Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T16:09:56.621Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Relative strength and foreign direct investment in civil conflicts

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 October 2023

Samaila Oluwatope Adelaiye
Affiliation:
Independent Scholar, New Haven, CT, USA, and University at Buffalo, Buffalo, NY, USA
Si Chen
Affiliation:
Independent Scholar, New York City, NY, USA
Mehwish Sarwari*
Affiliation:
SUNY Buffalo State University, Buffalo, NY, USA
*
Corresponding author: Mehwish Sarwari; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

What factors contribute to the differences in foreign direct investment (FDI) levels in environments characterized as high risk? While research shows that armed conflict influences foreign investment decisions, it remains unclear how conflict dynamics, specifically the relative power capabilities of warring parties, affect FDI. This study explores the effects of rebel strength relative to government forces on FDI. We argue that there is a reduction in foreign investments in civil conflict countries as rebels gain a military advantage relative to the government. Stronger insurgents send a signal that the government is losing its strength in the conflict, creating uncertainty regarding conflict outcomes and posing economic and security risks for investors. To avoid facing economic and property losses due to increasing rebel strength, investors are incentivized to decrease their investment in the conflict state. Using data on insurgent troop size relative to government forces and FDI, our findings show that higher military capabilities of rebel forces relative to the government are associated with less FDI inflows in conflict-affected countries.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Vinod K. Aggarwal

Introduction

In response to the growing strength of the Tigray rebels during the recent civil conflict in Ethiopia between the government and the Tigray People's Liberation Front, Prime Minister Abiy Ahmed noted in a press statement that “we should know that our enemy's main strength is our weakness and unpreparedness.”Footnote 1 The conflict, which started in November 2020, has escalated to different parts of the country as rebels have gained power in several cities, including those close to the country's capital.Footnote 2 These events have placed significant pressures on civilian populations and foreigners, including foreign investors, to leave the state. In fact, many investors in conflict-affected areas have ended their operations to avoid further losses. This includes investments made by Egyptian industrial firms located in the Tigray region.Footnote 3 Reflecting on the loss of millions of dollars in investments in Ethiopia as a result of the conflict and the weakening of the Ethiopian government, Alaa El-Sakty, vice chair of the Egyptian Federation of Investors Associations, claimed in an interview that “the Egyptian economy and investments will not be affected in any way, in the event that Egyptian investments exit from Ethiopia. In the meantime, it is possible to start business in another African country that does not suffer from the same security and protection problems.”Footnote 4

Variation in foreign direct investment (FDI) across high-risk environments is the subject of an emerging subliterature. This body of research explores the complex relationship between risk and FDI, acknowledging that while risk may generally reduce the levels of FDI, other factors come into play. Previous studies in this area suggest that the impact of risk on FDI is influenced by factors such as state capacity,Footnote 5 transparency,Footnote 6 conditions in the home country,Footnote 7 sector dynamics,Footnote 8 and even physical distance at the subnational level.Footnote 9 However, one area of research that remains unexplored is whether the military capabilities of warring parties relative to each other have any effect on the risk assessments made by foreign firms. As highlighted during the civil war in Ethiopia, investors take into account the increasing strength of insurgents during conflict when making their investment decisions. Governments that are militarily weaker relative to insurgent groups are pressured to funnel their resources into fighting the opposition, leaving them ill-equipped to provide foreign firms with the support and security they need to maintain their business. This can lead to material costs for investors and a decrease in confidence in such governments. Based on the concerns raised by foreign firms in conflicts such as the recent one in Ethiopia, we are interested in exploring the following question: in countries experiencing civil conflict, are the decisions made by foreign firms to invest in a country influenced by the military strength of rebel movements relative to government forces?

Armed conflict creates complicated conditions for foreign firms operating in a country, including potential economic losses and security dilemmas. While these issues are of concern in all conflict zones, investment decisions made by foreign firms vary across conflict states and over time. We seek to explain this variation. We propose the argument that intrastate wars in which insurgent groups are militarily strong relative to the state amplify the risks faced by foreign investors. Firms use state capacity as a signal of the stability of the government they are working with and the environment they are expected to do business in. States with stronger capacity are often associated with lower political and economic risks.Footnote 10 As the relative military capabilities of rebel groups increase, this poses a challenge to investors by creating conditions that can lead to commitment problems and possibly conflict renewal. These threats are expected to be factored into the decision-making calculus of foreign investors. We anticipate that firms withdraw their investments from conflicts where rebels have a military advantage relative to the government as a response to the security and economic uncertainties they face.

This work contributes to the study of variation in FDI across high-risk countries by concentrating on the dynamics of government capacity in conflict-affected states. First, we focus on a new aspect of government strength to understand the decisions made by foreign investors operating in civil conflict zones: the military capabilities of the government relative to the rebel groups they are at war with. While extant research has assessed the relationship between FDI and government capacity, most research focuses on political regime type, governance, and absolute government military power. In the case of civil wars, the balance of power between the government and rebels can serve as an indicator of government strength for foreign investors. Second, while most foreign investors are often hesitant to operate in conflict-torn countries, some still choose to do so. Our study provides insight into how the preferences of investors that decide to do business in a conflict-affected country may change during the course of a conflict once their government partner becomes weaker relative to its opponent. Lastly, we provide the first quantitative test exploring the effects of the relative power capabilities of rebel movements and governments on foreign capital using time-varying data on the relative troop size of warring parties.

Our article is organized in the following manner. The first section of the study covers existing works on determinants of FDI, including those specific to conflict environments. Building on the literature on civil wars and FDI, we put forth our theoretical framework. We argue that in intrastate conflicts in which the power balance is favorable to rebel groups, foreign firms are met with political and economic uncertainties. In response to these risks, they reduce their investments from the state. Following our discussion on the theoretical mechanisms linking FDI and the relative strength of governments to insurgent groups, we introduce our research design and empirical findings. Using data from the Uppsala Conflict Data Program on the relative military capabilities of rebels to state forces and FDI inflows, the results obtained yield support for the argument that civil war states receive less FDI when the relative military capabilities of rebels are a threat to the government they are in conflict with. This demonstrates that the relative military strength of the state is an aspect of government capacity that foreign investors are mindful of when operating in a country. The study concludes with suggestions for future research.

Determinants of foreign direct investment

Several factors determine foreign direct investments, including considerations of how much value such investments might have and the confidence that there will be no losses. These considerations are often contextualized as risks, and they mainly include financial and/or political risks.Footnote 11 Higher levels of political and economic threats create a disincentive for foreign firms as they produce added costs to doing business in such a country.Footnote 12 More recently, reputational risk has received increased attention for its growing potency in determining investment behavior, including reputational risks related to human rights and environmental concerns.Footnote 13 Scholars have categorized risks differently, but, generally speaking, economic and political risks tend to be the prime categories of factors found to influence FDI flow. The higher the risk in a country, the lower the amount of FDI it will host.

Economic risks deal with the economic performance of the host country, including risks associated with inflation, participation in international arrangements to resolve FDI disputes, and access to international credit.Footnote 14 Moreover, some works find that economic risk assessment tends to be the strongest predictor of inward FDI stock. Economic forces in a host country can weigh negatively on the fortunes of a foreign investor.Footnote 15

There is usually an interplay between economic and political risks in determining whether to invest or how much to invest in a host country. Political risks include the likelihood that the FDI host nation will take political actions or experience political problems that will affect FDI fortunes.Footnote 16 They also include more detailed considerations like the transparency of institutions, the ability of firms to influence government policy, the stability of government policy, and the government's ability to expropriate FDI assets.Footnote 17 Ekpenyong and Umoren point to the need to consider a more extensive range of factors that could influence political risk, defining political risk as events that have a destabilizing effect on the ability of enterprises to function in a polity.Footnote 18 This includes political violence, inconsistency in political alignment, and shifts in the power balance among political parties. One can summarize political risks as involving changes in political forces and events, where the assessment of the host country is conditioned on uncertainty about the actions of government, political institutions, minority groups, and even separatist movements.Footnote 19 Sometimes, aside from the usual institutional characteristics that predict risk in the host country, investors depend on surveys by political risk analysts, risk insurance brokers, and business leaders to gauge a country's political risk.Footnote 20 Once investments have been made, the investors are at the mercy of the host government. Political instability and the fear of expropriation can alter the interests of foreign investors and motivate their reluctance to move their capital into a potential host country.Footnote 21

Much research shows that political risks significantly affect investments when it comes to developing countries. It has been established that foreign firms and, by extension, foreign investors prefer their host countries to be free of armed violence and tend to show a preference for institutional arrangements that reduce the likelihood of unpredictable policies and risks.Footnote 22 These factors may include the level of protection of property rights and the rule of lawFootnote 23 and the host country's judicial system. Justice institutions are argued to be of particular importance for foreign firms from countries where these rights are well established or where the judicial system, for instance, enjoys independence from government interference.Footnote 24 In a study of French firms, Corcos et al. argue that stable justice institutions are essential factors considered even in trade within firms.Footnote 25 They represent a significant predictor of intrafirm trade, a significant component of FDI.

Researchers have historically debated the importance of political risks in FDI flow.Footnote 26 Not everyone agrees that these factors matter when it comes to the flow of inward FDI. Research has pointed to how economic factors such as market size, access to credit, and so on, tend to be the strongest predictors of FDI flow, explaining the gap in the amount of FDI hosted in industrialized countries compared to developing countries.Footnote 27 Some economic-focused research has found that political factors, such as government failure, do not influence FDI.Footnote 28 Others have argued that political considerations are second-order determinants of FDI as economic considerations remain the prime explanations for foreign direct investments.Footnote 29 In a study of FDI in Africa, Asiedu finds that while the usual economic factors like natural resources, market size, and inflation remain prime predictors of FDI, political and legal institutions and policies in the host government have similar effects, with corruption and political instability dissuading foreign investment.Footnote 30

Research has shown that political risks are stronger predictors of FDI flow in emerging economies than in industrialized countries and that such risks have increased in recent years.Footnote 31 Lucas points to political risk as the primary reason for the FDI gap between industrialized and developing countries, despite the potential for significant marginal returns in developing countries.Footnote 32 Regionally focused research on FDI flows to the Middle East and North African countries has also found political risk factors to be significant determinants of differences in FDI attractiveness across countries.Footnote 33 Some have called for a more conditional approach to political risks, such as political violence. Li, Murshed, and Tanna point out that while economic factors are the strongest predictors of FDI flows, the impact of political factors is uneven across sectors, as FDI flows to extractive sectors are most unlikely to be affected by armed conflicts.Footnote 34

The costs of divesting from a host country can dissuade investors from involving themselves in countries with domestic issues like political violence. However, although divestment comes with some costs to investors,Footnote 35 doing business in conflict-torn countries may come at a higher financial or even reputational cost. Material costs can be incurred as a result of attacks on infrastructure in these countries.Footnote 36 Investors can also face criticism from the international community for doing business with a country that is in active civil conflict.Footnote 37

Evidence of the state losing ground as well as legitimacy is detrimental to investor confidence. With uncertainty regarding the government's capabilities, a potential loss of future investment opportunities if the rebels win, and any risk of conflict renewal,Footnote 38 foreign businesses are pressured to reassess their decision to remain in the host country. Most of this research assumes the need for foreign investors to find a safe investing environment. However, this precondition is challenged when investors engage in risky investment behavior. For example, Kolstad and Wiig write that increasing Chinese investments have been finding their way into unstable and natural resource-rich African countries, further destabilizing these regions.Footnote 39 However, by understanding that risks are constantly juxtaposed with benefits in investment decisions, one can get a clear picture of how the relationship between risks and investments is conditioned on potential benefits.Footnote 40

While foreign firms face risks in nonconflict states, such risks are particularly prevalent in war-torn countries and conditioned by conflict-specific factors. In cases of civil war, we argue that one particular conflict characteristic that foreign investors should consider when determining a state's risk is the military strength of the government compared to the rebel movements it is at war with. This conflict feature can impact a foreign firm's confidence in the strength of the government it partners with. Next, we theorize how the balance of power between rebels and a government affects the investment decisions made by foreign businesses in a conflict state.

The risks associated with increasing rebel capabilities for foreign investors

FDI can serve as a crucial avenue for development and postconflict recovery in high-risk countries. Extensive research has demonstrated that foreign investments contribute to economic growth, both directly and indirectly. Countries grappling with armed conflict often require economic growth as they rebuild in the aftermath of turmoil, leading them to incentivize and attract foreign investors.Footnote 41 However, growth in the military capability of rebel groups could mean more intense conflict, which is linked to reduced economic growth. This could be through pathways that reduce public and private investment in the country experiencing conflict.Footnote 42 It is important to consider the extent to which these dynamics affect FDI.

The extant literature on FDI shows mixed findings on the relationship between armed conflict and FDI. Many works point out that foreign investors face significant risks in areas impacted by conflict and violence.Footnote 43 However, there is evidence that these concerns can be alleviated by strong state capacity, stable institutions, and military expenditure.Footnote 44 While studies have shown that the unique attributes of the state are important for explaining FDI,Footnote 45 research has yet to consider the role of rebels in shaping the views held by foreign investors regarding the strength and stability of a government during conflict. Rebel groups vary in terms of their characteristics, including their military strength relative to the government, which can impact the conflict and war outcomes.Footnote 46 As stated by Clayton, “the absolute strength of a belligerent is less important than their strength in relation to their opponent.”Footnote 47 While we agree that government strength matters to foreign investors, we rely on the literature on FDI and civil conflict and argue that foreign investors consider whether the government is militarily stronger relative to the rebels that it is in conflict with and not just the overall military strength of a government. The power dynamics between warring parties can affect the environment of the conflict country and as a result, impact the investment choices of foreign firms.

The reduction in FDI levels can occur through two pathways. First, it can happen as a result of relatively higher rates of divestment, as foreign firms withdraw their investments from a country. Divestment can be driven by a variety of factors, such as increased risks, political instability, unfavorable economic conditions, or concerns about the business environment. Research has shown that a deconstruction of firm-level decisions on disinvestment and decisions about how much to invest are not equally affected by political risks.Footnote 48 Unlike the decision to invest, withdrawing investment is more complex; foreign firms are at the mercy of the host government, and they are forced to be less responsive to political changes. Divestment could mean the loss of capital for some of these firms as FDI is less movable.Footnote 49 Firms that have already invested in the country might find it more difficult to exit the host government as a response to the political climate, and they tend to have a higher tolerance for political risks. However, they are still more likely to withdraw investment as political risks increase.Footnote 50

Second, lower FDI levels can also result from relatively lower rates of new investment, as foreign firms become hesitant to make further investments in a particular country. This hesitation can stem from factors such as uncertain economic prospects, unfavorable government policies, regulatory barriers, or lack of confidence in the business climate. Countries may be forced to reevaluate their decision to enter a host country that presents risks and uncertainties. This is the more sensitive pathway as the current political situation is considered.Footnote 51 Foreign investors thus assess the features of a potential market and make investment decisions based on the host country's climate, understanding that withdrawals will be difficult once investments are made. Amid an uncertain political environment in a potential host state, investors may be reluctant to move capital there. This may result in a reduction in the level of FDI.

In our theory, we consider both pathways—divestment and reduced new investment—as potential factors contributing to the lower levels of FDI observed. By examining these two pathways, we aim to comprehensively understand how the balance of power in conflict influences FDI and its variations across conflict zones. The reduction in the volume of FDI could result from a reduction in the amount of new foreign investments coming into the host government. It could also be a result of an increase in the exit or withdrawal of foreign investors or firms from a host country. It is thus important to address how the power dynamics of the conflict affect the decision to withdraw investment, as well the incentives to invest in a host country that is already experiencing armed conflict.Footnote 52

As pointed out by Li and Resnick, firms withdraw from areas where the costs of investment are high because of the risks they face.Footnote 53 We propose that the military capabilities of rebels relative to the government can create several concerns for foreign firms if the balance of power is tilted away from the government. First, rebel organizations that have a military advantage over the government can reveal the state's weakness in preventing its opponent from mobilizing and expanding its territorial control.Footnote 54 A shift in the balance of power between rebels and government forces in favor of rebels benefits the latter in that the rebels are able to gain control over territory, resources, and access to new recruits.Footnote 55 However, such shifts also suggest that state capacity is diminishing. As the literature has highlighted, a decline in government strength can send a negative signal to investors, influencing their decisions as to whether they should continue investing in the country.Footnote 56 While conflict itself creates a risky environment for foreign firms,Footnote 57 a government that is militarily weak relative to its enemy may create additional political and economic risks for investors, including enforcement of contracts and property rights.Footnote 58 Although a state's military power can help minimize these risks, this can change if a government faces strong rebels. Such governments must redirect their resources to deter the opposition from becoming even stronger, making it more difficult for investors to remain in the country.

Second, rebels with higher military capabilities relative to the government can pose security issues for investors. Governments that are challenged by rebels that have a military advantage are forced to allocate their available resources to fight their opponent. As a consequence, this affects their capacity to provide protection for local populations and businesses, including foreign firms and the individuals they employ, leaving them exposed to violence. Not only does this impact the personal security of investors and their workers, but it can also influence production and the ability of a foreign firm to make a profit.Footnote 59 Though some businesses may have the capacity to use their own capital to attain private security, not all investors have the means to do so. A decline in security measures by the state for foreign firms results in unexpected costs for investors and takes away from any earnings they may have gained while operating in the country.

Furthermore, the relative strength of a rebel group can influence the outcome of a conflict. States in conflict that have strong militaries are expected to pursue military victory as opposed to negotiating a deal with their opponent.Footnote 60 Stronger insurgents, on the other hand, are able to survive the costs of continued fighting and, as a result, threaten a government's ability to stay in power.Footnote 61 This can raise the costs of the conflict and lead to more violence and destruction of infrastructure.Footnote 62 While governments that face rebels with higher military capabilities are more likely to agree to mediationFootnote 63 and offer concessionsFootnote 64 to avoid a possible rebel victory, the bargaining position of stronger rebels can prolong conflict as they try to obtain additional concessions or further increase their power capabilities to defeat the government.Footnote 65 With little clarity as to how the conflict will end, foreign firms can become discouraged from maintaining their investments in the state.

Additionally, as noted by Lee, “foreign investors are both backward-looking and forward-looking.”Footnote 66 We therefore expect that increasing rebel strength and a potential rebel victory can raise concerns over future contract commitments for investors. Although it is difficult for investors to predict shifts in the fighting capabilities of conflict actors, any advancements in rebel military strength can put foreign investors in a difficult position. While a foreign firm may be familiar with the government in power and its business expectations and policies, the policy preferences of rebel groups will be less clear to foreign investors. If rebels were to defeat the government and win the conflict, it would be unknown to investors whether future contracts with the state would resume or remain credible given the likelihood of the state's institutions and policies changing.Footnote 67 To avoid having their capital and property affected if rebels were to achieve military victory, a foreign investor may find it beneficial to reduce their investments from a country on their own before they are forced out if the rebels are uninterested in maintaining ties with them.

Lastly, another factor that foreign investors consider when determining whether they should continue their investment in a country where rebels have stronger military capabilities relative to the government is the possibility of conflict reoccurrence.Footnote 68 While findings on the relationship between conflict outcomes and postconflict stability are mixed,Footnote 69 some studies show that conflict reoccurrence is less likely if government forces achieve victory in comparison to a rebel defeat.Footnote 70 In situations in which conflict renewal is likely to occur, the confidence of firms in seeing any possible future stability may be affected.Footnote 71 As a response, they may try to withdraw from the country to avoid getting entangled in the dynamics and consequences of a renewed conflict that could be more violent and costly than the previous one.

Our analysis considers the level of FDI inflow in the host country, and it does not differentiate between the withdrawal of FDI and the inflow of new investments. However, based on the mechanisms for both pathways considered earlier, we propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1: The stronger the military capabilities of rebel forces are relative to the government, the less FDI inflows the conflict country will receive.

Research design

In this study, we seek to examine the effect of the relative military capabilities of rebel movements to government forces on FDI in intrastate conflicts. To determine the appropriate cases to use in our sample, we rely on data from the Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP) Dyadic dataset v. 20.1.Footnote 72 Looking at civil wars during the period 1989–2009, our sample includes a total of 625 country-year cases.Footnote 73

Dependent variable

To measure yearly FDI Inflows for civil conflict countries included in our sample, we rely on data from the World Development Indicator Database. We account for the positive skewness of these data by using the logged values of FDI net inflows (measured in millions of US dollars) to estimate our analyses.Footnote 74

Independent variable

Our independent variable, Relative Rebel Strength, is measured as the ratio of the troop size of all rebel groups in a conflict to government forces. These data are drawn from the UCDP Conflict Encyclopedia.Footnote 75 To test our argument, we apply the measurement approach used by Wood and take the natural log of these data.Footnote 76 Negative values suggest that states forces are militarily stronger than the insurgents, whereas positive values suggest that rebel movements have a troop advantage over the government. In situations in which the power capabilities of the government and rebels are equal, such cases are assigned a value of 0.Footnote 77

Control variables

We also include in our analysis additional factors that may be correlated with investment decisions made by foreign firms. We first consider conflict-specific characteristics. The literature has highlighted the deterring effects of violence on foreign investments.Footnote 78 Violence can pose economic and security risks for foreign firmsFootnote 79 and disrupt peace processes,Footnote 80 creating uncertainty for investors. To control for this phenomenon, we use data on civilian victimization by state forces and rebels from the UCDP One-Sided Violence Dataset, v. 21.1, to create the variables Government-Inflicted Violence and Rebel-Inflicted Violence.Footnote 81 We also control for Size of the Conflict Zone (logged). It is possible that the larger a conflict area is, the more threats there will be to an investor's infrastructure, capital, and overall security, resulting in divestment from the conflict country. Data for this variable come from the International Peace Institute, Oslo (PRIO) Conflict Site Dataset v.3,Footnote 82 which captures the amount of territory impacted by conflict in square kilometers. Additionally, the variable Conflict Duration is included to consider any impact that the number of years a country has been in conflict has on FDI.Footnote 83

The unique features of the country facing intrastate conflict are also taken into consideration. First, we expect that the economic characteristics of a state shape foreign investment decisions. For instance, states with higher economic development are able to signal to investors the economic stability of the state and create investment opportunities for foreign firms.Footnote 84 To measure the Economic Capacity of a country, we draw on yearly gross domestic product (GDP) per capita data from the World Bank. Moreover, it is expected that areas where natural resources are available receive more FDI. Relying on World Bank data, our Natural Resources variable captures how much of a country's economy relies on revenue from natural resources (percent of GDP). Research also points out that foreign firms take into account the political qualities and security structure of a state they seek to invest in. Countries with stronger militaries are able to provide protection to investors and their property.Footnote 85 Relying on data from the National Material Capabilities dataset v. 5.0 to create the variable Troop Quality, we use a state's military expenditure per military personnel to measure the strength of its military infrastructure. The Political Regime of a state serves as a strong indicator of the political risks of a country and its likelihood of protecting property rights.Footnote 86 To capture the influence of a country's regime type on FDI, we use Polity IV data to calculate X-Polity scores.Footnote 87 Lastly, there is empirical evidence showing higher amounts of FDI in states with independent judiciaries and rule of law.Footnote 88 To measure the Judicial Quality of a country, data on de facto judicial independence from the Comparative Constitutions ProjectFootnote 89 are used.

Model

To test the claims proposed in the study, an ordinary least squares regression model with country and year fixed effects is estimated. To address issues of endogeneity, our predictor variables are lagged by one year.Footnote 90

Empirical analysis and discussion

Examining all civil conflicts that occurred between 1989 and 2009, we test the effect of relative rebel capabilities on foreign investment.Footnote 91 We estimate two models: one baseline model without control variables, to avoid introducing any bias (Model 1),Footnote 92 and a model that includes the control variables discussed in the previous section (Model 2). The results for these models are presented in Table 1. As shown in Table 1, our Relative Rebel Strength variable is negative and achieves statistical significance in both Models 1 and 2. In looking at the results of Model 1, our baseline model, the results indicate that a 1 percent increase in Relative Rebel Strength is associated with a 1.024 percent decrease in FDI inflows. As shown in Model 2, the effect that the relative strength of rebel groups has on FDI inflows becomes slightly smaller once we include our control variables in the model. Nevertheless, the findings show that foreign investors react to the military strength of rebel movements. Specifically, the coefficient for Relative Rebel Strength suggests that a 1 percent increase in rebel capabilities relative to the government results in a 0.853 percent decrease in FDI inflows. These findings yield support for our theoretical expectations that conflict-affected countries receive less investment from foreign firms as the military strength of rebels relative to government forces becomes stronger. Increasing rebel capabilities creates uncertainty for investors regarding the stability of the conflict environment and conflict outcomes and thus, discourages them from making investments in the state.

Table 1. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI

Note: Standard errors in parentheses.

* p < .1; ** p < .05; *** p < .01.

Using the results of Model 2, we calculate the predicted amounts of FDI inflow across different levels of relative rebel capabilities to illustrate the substantive effects of the balance of power between government forces and rebels on FDI.Footnote 93 These values are presented in Figure 1. As shown in the graph, when rebels are at parity with government forces (level 0), FDI inflows in the country are $3,639,948. However, in situations in which rebel movements are much stronger than the government (level 2), states receive $660,333 in FDI, a decrease of $2,979,615. This suggests that advances in military strength by rebels over state forces has reducing effects on foreign investments coming into a country.

Figure 1. Predicted FDI inflows across different levels of relative rebel capabilities.

Note: number of cases within parentheses*

Turning to the control variables included in Model 2, Size of Conflict Zone surprisingly has a positive and significant coefficient, suggesting that foreign investors are not necessarily deterred from countries where large amounts of territory are impacted by conflict. Larger conflict zones may be linked to larger countries having more territory. Further research will have to deconstruct what the expansion of conflict areas could mean for FDI and investors’ assessments of the country experiencing conflict. The duration of conflict also has a positive and significant relationship with FDI inflows. As found by and Buhaug, Gates, and Lujala and by Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan, weaker rebels are associated with longer conflicts.Footnote 94 An argument can be made that foreign firms continue to operate in countries experiencing longer wars if rebels are weak. With respect to the country-specific variables we account for in our analysis, Troop Quality is positive and significant. As anticipated, investors are drawn to countries that have better equipped militaries which can be used to provide protection for them and their assets. Another factor that is positive and achieves statistical significance is Judicial Quality. Consistent with findings in extant literature on FDI, these results suggest that states that practice judicial independence are able to signal the presence of stronger political institutions and as a result, receive more foreign investment.

Robustness checks

There is a significant debate in the literature on FDI regarding measurement of foreign investment in a country.Footnote 95 To address concerns regarding the appropriate measure of FDI to use and confirm the robustness of our findings, we estimate additional models using alternative measures of FDI. We first consider FDI as a percentage of a country's GDP and present the results in Table 2. Consistent with the findings of our main analyses, Relative Rebel Strength has a negative coefficient and holds statistical significance. An additional model is conducted using FDI stocks as the dependent variable. As portrayed in Table 3, this alternative measurement of FDI is in the negative direction and significant, providing additional confidence in our argument that the relative power capabilities of warring parties influence how attractive a country is to foreign firms.Footnote 96

Table 2. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (using FDI/GDP)

Note: Standard errors in parentheses.

* p < .1; ** p < .05; *** p < .01.

Table 3. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (using FDI stocks)

Note: Standard errors in parentheses.

* p < .1; ** p < .05; *** p < .01.

Conclusion

In contrast with other research on government stability and foreign direct investment, our work looks at the power dynamics within a conflict and how they could signal investment risks. The role of the power of rebel groups vis-á-vis the incumbent government presents an essential issue for any assessment of political and economic risks in investment decision-making. We find evidence to support our theory that rebel forces’ strength relative to the government of a state experiencing armed conflict disincentivizes inward FDI in civil war countries.

Our finding calls for more attention to how the power dynamics within a conflict affect investors’ confidence. Even in countries that experience armed conflict, other characteristics of the conflict could condition the perception of risk and the investment decisions made by foreign firms. Some research has cast doubt on the role of political instability on FDI, particularly pointing to investments in resource-rich countries despite existing armed conflicts. Our finding presents another layer to the argument and demonstrates that not all conflicts are equal. While foreign investors could ignore some risks in light of economic benefits and significant marginal gains, they may be unable to do so where rebel strength is high relative to state forces.

Beyond the impact of this on conflict time investments and economic development, this raises the importance of further research into how this could affect postconflict societies’ economic trajectories, seeing the importance of foreign investment for economic development. Where conflict has ended, what are the long-term effects of rebel strength on FDI? Seeing how risk perceptions are sticky, it would be worth analyzing how much the presence of strong rebel groups in previous armed conflicts affects FDI inflows and other policy options associated with a state's economic performance in postconflict settings.

This research encourages further research in other aspects of investments and how it may be affected by the strength dynamics of government and rebel forces. Our research focuses on foreign investment; however, domestic investors also play a significant role in the growth and development of states. Further research could also look at how the power dynamics of rebel and government forces could influence the activities of domestic investors. In addition to this, while our research examines countries experiencing conflict, future research could consider how other forms of unrest that signal a host government's loss of influence or power could influence the inward flow of FDI.

Some researchers have advocated for greater emphasis on fixed capital investment, arguing that focusing solely on FDI flows provides a limited perspective on foreign direct investment.Footnote 97 One suggestion that has been provided in the literature to address this concern is using plant, property, and equipment (PPE) data.Footnote 98 PPE represents the total value of physical structures, land, machinery, and equipment, considering factors such as depreciation and depletion. It also encompasses the book value of land, timber, mineral, and similar rights owned by the foreign affiliate. Because of data availability constraints, we are unable to test our theoretical expectations using PPE data. However, further research could expand upon this by examining a broader range of fixed capital expenditures to assess the impact of political risks on the behavior of multinational corporations. Kerner suggests that focusing on FDI flows and stock provides only a partial understanding, which is even more pronounced when considering PPE analysis.Footnote 99 Acquiring data in conflict zones could facilitate a more comprehensive analysis of how the balance of power between government and rebel forces significantly influences the assessment made by foreign firms and investors.

We acknowledge the limitations of our work, and we do not analyze the different types of FDI, industry-specific FDI or FDI data at the subnational level due to data limitations. While arguments could be made for how the relative military capabilities of conflict actors may have varying levels of impact based on these factors, it does not take away from our argument that the relationship is negative as it relates to the amount of FDI hosted by a country as a whole. At a macro level, as the strength of rebel groups increases relative to the government, the country is likely to see reduced amounts of foreign investments flow inward. This could fill in the blanks in our understanding of the causal mechanisms in the relationship between economics and government strength as determinants of FDI in conflict environments.

Supplementary appendix

I. Descriptive statistics

II. Model 2 results (Table 1)

Figure 2. Effect of relative rebel strength on FDI inflows.

III. Model 3 results (using FDI/GDP variable) (Table 2)

Figure 3. Effect of relative rebel strength on FDI/GDP.

IV. Model 4 results (using FDI stocks variable) (Table 3)

Figure 4. Effect of relative rebel strength on FDI stocks.

V. Results using PPML estimator

Table 4. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (using PPML estimator)

VI. Results of two-stage least squares (2SLS) model (second stage)

Table 5. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (2SLS model)

Footnotes

2 Walsh and Dahir (Reference Walsh and Dahir2022).

5 Coan and Kugler (Reference Coan and Kugler2008).

6 Barry and DiGiuseppe (Reference Barry and DiGiuseppe2019).

7 Beazer and Blake (Reference Beazer and Blake2018).

8 Wright and Zhu (Reference Wright and Zhu2018).

9 Dai, Eden, and Beamish (Reference Dai, Eden and Beamish2013).

11 Barry and DiGiuseppe (Reference Barry and DiGiuseppe2019); Blanton and Blanton (Reference Blanton and Blanton2009, 472); Jensen (Reference Jensen2008).

12 Jensen (Reference Jensen2008, 1040–42).

14 Lewandowski (Reference Lewandowski1997).

15 Goswami and Haider (Reference Goswami and Haider2014); Levis (Reference Levis1979).

16 Joshi and Quinn (Reference Joshi and Quinn2020).

18 Ekpenyong and Umoren (Reference Ekpenyong and Umoren2010).

19 Nelson, Sooreea, and Gokcek (Reference Nelson, Sooreea and Gokcek2016).

20 Lewandowski (Reference Lewandowski1997).

21 Li and Resnick (Reference Li and Resnick2003).

22 Bussmann (Reference Bussmann2010); Jensen (Reference Jensen2008); Jensen and Young (Reference Jensen and Young2008); Li, Murshed, and Tanna (Reference Li, Murshed and Tanna2017).

24 Beazer and Blake (Reference Beazer and Blake2018).

27 Qian and Baek (Reference Qian and Baek2011).

28 Goswami and Haider (Reference Goswami and Haider2014).

31 Qian and Baek (Reference Qian and Baek2011).

33 Nassour, Meftah, and Mirani (Reference Nassour, Meftah and Mirani2020).

34 Li, Murshed, and Tanna (Reference Li, Murshed and Tanna2017)

35 Guidolin and La Ferrara (Reference Guidolin and La Ferrara2007).

37 Adelaiye (Reference Adelaiye2023); Adelaiye, Oluwatope, and Roy (Reference Adelaiye, Roy and Sarwari2023); Barry, Clay, and Flynn (Reference Barry, Chad Clay and Flynn2013); Henisz (Reference Henisz2017).

38 Joshi and Quinn (Reference Joshi and Quinn2020).

39 Kolstad and Wiig (Reference Kolstad and Wiig2011).

40 Jensen and Johnston (Reference Jensen and Johnston2011).

41 Li and Liu (Reference Li and Liu2005); Osabutey and Okoro (Reference Osabutey and Okoro2015).

42 Imai and Weinstein (Reference Imai and Weinstein2000).

46 Buhaug, Gates, and Lujala (Reference Buhaug, Gates and Lujala2009); Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan (Reference Cunningham, Gleditsch and Salehyan2009).

47 Clayton (Reference Clayton2013, 611).

48 Haug, Nguyen, and Owen (Reference Haug, Nguyen and Dorian Owen2023).

49 Jensen and Johnston (Reference Jensen and Johnston2011).

50 Dai, Eden, and Beamish (Reference Dai, Eden and Beamish2013).

51 Osabutey and Okoro (Reference Osabutey and Okoro2015).

52 We thank an anonymous reviewer for highlighting the importance of discussing both pathways when explaining the reduced flow of FDI.

53 Li and Resnick (Reference Li and Resnick2003).

55 Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan (Reference Cunningham, Gleditsch and Salehyan2013); Kalyvas (Reference Kalyvas2006); Wood (Reference Wood2010).

56 Coan and Kugler (Reference Coan and Kugler2008).

57 Adelaiye (Reference Adelaiye2022); Adelaiye, Roy, and Sarwari (Reference Adelaiye2023); Collier (Reference Collier1999).

58 Papaioannou (Reference Papaioannou2009); Drezner and Hite-Rubin (Reference Drezner, Hite-Rubin, Suri and Valentino2016, 5–6).

61 Clayton (Reference Clayton2013); Nilsson (Reference Nilsson2010, 256).

62 Clayton (Reference Clayton2013).

63 Clayton (Reference Clayton2013).

64 Buhaug, Gates, and Lujala (Reference Buhaug, Gates and Lujala2009, 554); Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan (Reference Cunningham, Gleditsch and Salehyan2009).

65 Clayton (Reference Clayton2013).

66 Lee (Reference Lee2017, 171).

68 Bak and Lee (Reference Bak and Lee2021); Joshi and Quinn (Reference Joshi and Quinn2020).

69 Bak and Lee (Reference Bak and Lee2021, 5).

71 Bak and Lee (Reference Bak and Lee2021); Joshi and Quinn (Reference Joshi and Quinn2020).

72 Harbom, Melander, and Wallensteen (Reference Harbom, Melander and Wallensteen2008); Pettersson and Öberg (Reference Pettersson and Öberg2020).

73 This time frame was selected because of the availability of data for our Size of Conflict Zone variable. While our study accounts for 252 government-rebel movement dyads in 72 states, we are interested in testing how the overall military capacity of rebel groups relative to the government affects decisions made by foreign firms to invest in conflict countries. For this reason, we combine all rebel groups into one actor, which results in a total of 625 country-year cases.

74 As pointed out in the literature on trade and conflict, there are often zero or negative values of trade flows in countries impacted by conflict, and thus it is important to use a poisson pseudo maximum likelihood (PPML) estimator when empirically testing this relationship (Kamin Reference Kamin2022). To account for similar concerns in the case of foreign direct investment, we use a PPML estimator and report our findings in Table 4 in the appendix. The results of our independent variable, Relative Rebel Strength, support our expectation that the stronger the military capabilities of rebels are relative to government forces, the lower the FDI inflows in a conflict country.

75 UCDP (2022).

77 It is important to recognize that with respect to the relative military strength between rebels and governments, foreign investors may respond differently to the level of the relative ratio and changes in the relative ratio. While our study focuses on how the level of the relative ratio influences the investment decisions of foreign firms, future research should consider how the changes in the relative ratio affect foreign direct investment. We thank an anonymous reviewer for bringing this to our attention.

79 Blomberg, Hess, and Orphanides (Reference Blomberg, Brock and Orphanides2004); Lee (Reference Lee2017, 169–70).

80 Findley and Young (Reference Findley and Young2015); Fortna (Reference Fortna2015).

83 Buhaug, Gates, and Lujala (Reference Buhaug, Gates and Lujala2009) and Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan (Reference Cunningham, Gleditsch and Salehyan2009) find that conflicts last longer when rebel groups are militarily weaker.

84 Lee (Reference Lee2017, 197); Schneider and Frey (Reference Schneider and Frey1985).

85 Norrlof (Reference Norrlof2010).

87 Vreeland (Reference Vreeland2008).

88 Staats and Biglaiser (Reference Staats and Biglaiser2012).

89 Melton and Ginsburg (Reference Melton and Ginsburg2014).

90 In addition to using one-year lags, we lag our predictor variables by two years as a robustness check and find similar results as our main analyses. We also conduct a two-stage least squares (2SLS) model to account for the potential endogenous relationship between the relative capabilities of government forces and rebels and foreign direct investment. In this model, we use two instrumental variables, foreign support to state governments and foreign support to rebels. The findings are presented in Table 5 in the appendix. As shown by the results of our Relative Rebel Strength variable in the second stage of the 2SLS model, FDI inflows decrease as rebels become militarily stronger relative to the government.

91 All analyses were conducted using Stata 14. Summary statistics are available in the supplementary appendix.

93 Predictive values are calculated using SPOST (Long and Freese Reference Long and Freese2005).

94 Buhaug, Gates, and Lujala (Reference Buhaug, Gates and Lujala2009); Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan (Reference Cunningham, Gleditsch and Salehyan2009).

95 Lee (Reference Lee2017, 174).

96 We also provide coefficient plots to present the results of Model 2 (Table 1), Model 3 (Table 2), and Model 4 (Table 3) in the supplementary appendix (see Figures 2, 3 and 4).

97 Kerner and Lawrence (Reference Kerner and Lawrence2014).

Note: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses.

* p < .1; ** p < .05; *** p < .01.

Note: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses.

* p < .1; ** p < .05; *** p < .01.

References

Adelaiye, Samaila. 2022. “Foreign Direct Investment and Third-Party Diplomatic Intervention in Intrastate Conflict.” Territory, Politics: 118.Google Scholar
Adelaiye, Samaila. 2023. “Foreign Direct Investment Hosts and Violent Government Repression of Protests.” Business and Politics 25 (3): 315329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adelaiye, Samaila Oluwatope, Roy, Chhandosi, and Sarwari, Mehwish. 2023. “Economic Actors as Human Rights Watchers: The Effects of Government Sexual Violence on Foreign Direct Investment.” Foreign Policy Analysis, 19(2), p.orad001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Al-Aees, Shaimaa. 2021. “Egypt Investors in Ethiopia Request Compensations for Losses Due to Tigray Conflict.” Daily News Egypt, 21 January. Accessed on 1 November 2022, https://dailynewsegypt.com/2021/01/12/egypt-investors-in-ethiopia-request-compensations-for-losses-due-to-tigray-conflict/.Google Scholar
Anna, Cara. 2021. “Ethiopia PM Admits ‘Weakness and Unpreparedness’ as Tigray Rebels Make Gains.” Associated Press, 1 November. Accessed on 1 November 2022, https://www.cp24.com/world/ethiopia-pm-admits-weakness-and-unpreparedness-as-tigray-rebels-make-gains-1.5646516.Google Scholar
Asiedu, Elizabeth. 2005. “Foreign Direct Investment in Africa: The Role of Natural Resources, Market Size, Government Policy, Institutions and Political Stability.” WIDER Research Paper No. 2005/24. Accessed on 7 September 2023, https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/63499/1/500782164.pdf.Google Scholar
Aziz, Nusrate, and Khalid, Usman. 2019. “Armed Conflict, Military Expenses and FDI Inflow to Developing Countries.” Defence and Peace Economics 30 (2): 238–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bak, Daehee, and Lee, Hoon. 2021. “Intrastate Armed Conflict Termination and Foreign Direct Investment.” Foreign Policy Analysis 17 (2): oraa027.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballard, Barclay. 2020. “The Benefits (and Risks) of Investing in Myanmar.” World Finance, 3 February. Accessed on 1 November 2022, https://www.worldfinance.com/special-reports/the-benefits-and-risks-of-investing-in-myanmar.Google Scholar
Barry, Colin M. 2016. “Bringing the company back in: A firm-level analysis of foreign direct investment.” International Interactions 42 (2): 244–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, Colin M., and DiGiuseppe, Matthew. 2019. “Transparency, Risk, and FDI.” Political Research Quarterly 72 (1): 132–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, Colin M., Chad Clay, K., and Flynn, Michael E.. 2013. “Avoiding the Spotlight: Human Rights Shaming and Foreign Direct Investment.” International Studies Quarterly 57 (3): 532–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beazer, Quintin H., and Blake, Daniel J.. 2018. “The Conditional Nature of Political Risk: How Home Institutions Influence the Location of Foreign Direct Investment.” American Journal of Political Science 62 (2): 470–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Shannon Lindsey, and Blanton, Robert G.. 2006. “Human Rights and Foreign Direct Investment: A Two-Stage Analysis.” Business & Society 45 (4): 464–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Shannon Lindsey, and Blanton, Robert G.. 2007. “What Attracts Foreign Investors? An Examination of Human Rights and Foreign Direct Investment.” The Journal of Politics 69 (1): 143–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Shannon Lindsey, and Blanton, Robert G.. 2009. “A Sectoral Analysis of Human Rights and FDI: Does Industry Type Matter?” International Studies Quarterly 53 (2): 469–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomberg, S. Brock, Gregory Hess, and Orphanides, Athanasios. 2004. “The Macroeconomic Consequences of Terrorism.” Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (5): 1007–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bray, John. 2010. “Practice Note 3: Foreign Direct Investment in Conflict-Affected Contexts.” International Alert. Accessed on 7 September 2023, https://www.international-alert.org/publications/foreign-direct-investment-conflict-affected-contexts/.Google Scholar
Brewer, Thomas L. 1993. “Government Policies, Market Imperfections, and Foreign Direct Investment.” Journal of International Business Studies 24: 101–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buhaug, Halvard, Gates, Scott, and Lujala, Päivi. 2009. “Geography, Rebel Capability, and the Duration of Civil Conflict.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 53 (4): 544–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bussmann, Margit. 2010. “Foreign Direct Investment and Militarized International Conflict.” Journal of Peace Research 47 (2): 143–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clague, Christopher, Keefer, Philip, Knack, Stephen, and Olson, Mancur. 1996. “Property and Contract Rights in Autocracies and Democracies.” Journal of Economic Growth 1 (2): 243–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, Kevin A. 2005. “The Phantom Menace: Omitted Variable Bias in Econometric Research.” Conflict Management and Peace Science 22 (4): 341–52.10.1080/07388940500339183CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clayton, Govinda. 2013. “Relative Rebel Strength and the Onset and Outcome of Civil War Mediation.” Journal of Peace Research 50 (5): 609–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coan, Travis G., and Kugler, Tadeusz. 2008. “The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment: An Interactive Framework.” International Interactions 34 (4): 402–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Paul. 1999. “On the Economic Consequences of Civil War.” Oxford Economic Papers 51: 168–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corcos, Gregory, Irac, Delphine M., Mion, Giordano, and Verdier, Thierry. 2013. “The Determinants of Intra-firm Trade: Evidence from French Firms.” Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (3): 825–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cunningham, David E., Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede, and Salehyan, Idean. 2009. “It Takes Two: A Dyadic Analysis of Civil War Duration and Outcome.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 53 (4): 570–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dai, Li, Eden, Lorraine, and Beamish, Paul W.. 2013. “Place, Space, and Geographical Exposure: Foreign Subsidiary Survival in Conflict Zones.” Journal of International Business Studies 44 (6): 554–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drezner, Daniel W., and Hite-Rubin, Nancy F.. 2016. “Does American Military Power Attract Foreign Investment?” In Sustainable Security: Rethinking American National Security Strategy, edited by Suri, Jeremi and Valentino, Benjamin, 5172. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eck, Kristine, and Hultman, Lisa. 2007. “One-Sided Violence against Civilians in War: Insights from New Fatality Data.” Journal of Peace Research 44 (2): 233–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekpenyong, David B., and Umoren, Ntiedo. 2010. “Political Risk and the Business Environment: An Examination of Core Challenges.” Journal of Financial Management & Analysis 23 (1): 2733.Google Scholar
Findley, Michael G., and Young, Joseph K.. 2015. “Terrorism, Spoiling, and the Resolution of Civil Wars.” The Journal of Politics 77 (4): 1115–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fortna, Virginia Page. 2015. “Do Terrorists Win? Rebels’ Use of Terrorism and Civil War Outcomes.” International Organization 69 (3): 519–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gent, Stephen E. 2011. “Relative Rebel Strength and Power Sharing in Intrastate Conflicts.” International Interactions 37 (2): 215–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Globerman, Steven, and Shapiro, Daniel. 2002. “Global Foreign Direct Investment Flows: The Role of Governance Infrastructure.” World Development 30 (11): 1899–919.10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00110-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Globerman, Steven, and Shapiro, Daniel. 2003. “Governance Infrastructure and US Foreign Direct Investment.” Journal of International Business Studies 34 (1): 1939.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goswami, Gour Gobinda, and Haider, Samai. 2014. “Does Political Risk Deter FDI Inflow? An Analytical Approach Using Panel Data and Factor Analysis.” Journal of Economic Studies 41 (2): 233–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guidolin, Massimo, and La Ferrara, Eliana. 2007. “Diamonds Are Forever, Wars Are Not: Is Conflict Bad for Private Firms?” American Economic Review 97 (5): 1978–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hallberg, Johan Dittrich. 2012. “PRIO Conflict Site 1989–2008: A Geo-Referenced Dataset on Armed Conflict.” Conflict Management and Peace Science 29 (2): 219–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbom, Lotta, Melander, Erik, and Wallensteen, Peter. 2008. “Dyadic Dimensions of Armed Conflict, 1946–2007.” Journal of Peace Research 45 (5): 697710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haug, Alfred A., Nguyen, Ahn T. N., and Dorian Owen, P.. 2023. “Do the Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment Have a Reverse and Symmetric Impact on Foreign Direct Divestment?” Empirical Economics 64 (2): 659–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, Witold J. 2017. Corporate Diplomacy: Building Reputations and Relationships with External Stakeholders. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imai, Kosuke, and Weinstein, Jeremy. 2000. “Measuring the Economic Impact of Civil War.” Working Paper No. 51, Center for International Development at Harvard University. Accessed on 7 September 2023, https://imai.fas.harvard.edu/research/files/cid.pdf.Google Scholar
Jensen, Nathan M. 2003. “Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: Political Regimes and Inflows of Foreign Direct Investment.” International Organization 57 (3): 587616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Nathan M. 2008. “Political Risk, Democratic Institutions, and Foreign Direct Investment.” The Journal of Politics 70 (4): 1042–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Nathan M., and Johnston, Noel P.. 2011. “Political Risk, Reputation, and the Resource Curse.” Comparative Political Studies 44 (6): 662–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Nathan M., and Young, Daniel J.. 2008. “A Violent Future? Political Risk Insurance Markets and Violence Forecasts.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 52 (4): 527–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joshi, Madhav, and Quinn, Jason Michael. 2020. “Civil War Termination and Foreign Direct Investment, 1989–2012.” Conflict Management and Peace Science 37 (4): 451–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalyvas, Stathis N. 2006. The Logic of Violence in Civil War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kamin, Katrin. 2022. “Bilateral Trade and Conflict Heterogeneity.” Working Paper No. 2222, Kiel Institute for the World Economy. Accessed on 7 September 2023, https://www.ifw-kiel.de/fileadmin/Dateiverwaltung/IfW-Publications/-ifw/Kiel_Working_Paper/2022/KWP_2222_Bilateral_trade__and_conflict_heterogeneity/KWP_2222.pdf.Google Scholar
Kerner, Andrew. 2014. “What We Talk about When We Talk about Foreign Direct Investment.” International Studies Quarterly 58 (4): 804–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kerner, Andrew, and Lawrence, Jane. 2014. “What's the Risk? Bilateral Investment Treaties, Political Risk and Fixed Capital Accumulation.” British Journal of Political Science 44 (1): 107–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolstad, Ivar, and Wiig, Arne. 2011. “Better the Devil You Know? Chinese Foreign Direct Investment in Africa.” Journal of African Business 12 (1): 3150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreutz, Joakim. 2010. “How and When Armed Conflicts End: Introducing the UCDP Conflict Termination Dataset.” Journal of Peace Research 47 (2): 243–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Chia-yi. 2017. “Terrorism, Counterterrorism Aid, and Foreign Direct Investment.” Foreign Policy Analysis 13 (1): 168–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levis, Mario. 1979. “Does Political Instability in Developing Countries Affect Foreign Investment Flow? An Empirical Examination.” Management International Review 19 (3): 5968.Google Scholar
Lewandowski, James P. 1997. “Risk and Foreign Direct Investment in Emerging Economies: Lessons from the Former Soviet Union.” Middle States Geographer 30: 97104.Google Scholar
Li, Quan. 2006a. “Democracy, Autocracy, and Tax Incentives to Foreign Direct Investors: A Cross-national Analysis.” The Journal of Politics 68 (1): 6274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Quan. 2006b. “Political Violence and Foreign Direct Investment.” In Regional Economic Integration, volume 12, 231–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Quan. 2008. “Foreign Direct Investment and Interstate Military Conflict.” Journal of International Affairs 62 (1): 5366.Google Scholar
Li, Quan. 2009. “Democracy, autocracy, and expropriation of foreign direct investment.” Comparative political studies 42: 1098–127.Google Scholar
Li, Xiaoying, and Liu, Xiaming. 2005. “Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: An Increasingly Endogenous Relationship.” World Development 33 (3): 393407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Quan, and Resnick, Adam. 2003. “Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows to Developing Countries.” International Organization 57 (1): 175211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Chengchun, Murshed, Syed Mansoob, and Tanna, Sailesh. 2017. “The Impact of Civil War on Foreign Direct Investment Flows to Developing Countries.” The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 26 (4): 488507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Long, Scott, and Freese, Jeremy. 2005. Regression Models for Categorical Outcomes Using Stata. 2nd ed. College Station, TX: Stata Press.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. 1990. “Why Doesn't Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?” American Economic Review 80 (2): 9296.Google Scholar
Melton, James, and Ginsburg, Tom. 2014. “Does De Jure Judicial Independence Really Matter?” Journal of Law and Courts 2 (2): 187217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nassour, Abdelkader, Meftah, Saliha, and Mirani, Sajid Hussain. 2020. “Does Political Risk Affect Foreign Direct Investment Inflows? Empirical Evidence from Selected MENA Economies.” Studies of Applied Economics 38 (3): 113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Meghan M., Sooreea, Rajeev, and Gokcek, Gigi. 2016. “The FDI-Political Risk Nexus: Some New Insights.” Journal of Business and Retail Management Research 11 (1): 3141.Google Scholar
Nilsson, Desirée. 2010.“Turning Weakness into Strength: Military Capabilities, Multiple Rebel Groups and Negotiated Settlements.” Conflict Management and Peace Science 27 (3): 253–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norrlof, Carla. 2010. America's Global Advantage: U.S. Hegemony and International Cooperation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nujen, Bella B, Solli-Saether, Hans, Mwesiumo, Deodat, and Hammer, Bianca. 2021. “Reputational risk as a factor in the offshore location choice.” Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management 27 (2):CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osabutey, Ellis L. C., and Okoro, Chris. 2015. “Political Risk and Foreign Direct Investment in Africa: The Case of the Nigerian Telecommunications Industry.” Thunderbird International Business Review 57 (6): 417–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papaioannou, Elias. 2009. “What Drives International Financial Flows? Politics, Institutions and Other Determinants.” Journal of Development Economics 88 (2): 269–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettersson, Therése, and Öberg, Magnus. 2020. “Organized Violence, 1989–2019.” Journal of Peace Research 57 (4): 597613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettersson, Therése, Davies, Shawn, Deniz, Amber, Engström, Garoun, Hawach, Nanar, Högbladh, Stina, and Öberg, Margareta Sollenberg Magnus. 2021. “Organized Violence 1989–2020, with a Special Emphasis on Syria.” Journal of Peace Research 58 (4): 809–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pinto, Pablo M., and Zhu, Boliang. 2016. “Fortune or Evil? The Effect of Inward Foreign Direct Investment on Corruption.” International Studies Quarterly 60 (4): 693705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powers, Matthew, and Choi, Seung-Whan. 2012. “Does Transnational Terrorism Reduce Foreign Direct Investment? Business-Related versus Non-Business-Related Terrorism.” Journal of Peace Research 49 (3): 407–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qian, Xingwang, and Baek, Keonghi. 2011. “An Analysis on Political Risks and the Flow of Foreign Direct Investment in Developing and Industrialized Economies.” Economics, Management, and Financial Markets 6: 6091.Google Scholar
Raleigh, Clionadh, Cunningham, David, Wilhelmsen, Lars, and Gleditsch, Nils Petter. 2006. “Conflict Sites 1946–2005.” UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflicts Dataset 2.Google Scholar
Schneider, Friedrich, and Frey, Bruno S.. 1985. “Economic and Political Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment.” World Development 13 (2): 161–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, David B. 2011. “Corporate Social Responsibility in the Oil and Gas Industry: The Importance of Reputational Risk.” Chicago Kent Law Review 86: 5985.Google Scholar
Staats, Joseph L., and Biglaiser, Glen. 2012. “Foreign Direct Investment in Latin America: The Importance of Judicial Strength and Rule of Law.” International Studies Quarterly 56 (1): 193202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, Jakob. 1998. “Investment, Property Rights and Political Instability: Theory and Evidence.” European Economic Review 42 (7): 1317–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uppsala Conflict Data Program. 2022-03-15. UCDP Conflict Encyclopedia: ucdp.uu.se, Uppsala University.Google Scholar
Vreeland, James Raymond. 2008. “The Effect of Political Regime on Civil War: Unpacking Anocracy.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 52 (3): 401–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walsh, Declan, and Dahir, Abdi Latif. 2022-03-16. “Why Is Ethiopia at War with Itself?.” New York Times.Google Scholar
Wood, Reed M. 2010. “Rebel Capability and Strategic Violence against Civilians.” Journal of Peace Research 47 (5): 601–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank, . 1997. World development report 1997: The state in a changing world. The World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Joseph, and Zhu, Boliang. 2018. “Monopoly Rents and Foreign Direct Investment in Fixed Assets.” International Studies Quarterly 62 (2): 341–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI

Figure 1

Figure 1. Predicted FDI inflows across different levels of relative rebel capabilities.Note: number of cases within parentheses*

Figure 2

Table 2. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (using FDI/GDP)

Figure 3

Table 3. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (using FDI stocks)

Figure 4

Figure 2. Effect of relative rebel strength on FDI inflows.

Figure 5

Figure 3. Effect of relative rebel strength on FDI/GDP.

Figure 6

Figure 4. Effect of relative rebel strength on FDI stocks.

Figure 7

Table 4. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (using PPML estimator)

Figure 8

Table 5. Effect of relative rebel military capabilities on FDI (2SLS model)