist at all in Canadian combines.

Testimony before the Select Committee supports the more advanced state of American combines. According to several witnesses, Canadian combines were formed at the instigation or with the support of American cartels. Charles Stark, a watch seller and watch case manufacturer, accused an American combine of tying the sale of watch movements to the sale of watch cases, rendering his business worthless.Footnote 107 While John Jones, a Montreal wholesale jeweller, claimed the tying arrangement had been necessary to prevent the sale of “bogus” Swiss watches “advertised and sold as genuine American watches,”Footnote 108 the real impetus was probably that Stark operated a catalogue business that was significantly undercutting the prices charged by retail jewellers.Footnote 109 Although the evidence points to this being a Canadian wholesalers’ cartel enforced by American manufacturers, Stark nonetheless blamed the broader combines problem on the United States, since combines “are of recent growth and originated in the States.”Footnote 110

American influence can also be seen in the formation of the combine of Toronto coal dealers, operated through the Coal Section of the Toronto Board of Trade. Failed Toronto mayor candidate Elias Rogers claimed that the combine was created at the instigation of the American coal producers, who “insisted on our organizing and fixing prices.”Footnote 111 But, Thomas McConnell, a rival coal merchant, testified that it had been Rogers himself who was behind the formation of the combine. According to McConnell, Rogers brought the American coal producers to Toronto and was instrumental in gaining their acquiescence in enforcing the Coal Section’s pricing scheme. But, ironically, this did not make the combine any less American, as, McConnell further testified that Rogers “has been an American himself” and was also a member of the American coal combine.Footnote 112 Whether the decision to form a combine was made in Toronto or south of the border, the perception was that it was ultimately an American decision.

Conservatives also worried that American firms were engaged in predatory pricing (in the form of dumping) in order to destroy Canadian competitors in their infancy. In February 1888, for instance, Wallace cited an 1887 speech by Liberal MP James Frederick Lister in which Lister detailed the threat posed by Standard Oil. “We know perfectly well, as far as the United States is concerned, that the whole oil interest in the United States is practically controlled by the Standard Oil Company, and we know that they have been bringing oil into this country to sell at a less price than the cost of producing it, in order to get the control of this market.”Footnote 113 Similarly, the New Brunswick rope manufacturer John Connor testified to the Select Committee that the American binding twine syndicate was “concentrating their efforts to kill the rival manufacturers and spread their product of low quality throughout Canada as well.”Footnote 114

The discourse of the United States as originator and propagator of combines reached a fever pitch in the 1888 parliamentary debates on trade reciprocity. Responding to Liberal claims that trade reciprocity would cure the combines problem, Conservatives argued instead that free trade would merely expose Canadian businesses and consumers to the far worse American combines. Conservative MP John Ferguson spoke most directly to Liberal proponents of unrestricted reciprocity when, on March 27, 1888, he said, “Why, … the ‘promised land’ of hon. gentlemen opposite is the mother of ‘combines,’ and it is well known that the combines regulate the whole trade of the country, and yet this is the country the hon. gentlemen invite us to go to.”Footnote 115 These sentiments were repeated a week later by James Masson, representative for Grey North: “They tell us that we are cursed with combines, and they calmly propose to cast us helpless into the lap of the mother of combines.”Footnote 116 Even when they did not use the “mother of combines” language, Conservative politicians portrayed the United States as utterly dominated by combines.

By the 1889 parliamentary session, both reciprocity and the combines problem had largely been replaced in the press, in the public mind, and on the legislative calendar by other issues, especially the Quebec Jesuits’ Estates Act. Insofar as the issues were raised, however, Liberals continued to claim free trade was a better solution, and Conservatives continued to rebut with claims of the perfidy of American combines. On March 14, 1889, for instance, Conservative MP Josiah Wood claimed, “Every person knows that there is no country in the world to-day where combinations of capital exist on a more extended scale, or with more perfect organization, and with more extended and dangerous powers, than they do in the United States at the present time.”Footnote 117 On April 8, 1889, George Guillet put the issue most colourfully, noting “What they say practically amounts to this: the jackals are abroad in this country, let us introduce a horde of American wolves to drive out the jackals. They say the hawks are carrying off the chickens and they would prevent that by permitting the American eagle and vulture to carry off our lambs.”Footnote 118

Although the issue was largely argued on partisan grounds, some Liberals did acknowledge and try to remedy the threat of American combines. During the debates on the Anti-Combines Act itself, Liberal MP James McMullen recognized targeted action was necessary:

When we look at the history of the United States, and see the evils which have arisen there in connection with these combines, I think we will decide that it is high time that something should be done here to prevent the implanting of these evil and pernicious systems in Canada, which result in giving to those who are producers the advantage which should be obtained by the consuming public. …

[T]he fact is that combines in that country have succeeded to such an extent that it seems as if everyone was interested in a combine. When those companies approach the legislatures, almost every man sitting in the House is either directly or indirectly interested in a combine, and consequently they cannot be reached.Footnote 119

While McMullen did not directly adopt the rhetoric of the United States as “mother of combines,” he and other Liberal supporters of anti-combine legislation recognized that free trade was itself not a universal palliative.

Regardless of whether American combines were genuinely as bad as argued by Conservative MPs (though they probably were), the discourse of the United States as “mother of combines” demonstrated widespread Canadian discomfort with their neighbour to the south. American combines and trusts were genuinely problematic, but the vehemence of Conservative discourse suggests that something else was also at play—the United States represented what Canada could have been, but had chosen not to be.

III. Conclusion

References to the United States pervaded the Canadian anti-combines debates of 1887 to 1889. From the very beginning, the Liberal Opposition tied the existence of combines in Canada to the National Policy tariff and argued that opening up the border with the United States would prove fatal to the combines. On the other hand, Conservatives—buoyed by testimony before Wallace’s Select Committee—argued that combines were much more advanced south of the border and implicated numerous American companies and American émigrés in the formation and propagation of combines in Canada. Though this debate was centrally over economic policy, it was not limited to it, and had serious implications for the evolving discourse of Canadian national identity. For the Conservatives under Sir John A. Macdonald, being Canadian meant resisting the influence of the United States in the economic sphere, as well as the political; for the Liberal Opposition, being Canadian meant something different, focused more on maintaining a British style of government or maintaining vague cultural ties to the mother country than on the level of economic integration with the United States. Though these conflicting conceptions of Canadian national identity would come to a head in the 1891 parliamentary election, the slow growth of the conflict can be seen clearly in the 1887 to 1889 combines debates in and out of Parliament.

Even as Conservatives portrayed the United States as “the mother of combines,” however, they remained willing to look to American law for potential solutions to the combines problem. Given Liberal free trade rhetoric, it is unsurprising that they borrowed American ideas, especially when those ideas called for lowering the tariff. But Conservative rhetoric explicitly questioned any influence from the United States. Though some explanations could be theorized—American law was less threatening than American businesses, Canadians had to look somewhere for legal ideas since the United Kingdom had failed to act on the combines problem, or simply that Wallace’s borrowing of a failed New York bill did not represent broader Conservative policy—the great paradox of the anti-combines debates remains: Canadians borrowed American ideas in order to avoid becoming American.

Footnotes

*

Legal Director, FreeState Justice (Baltimore, Maryland). An earlier version of this article was presented at the American Society for Legal History Annual Meeting in November 2013, as part of the panel “Resistance and Reception: Attitudes to American Law in Nineteenth-Century Canada.” My sincerest thanks to Mark Antaki, Elsbeth Heamon, Pierre-Emmanuel Moyse, Lyndsay Campbell, David Schorr, Stephen Azzi, and Catharine MacMillan for their comments on my earlier draft and/or conference paper. This research was supported in part by a grant from the McGill University Faculty of Law, as well as a Richard H. Tomlinson Doctoral Fellowship.

References

1 An Act for the Prevention and Suppression of Combinations Formed in Restraint of Trade SC 1889 c 41.

2 Sherman Antitrust Act 26 Stat 209 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 USC § 1-7).

3 This article focuses on these actors (and on the popular and political rhetoric surrounding the Anti-Combines Act more broadly) because they were the voices that dominated within the legal bodies (primarily the Parliament of Canada) that considered the combines problem. By contrast, academic discourse was largely absent from the debates. While the views of lawyers, judges, and other legal actors played a critical role in the shifting interpretation of the common law restraint of trade doctrine, which formed the basis of both the Anti-Combines Act and the American Sherman Antitrust Act, I have discussed this shifting legal discourse at length elsewhere. See C. P. Hoffman, “A Reappraisal of the Canadian Anti-Combines Act of 1889” Queen’s Law Journal 39, no. 1 (2013): 127.

4 While the United Kingdom was referenced throughout the legislative debates, it never became a central focus in the same way that the United States did. This was in large part due to the fact that Free Trade and laissez-faire ideologies held much greater sway over British law and policy, leading to a system that was far less concerned with the regulation of combines and cartels. See Freyer, Tony, Regulating Big Business: Antitrust in Great Britain and America, 1880–1990 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992), 2021, 46CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Trebilcock, Michael J, The Common Law of Restraint of Trade: A Legal and Economic Analysis (Toronto: Carswell, 1986), at 1516 Google Scholar. Without British debates or reforms to point to, Canadian attention became focused far more on what was happening south of the border than across the Atlantic.

5 See Fowke, Vernon Clifford, The National Policy and the Wheat Economy (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1957), at 64 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Bliss, Michael, A Living Profit: Studies in the Social History of Canadian Business, 1883–1911 (Toronto: McClelland and Stewart, 1974), 12 Google Scholar [Bliss, A Living Profit]. Christopher Pennington was slightly more circumspect, stating, “In late nineteenth-century Canadian politics there were really only two subjects of life-or-death importance: the trade question, and the race-and-religion question.” Christopher Pennington, The Destiny of Canada: Macdonald, Laurier, and the Election of 1891 (Toronto: Allen Lane Canada, 2011) (ebook version), at Part I, Chapter 1.

7 Edward Porritt, “Canada’s National Policy” Political Science Quarterly 32, no. 2 (1917):177.

8 Morton, Desmond, A Short History of Canada, 6th ed. (Toronto: McClelland & Stewart, 2006)Google Scholar (ebook version), at Part II, Chapter 3.

9 Pennington, supra note 6, at Part I, Chapter 1.

10 See Baggaley, Carman D., “Tariffs, Combines and Politics: The Beginning of Canadian Competition Policy, 1888–1900,” in Historical Perspectives on Canadian Competition Policy, ed. Khemani, R. S. and Stanbury, W. T. (Halifax: Institute for Research on Public Policy, 1991), 1 at 35 Google Scholar.

11 Ibid 4.

12 Bliss, A Living Profit, supra note 6, 102; see also Baggaley, supra note 10, 4.

13 See Morton, supra note 8, Part II, Chapter 3; Pennington, supra note 6, Part I, Chapter 3.

14 Morton, supra note 8, Part II, Chapter 4.

15 Ibid; Pennington, supra note 6, Part I, Chapter 2.

16 Pennington, supra note 6, Part I, Chapter 3.

17 Ibid.

18 Journals of the House of Commons of the Dominion of Canada, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 22 (7 April 1888) at 161–64.

19 See, generally Pennington, supra note 6.

20 Forster, supra note 11, 110.

21 See Code, W. E. Brett, “The Salt Men of Goderich in Ontario’s Court of Chancery: Ontario Salt Co. v. Merchants Salt Co. and the Judicial Enforcement of Combinations,” McGill Law Journal 38, no. 3 (1993): 517 Google Scholar.

22 Ontario Salt v Merchants Salt (1871), 18 Gr Ont Ch 540.

23 See Baggaley, supra note 10, 8.

24 See, e.g., Schrader v Lillis (1886), 10 OR 358; see also Tucker, Eric, “The Faces of Coercion: The Legal Regulation of Labor Conflict in Ontario, 1880–1889,” Law and History Review 12, no. 2 (1994):277 Google Scholar.

25 See Baggaley, supra note 10 at 9; see also Bliss, A Living Profit, supra note 6, 33–54.

26 House of Commons, “Report of the Select Committee,” in Journals of the House of Commons, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 22 (16 May 1888) Appendix 3, 3–5 [“Select Committee Report”].

27 See, e.g., “News from Montreal: Grocers’ Combinations,” The [Toronto] Globe, 6 July 1887, 1.

28 See, e.g., Code, supra note 21.

29 Indeed, the Globe’s first editorial on sugar combine began by tying it to the National Policy. See “Sugar Refiners’ and Grocers’ Combination,” The [Toronto] Globe, 23 July 1887, 8.

30 See, e.g., “News from Montreal: Alleged Contractors’ ‘Combine,’” The [Toronto] Globe, 15 July 1887, 1; “News from Montreal: That ‘Combine,’” The [Toronto] Globe, 16 July 1887, 1 (reporting bid-rigging scheme for road construction contracts in Montreal; “A Corner in Salmon,” The [Toronto] Globe, 23 July 1887, 8 (reporting combine in canned salmon); “Notes and Comments,” The [Toronto] Globe, 27 July 1887, 4 (reporting on combine formed by American envelope makers); “Trusts,” The [Toronto] Globe, 5 August 1887, 4 (blaming the “trusts” problem in United States on protectionist trade policy) “Combination to Plunder the Public,” The [Toronto] Globe, 15 August 1887, 4 (reporting on combine among Canadian cotton mills).

31 See Andrew Thomson, The Sentinel and Orange and Protestant Advocate, 1877–1896: An Orange View of Canada (MA Thesis, Wilfrid Laurier University Department of History, 1983) [unpublished], 57; Christopher Armstrong and H. V. Nelles, The Revenge of the Methodist Bicycle Company: Sunday Streetcars and Municipal Reform in Toronto, 1888–1897 (Toronto: P Martin, 1977), 15; Baggaley, supra note 10, 10; Michael Bliss, “Another Anti-Trust Tradition: Canadian Anti-Combines Policy, 1889–1910” Business History Review 47, no. 2 (1973):178 [Bliss, “Another Anti-Trust Tradition”]; Brian P. Clark, “Wallace, Nathaniel Clarke,” Dictionary of Canadian Biography, vol. 13 (University of Toronto/Université Laval, 1994), online: Dictionary of Canadian Biography Online http://www.biographi.ca/en/bio/wallace_nathaniel_clarke_13E.html. See also Testimony of Elias Rogers (17 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 147.

32 See Hoffman, supra note 3.

33 Interestingly, while the conduct may have been seen as shocking to journalists and to the broader public, it was in many instances widespread within the specific business community. Indeed, much of the conflict in early competition law is centered on public attempts to override practices such as price fixing that had been normalized within business communities with the expectations of the broader populace. This mismatch between business practices and the public perception of those practices deserves greater attention in the future.

34 See infra Part II.4.

35 Mogul Steamship v McGregor, Gow & Co [1892] AC 25 (HL).

36 Nordenfelt v Maxim Nordenfelt Guns & Ammunition [1894] AC 535 (HL).

37 Mitchel v Reynolds (1711), 10 Mod 130, 88 ER 660 (QB).

38 See, e.g., Smith, John William, A Selection of Leading Cases on Various Branches of the Law with Notes, 7th ed., ed. Collins, Richard Henn and Arbuthnot, Robert George (London: William Maxwell & Son, 1876), 421 Google Scholar.

39 Mitchel, supra note 37 at 133.

40 Collins v Locke [1879] 4 AC 674 at 686 (PC).

41 Horner v Graves (1831), 7 Bing 735 at 743, 131 ER 284 at 287 (CP).

42 See Smith, John William, The Law of Contracts, 8th ed., ed. Thompson, Vincent T. (London: Stevens and Sons, 1885), 216 Google Scholar.

43 See, e.g., Chitty, Joseph, A Treatise on the Law of Contracts, Not under Seal, and upon the Usual Defenses to Actions Thereon, 12th ed., ed. Lely, J. M. and Geary, Nevill (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1890), 682 Google Scholar; Pollock, Frederick, Principles of Contract: Being a Treatise on the General Principles Concerning the Validity of Agreements in the Law of England, 4th ed. (London: Stevens & Sons, 1885), 316–19Google Scholar.

44 Hoffman, supra note 3.

45 Collins v Locke [1879] 4 AC 674 at 686 (PC).

46 Mineral Water Bottle Exchange & Trade Protection Society v Booth [1887] 36 CD 465.

47 Hoffman, supra note 3, 157.

48 See, e.g., Hilton v Eckersley (1855), 6 E & B 47, 119 ER 781 (Ex Ch) at 784–785 (QB) (Crompton, J). See also Tucker, supra note 24, 282.

49 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 25 (29 February 1888), 28 (Nathaniel Clarke Wallace).

50 “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 3.

51 Ibid, 7.

52 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 26 (18 May 1888), 1545 (Nathaniel Clarke Wallace). The full text of Wallace’s initial draft bill, which was not published in the official Hansard, is available in “The following is the text of the act for the suppression of combines introduced by Mr. Clarke Wallace,” The Canadian Journal of Commerce, Finance and Insurance Review (15 June 1888): 1152.

53 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 27 (6 February 1889), 19 (Nathaniel Clark Wallace).

54 See House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 28 (8 April 1889), 1117.

55 The bill was not printed at second reading, making it unclear what changes were introduced at this point by Wallace versus later by the Committee on Banking and Commerce. See Baggaley, supra note 10, 25. It is likely, however, that Wallace’s revised bill amended Section 1 to replace the qualifying language of “unduly” and “unreasonably” with “unlawfully,” increased fines to $4,000 for individuals and $10,000 for corporations, and deleted the provision in Section 2 that would have permitted the revocation of corporate charters.

56 See House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 28 (22 April 1889), 1446 (George Guillet).

57 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 28 (22 April 1889), 1440 (Nathaniel Clarke Wallace).

58 See House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 28 (22 April 1889), 1437 (John Sparrow David Thompson).

59 See, e.g., House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 28 (22 April 1889), 1439 (Louis Henry Davies); ibid, 1437–38 (David Mills); ibid, 1438 (James David Edgar); ibid, 1439 (John Sparrow David Thompson); ibid, 1441 (William Mulock).

60 See, e.g., Senate Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess. (26 April 1889), 622 (John Macdonald); Senate Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess. (29 April 1889), 635 (Francis Clemow); ibid, 641 (Jedediah Slason Carvell); ibid, 639 (John Joseph Caldwell Abbott).

61 Senate Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess. (29 April 1889), 654. The bill passed over five objections, but many of the senators who expressed reticence about the bill during the debates appear not to have been present for the final vote, which occurred after the evening recess.

62 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 28 (30 April 1889), 1691.

63 SC 1889 c 41 s 1.

64 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 28 (30 April 1889), 1689 (Nathaniel Clarke Wallace).

65 See Baggaley, supra note 10 at 32–34.

66 For a detailed review at the state of restraint of trade law at the time the Act was passed and of the various critiques of the law, see Hoffman, supra note 3.

67 Indeed, in some cases, north-south Canadian-American trade displaced east-west trade even within the United States. American brewers, for instance, preferred to purchase Canadian barley rather than barley from the western states, which was not suited for making lager ales. See Testimony of George Taylor, MP (27 April 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 316.

68 See, e.g., “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 8.

69 Ibid.

70 Ibid.

71 Ibid, 9 (noting that the price of stoves was generally comparable in the United States and Canada, with some styles cheaper in Canada).

72 Testimony of Thomas McConnell (5 April 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 208–209; Testimony of George F. Hartt (10 April 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 239 (comparing price of anthracite coal in Montreal to price in Toronto and in American cities, including Buffalo).

73 Testimony of George Taylor, MP (27 April 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 314 (“We always pay as much to the Canadian farmers as the Americans do to their farmers. I have been buying for 25 years and I do not know of any difference.”).

74 Testimony of Walter Paul (18 April 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 131–32.

75 “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 9.

76 See “Fire Underwriting and Gasoline Stoves,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 6 April 1888, 220; “The Insurance Combine Against Gasoline Stoves,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 1 June 1888, 371; “Editorial Notes,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 1 June 1888, 372–73; “Insurance Reform,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 5 October 1888, 234–35.

77 “Gasoline Stoves,” The Monetary Times and Trade Review, 13 April 1888, 1272.

78 “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 10.

79 See, e.g., Testimony of John Connor (22 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 345–52.

80 “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 8.

81 Testimony of George Lightbound (9 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 28.

82 Ibid.

83 See Baker, G. Blaine, “The Reconstitution of Upper Canadian Legal Thought in the Late-Victorian Empire,” Law and History Review 3, no. 2 (1985): 219–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

84 See Hoffman, supra note 3.

85 Bliss, “Another Anti-Trust Tradition,” 178.

86 Testimony of Charles Stark (9 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 328.

87 “John Sherman’s Opportunity,” The New York Times, 20 August 1888.

88 Bliss, “Another Anti-Trust Tradition,” 183.

89 See Freyer, Regulating Big Business: Antitrust in Great Britain and America, supra note 4, 4.

90 See Bliss, “Another Anti-Trust Tradition,” 182.

91 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 25 (29 February 1888), 31 (James David Edgar).

92 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 25 (29 February 1888), 31 (James Frederick Lister).

93 See, e.g., Testimony of J. A. Matthewson (9 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 31 (noting that Canada had incurred “the ill-will of our neighbors [the United States] most decidedly by levying a tariff which largely meant them.”).

94 Ibid.

95 “The ‘Undervaluation’ Screw to Be Turned,” The [Toronto] Globe, 25 August 1887, 4.

96 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 25 (29 February 1888), 31 (James David Edgar).

97 See Pennington, supra note 6, Part I, Chapter 5.

98 See ibid.

99 Bliss, “Another Anti-Trust Tradition,” 186; Jamie Benidickson, “The Combines Problem in Canadian Legal Thought, 1867–1920” University of Toronto Law Journal 43, no. 4 (1993):799–850.

100 The change in policy began in June 1888, when the Canadian Manufacturer distinguished between “combinations” and “monopolies,” in which it endorsed legislation to protect against bad combines, but not blanket prohibitions on combines and trade associations. “Combinations Versus Monopoly,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 1 June 1888, 371. See also “Editorial Notes,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 1 June 1888, 373 (“The use of combinations for illegal purposes should be ‘repressed,’ but combinations—never.”).

101 “Editorial Notes,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 6 April 1888, 229.

102 “Fire Underwriting and Gasoline Stoves,” supra, note 76, 220.

103 “Editorial Notes,” The Canadian Manufacturer and Industrial World, 6 April 1888, 226.

104 Ibid, 228.

105 Ibid, 229.

106 See Hilton v Eckersley (1855), 6 El & Bl 47, 119 ER 781, (Ex Ch); see also Hoffman, supra note 3.

107 Testimony of Charles Stark (9 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 326.

108 Testimony of John H. Jones (9 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 332.

109 Testimony of Charles Stark (9 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 330.

110 Ibid at 331.

111 Testimony of Elias Rogers (17 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 147–50.

112 Testimony of Thomas McConnell (5 April 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 211.

113 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 25 (29 February 1888), 33 (Nathaniel Clarke Wallace) (quoting James Frederick Lister from 1887 debates).

114 Testimony of John Connor (22 March 1888), in “Select Committee Report,” supra note 26, 346.

115 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 25 (27 March 1888), 459 (John Ferguson).

116 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 2d sess., vol. 25 (4 April 1888), 543 (James Masson).

117 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 27 (14 March 1889), 627 (Josiah Wood).

118 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 28 (8 April 1889), 1115 (George Guillet).

119 House of Commons Debates, 6th parl., 3d sess., vol. 28 (22 April 1889), 1441 (James McMullen).