Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T18:56:44.488Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Legislator Dissent Does Not Affect Electoral Outcomes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 December 2022

Philip Cowley*
Affiliation:
School of Politics and International Relations, Queen Mary University of London, London, UK
Resul Umit
Affiliation:
School of Government and International Affairs, Durham University, Durham, UK
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Are there electoral consequences or benefits for legislators who deviate from the party line? We answer this question with data from individual-level vote choice and constituency-level electoral results in the UK for the last two decades. Exploring the variations in voting patterns over time with a panel-regression approach, we find results that are most compatible with the null hypothesis, that is, that dissent by legislators is neither rewarded nor punished in elections. These results call into question the degree to which voters know and/or care about legislative dissent in parliament.

Type
Letter
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Based on the existing evidence, one would believe that there might be electoral consequences or benefits for legislators who deviate from the party line. On the one hand, voters dislike parties that appear divided (see, for example, Kam Reference Kam2009; Wolak Reference Wolak2017), and they might therefore punish legislators who cause such divisions. On the other hand, they like independent-minded legislators (see, for example, Crisp et al. Reference Crisp2013; Méndez-Lago and Martínez Reference Méndez-Lago and Martínez2002) and might reward those who dissent instead.

This article tests this common belief with data from the UK, where party discipline has been weakening for the last fifty or so years. Once considered the archetype of party government, recent decades have seen Members of Parliament (MPs) rebel more often, in greater numbers, and with greater effect (Cowley Reference Cowley2002; Cowley Reference Cowley2005; Cowley Reference Cowley, Anthony and Mike2015; Cowley and Norton Reference Cowley and Norton1999; Cowley and Stuart Reference Cowley and Stuart2014; Norton Reference Norton1975; Norton Reference Norton1980). This has included high-profile rebellions on matters of high politics, such as the Iraq war or Britain's membership of the European Union. In line with most findings elsewhere, research finds that British voters prefer MPs who deviate from the party line in this way (Campbell et al. Reference Campbell2019; Johnson and Rosenblatt Reference Johnson and Rosenblatt2007; Wagner, Vivyan and Glinitzer Reference Wagner, Vivyan and Glinitzer2020).

Yet, this work mostly draws on surveys or experiments – and we need to know whether these have external validity. Voters may appear to prefer independent-minded MPs, but this is of less significance if it does not manifest itself in electoral behaviour.

Expecting to detect electoral correlates for the way MPs voted on individual issues is to set an exceptionally high bar. It requires voters to have a stance on an issue and to know their MPs' voting on that issue, and for the two to then be so in conflict or agreement that this one issue changes the way they will vote at the next election. It is therefore perhaps not surprising that attempts to discover such effects find relatively little. Hanretty, Mellon and English (Reference Hanretty, Mellon and English2021) found only extremely limited effects even when examining the way voters reacted to MPs' voting over Brexit, which is about as good a test case as it is possible to imagine (and, moreover, they found that MPs appeared to know they were largely immune from any electoral sanction for their voting). Vivyan and Wagner (Reference Vivyan and Wagner2012) detected only marginal effects when it came to voting over Iraq. Earlier research found only small electoral correlates on a number of high-profile social issues (Pattie, Fieldhouse and Johnston Reference Pattie, Fieldhouse and Johnston1994).

More plausibly, though, voters might acquire a vaguer sense of whether an MP is independent minded or not. This would not require knowledge of specifics about the way an MP has voted, but rather to have picked up on the extent to which they were in lockstep with their party. This still requires some knowledge of an MP's behaviour and for it then to be enough to influence the voter at the ballot box – but the bar here is lower. An MP's voting record would not be the only thing driving this effect, as there are other ways an MP can demonstrate their independence (Campbell et al. Reference Campbell2019), but we might expect their voting record, broadly conceived, to at least constitute a part of how they are perceived by their voters. We know that British voters appear to value independence because they see it as a valence issue, rather than being concerned about the details of the votes themselves (Campbell et al. Reference Campbell2019). There is also evidence that rebels may have a higher profile in their constituencies as a result of their behaviour (Kam Reference Kam2009).

Data and Design

We look for the electoral effects of legislator dissent in the House of Commons on the general elections in the UK, from where much of the existing evidence originates in the first place. Indeed, ‘nearly all studies [on this topic] are conducted in single-member district systems, such as the United States and United Kingdom, which are generally considered most-likely settings for observing such effects’ (Bøggild and Pedersen Reference Bøggild and Pedersen2020, 1). If we find – as we do – that dissent does not affect electoral outcomes in the UK, this poses a significant challenge to such claims.

Our study draws on two datasets. First, we have generated an MP-level panel dataset that covers the period between 1997 and 2019, bringing together observations from: (1) MPs' legislative votes during six parliamentary terms; and (2) their vote share in the elections that follow these terms. Second, we have complemented this with panel survey data on (3) their constituents' electoral behaviour, which limits the beginning of the period to 2010 for the voter-level analysis. All data come from publicly available sources.Footnote 1

We focus on two outcome variables, measuring the support for incumbents at the level of MPs and voters: Vote Share is the proportion of valid votes cast for incumbents; and Vote Choice is whether (1) or not (0) individual constituents vote for incumbents. Our independent variable of interest measures how often an MP, m, votes against the majority of members of their party, p, in a parliamentary term, t:

(1)$$Dissent_{mpt} = \displaystyle{{{\rm \# } \, {\rm votes}\;{\rm cast}\;{\rm against}\;{\rm the}\;{\rm majority}\;{\rm of}\;{\rm party}\;{\rm member}{\rm s}_{mpt}} \over {{\rm \# } \, {\rm votes}\;{\rm held}\;{\rm in}\;{\rm a}\;{\rm parliamentary}\;{\rm ter}{\rm m}_t}}$$

By definition, this design excludes three groups of MPs from the analysis: (1) those who do not run for re-election; (2) those who do not vote (that is, speakers, deputy speakers and absentee MPs from Northern Ireland); and (3) who do not belong to a party (that is, independent MPs). To increase the comparability of our observations, we also exclude MPs whose party affiliation and/or constituency change from one election to the next. All exclusions are specific to a parliamentary term or terms that MPs meet one or more of these criteria.Footnote 2

Most existing studies of backbench dissent in the UK exclude what are called ‘free votes’, that is, those occasions where the party managers (the whips) did not issue instructions to their MPs. This happens on some social issues, various procedural votes and when a party is trying to avoid high-profile splits on other matters. The data utilized here are more inclusive, taking in all votes in the Commons in the periods analysed, both free and whipped.Footnote 3 We think it must be moot whether too many members of the public closely follow the intricacies of party management. While it may matter internally – the whips will look more askance at an MP deviating from the party on a whipped vote – we suspect the public will not pick up on such distinctions. This method also gives us a fuller data source, covering all parties in Parliament for the period examined, whereas published data on dissent (more narrowly conceived) are only available for the government. However, for the record, the two sources of data match closely anyway.Footnote 4

Simple comparisons of electoral outcomes for those who dissent more or less from their party line are likely to be misleading. There might be systematic differences between these two groups of MPs that might affect both legislative dissent and electoral outcomes. For example, senior legislators are more likely to dissent from their party line (Slapin et al. Reference Slapin2018) and they have an increased incumbency advantage in elections (Butler Reference Butler2009). While we can measure and control for seniority, doing so for all potential factors is not credible.

One way to address such concerns is to use linear fixed-effects regressions – limiting the analysis to within-MP and, for individual-level analysis, within-voter comparisons over time. This forms the basis of our identification strategy.Footnote 5

Results

Table 1 presents the main regression models: three for MP-level Vote Share and three for individual-level Vote Choice. In the baseline models without fixed effects (Models 1 and 4), we estimate the results using the pooled data – pooling all observations across time, constituencies, MPs and voters. With this naive approach, we find that the coefficients for Dissent are positive, and in the case of Vote Choice, the effect is relatively large and statistically significant.

Table 1. Effect of dissent on vote share and vote choice

Notes: Standard errors are clustered at the level of MPs. Controls refer to three variables in Vote Share models (Attendance, Majority and Office) and additionally four variables in Vote Choice models (Political Knowledge, Media Consumption, Left–Right Position and Party ID). See the Online Appendix for the complete results (see Table A2) and for further details on the underlying data and variables. *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001.

However, when we limit the analysis to within MPs and within voters, the results change, which indicates that there might be selection bias in our initial estimates. We use fixed effects for the MP–constituency and party–election pairs for Vote Share. In estimating the effect of legislator dissent on Vote Choice, we also include fixed effects for individual voters. Finally, we cluster the standard errors at the level of MPs in all models.

In the models with fixed effects, we find that the coefficients for Dissent are statistically insignificant. These results suggest that, on average, MPs are neither rewarded nor punished electorally following a parliamentary term in which they dissent more from their party line. At the aggregate level, we find no change in vote share as a result of dissent, nor at the individual level do we find constituents becoming more or less likely to vote for them. This does not change with the inclusion of time-variant control variables: Attendance, Majority and Office in Model 3, and, additionally, Political Knowledge, Media Consumption, Left–Right Position and Party ID in Model 6. We describe these variables in the Online Appendix.

Multiverse Analysis

In this section, we report evidence from a multiverse analysis to show that the null results are not sensitive to the coding of the independent variable (Steegen et al. Reference Steegen2016) and/or to the combination of the control variables (Young and Holsteen Reference Young and Holsteen2017). First, we systematically recode Dissent by excluding divisions based on (1) parliamentary- and (2) party-level attendance, and (3) party-level shares of rebellious MPs. Low attendance might indicate low salience or three-way splits (see Footnote 4), while high rebellion might indicate free votes or make individual rebels less noticeable by voters. In one iteration of this process, for example, we disregard rebellion if it occurred in a division where (1) less than 30 per cent of all MPs or (2) 20 per cent of MPs in their own party voted, or (3) more than 10 per cent of MPs in their own party rebelled as well. With ten different percentage thresholds for each of these three variables, we therefore recode Dissent (103) one thousand times to systematically address such concerns.

Then, based on each of these thousand recodings, we re-estimate the fixed-effects models across all (23 + 27 = 136) combinations of possible control variables. Unlike in Table 1, where we report models either with all or without any controls, this process allows us to observe results in between these two extremes. In total, we therefore estimate 136,000 regression models.

Figure 1 plots the t-values associated with the coefficient estimates for Dissent. It shows that the results presented in Table 1 are robust as the t-values are small, and they indicate statistical significance (that is, greater than 1.96 in magnitude) in just 0.17 per cent of the regression models. We consider these false positives, especially because they occur when our underlying data on divisions is reduced to, on average, 10.99 per cent of the sample (s.d. = 1.74; median = 11.78; min = 5.36; max = 11.94). Besides, after estimating this many regression models, we would expect up to 5 per cent false positives.

Figure 1. Distribution of t-values from a multiverse analysis.

Conditional Effects

In this section, we report conditional effects to show that the null results hold across different levels of voter characteristics that could potentially moderate the effect of legislator dissent. How voters react to dissent could depend, for example, on their party identity (Kam Reference Kam2009) or ideological positions (Besch and López-Ortega Reference Besch and López-Ortega2021). We therefore re-estimate Model 6 in Table 1, by adding interaction terms between Dissent and four variables: Political Knowledge, Media Consumption, Left–Right Position and Party ID. We provide these models in Table A3.

Figure 2 plots the relevant estimates with 95 per cent confidence intervals. Most of these estimates are small and the confidence intervals include zero. For example, as we move from voters on the left to those on the right along the ideological spectrum, the best estimate for the effect of Dissent turns from negative to positive, but none of these estimates are statistically significant. In other words, the results remain null under these potentially moderating conditions.

Figure 2. Marginal effect of Dissent on Vote Choice, conditional on various voter characteristics.

Conclusion

Our results therefore do not support the expectation that legislator dissent might have effects on electoral outcomes. We found results that are most compatible with the null hypothesis, that is, that legislator dissent is neither rewarded nor punished in elections. In addition to the analysis reported earlier, we conducted nine further robustness tests, which are detailed in the Online Appendix. Each increased our confidence in these null results.

We did not, of course, ever expect to find especially large electoral effects. Britain remains a party-based democracy. For all that rebellious behaviour has been increasing at Westminster, it remains limited: most votes in the House of Commons still see complete cohesion; most rebellions are small; even the most rebellious MPs vote with their party most of the time; and the government almost always still wins. Most voters will live their lives blissfully unaware of the way their MPs behave and will continue to vote according to national or party factors.Footnote 6 The personal vote of an MP has been growing, but it remains relatively small. The 2019 British Election Study found just one in ten voters saying that they voted for the local candidate rather than national factors. Smith (Reference Smith2013) estimated the personal vote at 1–2 percentage points for Labour and Conservative MPs, if larger for Liberal Democrats, and an MP's voting pattern will only ever constitute a portion of their personal vote, with the rest accounted for by broader constituency service (Cain, Ferejohn and Fiorina Reference Cain, Ferejohn and Fiorina2013).

However, our findings are both statistically and substantively insignificant. Based on the models with control variables, a one within-unit standard deviation increase in Dissent leads to a −0.12 [−0.35 to 0.1] percentage-point decrease in incumbents' vote share and a −0.0016 [−0.02 to 0.02] percentage-point increase in the probability that constituents vote for their incumbent MP. Even at the ends of the 95 per cent confidence intervals in the square brackets, these are negligible effects in UK elections. Of all observations of electoral margins in our analysis, only 1.09 per cent of constituency races were decided by less than 0.35 per cent of the votes.

In sum, we have looked at the most likely case, we have examined both aggregate and individual-level outcomes, we have provided a range of further tests (covering multiverse analysis, conditional effects and a raft of robustness checks), and we have found results that are substantively negligible, in addition to being statistically insignificant. We are therefore left with a puzzle. There is plenty of evidence that MPs are increasingly willing to break ranks and defy their party managers. British voters say they prefer MPs who demonstrate independence and who are willing to deviate from the party line. At the same time, they dislike parties that appear divided. Yet, there is little or no evidence that voters then reward or punish MPs accordingly.

Supplementary Material

Online appendices are available at: https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123422000618

Data Availability Statement

The replication package for this article is available at the BJPolS Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/XI3ACQ

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Mathias Poertner, Jens Wäckerle, David M. Willumsen and the audiences at the 2021 American Political Science Association Annual Meeting, 2021 European Political Science Association Annual Conference and the 6th Conference of the Standing Group on Parliaments for their comments on earlier versions of this article.

Financial Support

None.

Competing Interests

None.

Footnotes

1 The data on MPs' votes come from the Public Whip, which has provided the voting records in the House of Commons since 1997. The constituency-level election results are available from the Electoral Commission. Finally, the survey data come from the British Election Study Internet Panel. For more information on data sources and variables, please see the Online Appendix.

2 In Table A4, we provide a robustness check with data from the latter, purposefully excluded, groups of MPs. The results remain the same. All tables and figures numbered with the prefix ‘A’ are in the Online Appendix.

3 When a party's official line is to abstain, online data sources will not register MPs who are breaking their whip to vote on an issue (either for or against), unless the MPs doing so are themselves divided, with the party splitting three ways (abstain, aye and no). This is usually less of a problem for parties in government, as it is rare for the government to be neutral on an issue, but it can be more of a problem when analysing the behaviour of opposition MPs. As we note in the text, however, the two data sources correlate closely, indicating that this is not a major problem.

4 For example, the correlation between the number of votes cast against the whip by Labour MPs in the 2008–9 session (reported in Cowley and Stuart [Reference Cowley and Stuart2009]) and the total number of times they deviated from the majority position of their party, the data used in this letter, is 0.98. The equivalent correlation for Conservative MPs in the 2012–13 session (based on data in Cowley and Stuart [Reference Cowley and Stuart2013]) is 0.89 (see Figure A3).

5 The ability to identify causal effects with this strategy rests on some strong assumptions (Cunningham Reference Cunningham2021). Particularly relevant for our research design is one such assumption that past electoral outcomes do not affect future legislator dissent (Imai and Kim Reference Imai and Kim2019). We relax this assumption somewhat by controlling for legislators' electoral majority in our estimations.

6 Voting in the House of Commons is transparent – with a high number of roll-call votes, frequently around 200–300 per year, the details of which are public – and it is now increasingly easy to access. Division lists are published online – whereas previously someone would have had to either subscribe to the parliamentary record or go to a library – and harvested by multiple websites to allow voters to check the voting behaviour of MPs. Following high-profile rebellions, it is quite common for lists of MPs who have broken with their party to be published in the media. Still, while this information may be more accessible than in the past, most voters do not spend their time looking up the way their MPs have voted.

References

Besch, J and López-Ortega, A (2021) Do all voters appreciate rebels? Ideology moderates valence benefits from factional dissent. Journal of Legislative Studies, 122.Google Scholar
Bøggild, T and Pedersen, HH (2020) Voter reaction to legislator dissent across political systems. Electoral Studies 68, 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Butler, DM (2009) A regression discontinuity design analysis of the incumbency advantage and tenure in the US House. Electoral Studies 28(1), 123128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cain, B, Ferejohn, JA and Fiorina, MP (2013) The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, R et al. (2019) Legislator dissent as a valence signal. British Journal of Political Science 49(1), 105128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowley, P (2002) Revolts and Rebellions: Parliamentary Voting under Blair. London: Politico's.Google Scholar
Cowley, P (2005) The Rebels: How Blair Mislaid His Majority. London: Politico's.Google Scholar
Cowley, P (2015) The coalition and parliament. In Anthony, S and Mike, F (eds), The Coalition Effect. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 136156.Google Scholar
Cowley, P and Norton, P (1999) Rebels and rebellions: Conservative MPs in the 1992 Parliament. British Journal of Politics & International Relations 1(1), 84105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowley, P and Stuart, M (2009) Dissension amongst the Parliamentary Labour Party, 2008–2009: A Data Handbook. Nottingham: University of Nottingham.Google Scholar
Cowley, P and Stuart, M (2013) Cambo Chained: Dissension amongst the Coalition's Parliamentary Parties, 2012–2013: A Data Handbook. Nottingham: University of Nottingham.Google Scholar
Cowley, P and Stuart, M (2014) In the brown stuff? Labour backbench dissent under Gordon Brown, 2007–10. Contemporary British History 28(1), 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowley, P, Umit, R (2022), “Replication Data for: Legislator Dissent Does Not Affect Electoral Outcomes”, https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/XI3ACQ, Harvard Dataverse, V1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crisp, BF et al. (2013) Vote-earning strategies in flexible list systems: seats at the price of unity. Electoral Studies 32(4), 658669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cunningham, S (2021) Causal Inference: The Mixtape. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hanretty, C, Mellon, J and English, P (2021) Members of parliament are minimally accountable for their issue stances (and they know it). American Political Science Review 115(4), 12751291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imai, K and Kim, IS (2019) When should we use unit fixed effects regression models for causal inference with longitudinal data? American Journal of Political Science 63(2), 467490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, C and Rosenblatt, G (2007) Do MPs have the ‘right stuff’? Parliamentary Affairs 60(1), 164169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kam, CJ (2009) Party Discipline and Parliamentary Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Méndez-Lago, M and Martínez, A (2002) Political representation in Spain: an empirical analysis of the perception of citizens and MPs. Journal of Legislative Studies 8(1), 6390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, P (1975) Dissension in the House of Commons: Intra-party Dissent in the House of Commons’ Division Lobbies 1945–1974. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, P (1980) Dissension in the House of Commons 1974–1979. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pattie, C, Fieldhouse, E and Johnston, RJ (1994) The price of conscience: the electoral correlates and consequences of free votes and rebellions in the British House of Commons, 1987–92. British Journal of Political Science 24(3), 359380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slapin, JB et al. (2018) Ideology, grandstanding, and strategic party disloyalty in the British Parliament. American Political Science Review 112(1), 1530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, TH (2013) Are you sitting comfortably? Estimating incumbency advantage in the UK: 1983–2010. Electoral Studies 32(1), 167173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steegen, S et al. (2016) Increasing transparency through a multiverse analysis. Perspectives on Psychological Science 11(5), 702712.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Vivyan, N and Wagner, M (2012) Do voters reward rebellion? The electoral accountability of MPs in Britain. European Journal of Political Research 51(2), 235264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, M, Vivyan, N and Glinitzer, K (2020) Costly signals: voter responses to parliamentary dissent in Austria, Britain, and Germany. Legislative Studies Quarterly 45(4), 645678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolak, J (2017) Public expectations of state legislators. Legislative Studies Quarterly 42(2), 175209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, C and Holsteen, K (2017) Model uncertainty and robustness: a computational framework for multimodel analysis. Sociological Methods & Research 46(1), 340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Effect of dissent on vote share and vote choice

Figure 1

Figure 1. Distribution of t-values from a multiverse analysis.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Marginal effect of Dissent on Vote Choice, conditional on various voter characteristics.

Supplementary material: Link

Cowley and Umit Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Cowley and Umit supplementary material

Cowley and Umit supplementary material

Download Cowley and Umit supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 503.8 KB