Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T09:48:37.591Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Electoral Distortion under STV Random Sampling Procedures: A Comment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Extract

In a recent Note in this Journal by Gallagher and Unwin, it was stated that the element of randomness due to sampling surplus votes in single transferable vote (STV) elections ‘has long been recognized, but no previous attempt has been made to assess its impact’. This is incorrect. Work done in Australia (and reported in the leading Australian journals in their respective fields) has comprehensively dealt with this problem both in theory and practice. Since STV is practised in national elections in only three countries (Australia, Ireland and Malta, the most populous being Australia) it is surprising that contributors to, and referees of, this Journal should be unaware of such material. It was largely because of the evidence contained in these articles that the Joint Committee on Electoral Reform recommended to the Australian Parliament an amendment to the Electoral Act, to avoid the problems caused by sampling votes, by using the Gregory method of counting them. The Act was amended in this way in 1983.

Type
Notes and Comments
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1988

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Gallagher, Michael and Unwin, A. R., ‘Electoral Distortion under STV Random Sampling Procedures’, British Journal of Political Science, 16 (1986), 243–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 Fischer, A. J., ‘Sampling Errors in the Electoral Process for the Australian Senate’, Australian Journal of Statistics, 20 (1980), 2439CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Fischer, A. J., ‘Aspects of the Voting System for the Senate’, Politics, 16 (1981), 5762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Fischer, , ‘Sampling Errors in the Electoral Process’, p. 36.Google Scholar

4 K. J. Arrow has shown that given only a few, fairly weak anxioms to describe the social choice process, no voting mechanism exists that will satisfy them under all circumstances. See Arrow, K. J., Social Choice and Individual Values (New York: Wiley, 1951; revised 1963).Google Scholar

5 Gibbard, A.Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result’, Econometrica, 41 (1973), 587602CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Satterthwaite, M. A.Strategy-Proofness and Arrow's Conditions: Existence and Correspondence Theorems for Voting Procedures and Social Welfare Functions’, Journal of Economic Theory, 10 (1975), 187217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar These theorems state that even in voting systems exhibiting monotonicity, there will always be occasions when some voters will gain more desirable outcomes by misrepresenting their preferences or intensity of preferences. The effect of the Arrow and Gibbard-Satterthwaite theorems is that we cannot hope to find a voting system which will have no undesirable properties. We must therefore make judgements about the relative importance of different violations of desirable properties by different voting systems. Not only is the lack of monotonicity likely to cause relatively minor distortions in STV, it is relatively insignificant compared with the extent to which strategic voting may occur in alternative systems of voting.