Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-20T00:15:50.482Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Structural Changes in the Dominion Personal Income Tax, 1932-49

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 November 2014

Wm. C. Hood*
Affiliation:
The University of Toronto
Get access

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Notes and Memoranda
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association 1949

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Musgrave, R. A. and Thin, Tun, “Income Tax Progression, 1929-1948” (Journal of Political Economy, vol. LVI, 1948, pp. 498514).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 Those with investment income over $3,000 did not enjoy the full 50 per cent abatement; rather, 50 per cent of the tax on such investment income was deferred until the taxpayer's death.

3 For a discussion of this and other measures of progression and references to other literature see Musgrave and Thin, “Income Tax Progression.”

4 It has also been called the “built-in-flexibility” of the income tax structure by Slitor, Richard E., in “The Measurement of Progressivity and Built-in-Flexibility” (Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. LXII, 1948, pp. 309–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar). This is perhaps not a good term since it does not show the elasticity of total tax yield from all taxpayers with respect to a change in rates.

5 For example, in 1949, the tax on $3,000 is $105 and on $4,000 is $269. For this income interval, the marginal rate may be taken as ($269 - $105) ÷ $1,000, or 16.4 per cent. Since the average rate on $3,000 in 1949 was 3.5 per cent liability progression at $4,000 is given 16.4% ÷ 3.5% =4.68.