Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T00:03:19.566Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Effects of Import Shocks, Electoral Institutions, and Radical Party Competition on Legislator Ideology: Evidence from France

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 January 2024

Anna M. Meyerrose*
Affiliation:
School of Politics and Global Studies, Arizona State University, Tempe, AZ, USA
Sara Watson
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Ohio State University, Columbus, OH, USA
*
Corresponding author: Anna M. Meyerrose; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Across advanced industrialized democracies, the political centre is collapsing as politicians on the far right and far left enjoy increasing electoral success. Recent research links import shocks to voter support for far-right parties. However, we know comparatively less about how these shocks impact individual legislator ideology, especially that of mainstream politicians. Do import shocks drive economic or cultural ideological shifts among mainstream legislators? If so, to what extent do local competitive contexts shape these shifts? Using a dataset of French Senate roll call votes, we find that localized increases in import exposure moves elite ideology to the left economically; this is magnified in departments with majoritarian electoral systems. We show that legislators shift their cultural positions in response to import shocks, but only when faced with extremist political competitors focused on cultural issues. Our results suggest the value of attending to how political and economic geography intersect to shape elite policy positions.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Introduction

Across advanced democracies, as electorates increasingly opt for populist candidates, the political centre is collapsing. The National Rally in France, the Alternative for Germany, and the Brothers of Italy are among the ever-growing list of right-wing nationalist parties gaining support throughout Europe. At the same time, the voting base of the traditional social democratic left is being bled by radical left competitors such as the France Insoumise and the Left Bloc in Portugal.

Research identifies dimensions of globalization, and localized import shocks in particular, as key determinants of support for populists and rising societal polarization (Autor et al. Reference Autor2020; Ballard-Rosa, Jensen, and Scheve Reference Ballard-Rosa, Jensen and Scheve2021; Milner Reference Milner2021) as voters in regions with import influxes increasingly turn to extremist candidates who overwhelmingly emphasize cultural issues (Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Margalit Reference Margalit2011). While there is extensive research on demand-side responses to trade on the cultural dimension and work investigating the effects of public opinion on legislator preferences (Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Dippel, Gold, and Heblich Reference Dippel, Gold and Heblich2015; Gingrich Reference Gingrich2017; Guisinger Reference Guisinger2009; Milner and Tingley Reference Milner and Tingley2011), we know comparatively less about how import shocks affect politicians (Rodrik Reference Rodrik2021; Rommel and Walter Reference Rommel and Walter2018), and how they respond to the concurrent emergence of extremist party competition (Abou-Chadi and Krause Reference Abou-Chadi and Krause2020; Spoon and Williams Reference Spoon and Williams2021).

Work on legislative responses to trade is characterized by convergent findings, disagreement, and even silence on key questions. On the one hand, scholars agree that localized import shocks increase negative views about trade and specific trading partners as well as support for protectionism (Campello and Urdinez Reference Campello and Urdinez2021; Kleinberg and Fordham Reference Kleinberg and Fordham2013; Kuk, Seligsohn, and Zhang Reference Kuk, Seligsohn and Zhang2018) and that these effects are stronger among politicians in competitive electoral districts (Feigenbaum and Hall Reference Feigenbaum and Hall2015), suggesting electoral incentives also influence legislator ideology. However, scholars disagree about whether trade impacts elite ideology beyond the narrow scope of trade policy (Autor et al. Reference Autor2020; Feigenbaum and Hall Reference Feigenbaum and Hall2015). While trade is one important dimension of economic policy, import shocks also make salient more general economic ideological concerns related to compensation and redistribution. At the same time, an exclusive focus on legislators' economic ideology stands in tension with extensive literature suggesting that trade is closely tied to cultural ideological issues. However, perhaps because the vast majority of studies on legislator responses emerge from the US setting, there have been few efforts to explore how different types of competitive and institutional contexts refract trade-induced dislocations. This is despite general agreement that institutional and competitive contexts should incentivize legislators to respond to economic shocks in distinct ways (Rickard Reference Rickard2018).

This paper asks: do import shocks lead to economic and/or cultural ideological shifts among mainstream legislators? Import shocks are highly localized events that impact some regions of a country while leaving others largely untouched. When representing regions hard hit by imports, mainstream legislators, whose ideology focuses primarily on economic issues, face incentives to shift economically to the left to reflect increased demands for redistribution and compensation (Ruggie Reference Ruggie1982; Scheve and Serlin Reference Scheve and Serlin2023). However, local competitive contexts – in the form of varying electoral institutionsFootnote 1 and the extent of competition from extremist candidates on both the far right and the far left – should mediate these economic and ideological shifts and, in some cases, force mainstream politicians to adapt their cultural ideology to accommodate the core ideological appeals of their extremist competitors (Meguid Reference Meguid2005). In other words, we argue the effects of import shocks on legislator ideology are contingent on the competitive and institutional contexts in which they operate.

Using an original hand coded dataset of roll call votes from the French Senate, we present three findings of note. First, in line with existing work, we show that localized increases in import exposure drive elite shifts to the left on the economic ideological dimension. Second, these effects are magnified in competitive majoritarian electoral systems. Finally, we find that local variation in radical party strength mediates the effects of import shocks on legislator ideology: a strong radical left presence pulls left-leaning mainstream politicians to the left on both economic and cultural issues, with similar dynamics present on the right. Taken together, our findings contribute to scholarship on the domestic consequences of trade by showing the value of attending to how international forces intersect with localized patterns of political competition to shape the economic and cultural ideologies of elected officials. We also contribute to research on how radical party strength shapes mainstream political actors’ behaviour and policy positions.

The Domestic Consequences of Import Shocks

In recent decades, advanced industrialized countries (AICs) have experienced a tremendous increase in trade, labour flows, and finance internationalization. In the aggregate, economic openness can generate significant welfare gains, including overall improvements to industrial productivity (Melitz Reference Melitz2003), higher wages for workers in productive exporting firms (Helpman, Itskhoki, and Redding Reference Helpman, Itskhoki and Redding2010), employment opportunities for workers that sell their services to foreign customers (Hummels et al. Reference Hummels2014), and consumer access to less costly products (Costinot and Rodríguez-Clare Reference Costinot, Rodríguez-Clare, Gopinath, Helpman and Rogoff2014). However, one specific aspect of economic globalization – sudden, concentrated increases in imports from low-wage countries – carries significant costs for the affected populations in AICs.

Import shocks, which are regionally concentrated, have, over the past twenty years, led to job losses in traditional industries and put substantial downward pressure on wages (Balsvik, Sissel, and Salvanes Reference Balsvik, Sissel and Salvanes2015; Dauth, Findeisen, and Suedekum Reference Dauth, Findeisen and Suedekum2014; Donoso et al. Reference Donoso2014; Malgouyres Reference Malgouyres2017b). Import flows impact not just workers but also all residents of exposed regions who are concerned about long-term economic decline (Rickard Reference Rickard2022) regardless of their own employment status (Mansfield and Mutz Reference Mansfield and Mutz2009). In these regions, the detrimental effects of imports significantly outweigh the overall gains from trade (Rodrik Reference Rodrik2011), and residents in these areas are more likely to emphasize the negative consequences of globalization (Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006). In regions where import competition from low-wage countries is higher, research shows that, on both sides of the Atlantic, voters gravitate toward radical candidates and parties (Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Dippel, Gold, and Heblich Reference Dippel, Gold and Heblich2015; Gingrich Reference Gingrich2017; Malgouyres Reference Malgouyres2014; Milner Reference Milner2021).

Building on this voter-centered work, we ask how legislators representing these regions – and legislators from non-extremist parties, in particular – have changed their policy positions in response to these import-induced dislocations. There is little consensus on how or even whether import shocks affect legislators' ideology (Autor et al. Reference Autor2020; Butler and Nickerson Reference Butler and Nickerson2011; Karol Reference Karol2007; Kleinberg and Fordham Reference Kleinberg and Fordham2013; Kuk, Seligsohn, and Zhang Reference Kuk, Seligsohn and Zhang2018). On the one hand, there is some evidence that voters' interests around trade only marginally impact how members of the US Congress vote on legislation (Fordham and McKeown Reference Fordham and McKeown2003; Guisinger Reference Guisinger2009; Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006). Other US studies find local dynamics impact legislative votes, but even here there is disagreement about the scope of these effects. While Feigenbaum and Hall (Reference Feigenbaum and Hall2015) find trade shocks cause legislators representing affected regions to vote in a more protectionist direction on trade bills alone, Autor et al. (Reference Autor2020) show evidence of a more generalized polarized ideological response.

Interestingly, most research on legislative responses to trade shocks draws on data from the US.Footnote 2 What is more, all studies of legislative responses to import shocks of which we are aware analyze a single economic ideological dimension of politics. This economic focus, however, sits in tension with work on how European voters react to trade and globalization. This important literature suggests that rapid import penetration should impact both the economic and cultural dimensions of politics.Footnote 3 The centrality of the American case has also limited our understanding of scope conditions since key institutional features of the American polity – a two-party system generated by single-member district electoral rules – are not representative of many other advanced democracies that have been similarly exposed to import shocks.

We advance work on trade and elite ideology by examining the political dynamics of local labour market disruptions in a case outside of the US – France. Like other advanced democracies, France has experienced a dramatic increase in trade from low-wage countries since the early 2000s. Moreover, in contrast to the US, France has a polarized, multi-party system and utilizes a range of electoral systems. These features of the French context enable us to answer important questions about how mainstream political elites respond ideologically to import shocks and how these responses are mediated by electoral institutions and the growing presence of extremist political challengers.

Import Shocks, Local Electoral Context, and Legislator Ideology

Politics in Western democracies takes place along two distinct ideological dimensions: the traditional economic divide and an increasingly salient cultural dimension that focuses on social issues such as gender equality, immigration, and European integration (Caughey, O'Grady, and Warshaw Reference Caughey, O'Grady and Warshaw2019; Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2018).Footnote 4 As illustrated in Fig. 1, we distinguish between the economic left and right and use similar terminology for the second dimension, where the cultural right is characterized by anti-immigrant sentiment, authoritarian attitudes, and nationalism, while the cultural left is more multicultural, libertarian, and (internationally) cosmopolitan (Volkens et al. Reference Volkens2020).

Figure 1. Politics in Western democracies takes place along two distinct ideological dimensions: the economic dimension and the cultural one.

In multiparty systems, parties differ with respect to their policy platforms and the relative emphasis they place on economic versus cultural issues, understood in general terms and in response to challenges created by globalization (Haupt Reference Haupt2010). Established mainstream parties on both the left and right focus predominantly on economic ideological issues (Rommel and Walter Reference Rommel and Walter2018) around which these parties were originally formed. While the left emphasizes policies to strengthen the welfare state and expand redistribution, the mainstream right advocates market-oriented policies, decreased government spending, and lower taxes (Allan and Scruggs Reference Allan and Scruggs2004; Benoit and Laver Reference Benoit and Laver2007; Schmidt Reference Schmidt, Castles, Leibfried, Lewis, Obinger and Pierson2010).

The newer niche parties, such as the radical right and the Green parties, tend to reject this class-based orientation of politics, focusing instead on post-materialist issues such as nationalism, immigration, the environment, or regional autonomy (Meguid Reference Meguid2005). Because these parties define themselves primarily along that second cultural dimension, their economic policy positions are often ambiguous; this is especially the case with the far-right (Ennser-Jedenastik Reference Ennser-Jedenastik2022; Rovny Reference Rovny2013). To the extent they adopt economic positions, these parties were, historically, on the economic right (Kitschelt and McGann Reference Kitschelt and McGann1995; Kriesi et al. Reference Kriesi2012; Minkenberg Reference Minkenberg2000), but, over time, they have shifted toward the left, adopting a ‘welfare chauvinist’ platform that advocates increased social protections for natives while excluding immigrants and other non-nationals (Betz and Meret Reference Betz and Meret2012; Lefkofridi and Michel Reference Lefkofridi and Michel2014).

Economic Ideology and the Mediating Role of Electoral Institutions

We draw on existing research on domestic responses to economic globalization to derive clear predictions regarding the ideological shifts of mainstream legislators representing regions hard hit by import shocks. Given that politicians from mainstream parties focus primarily on economic issues and building on work showing legislators respond to trade influxes along the economic dimension (Autor et al. Reference Autor2020; Campello and Urdinez Reference Campello and Urdinez2021; Feigenbaum and Hall Reference Feigenbaum and Hall2015), we expect that, all else being equal, non-extremist political elites' responses to trade shocks will be reflected primarily in economic ideological shifts. There are two economic policy mechanisms available to legislators to address the dislocations created by import shocks: legislators can advocate expanding compensation and/or greater protectionism. While the literature has increasingly argued that both voters (Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018) and (non-European) legislators (Campello and Urdinez Reference Campello and Urdinez2021; Feigenbaum and Hall Reference Feigenbaum and Hall2015) are likely to favour protectionism in response to trade shocks, in the European context, legislators' economic policy responses are more limited. For all European Union (EU) member states, decisions about trade policy are made at the EU level, with the EU Commissioner for Trade acting on behalf of all member states (Nanou and Dorussen Reference Nanou and Dorussen2013). Legislators in EU member states thus have limited influence over trade policy and cannot credibly promise to introduce protectionist measures since voters in these countries are aware politicians' hands are tied on these issues (Hellwig Reference Hellwig2014; Meyerrose Reference Meyerrose2020, Reference Meyerrose2023). Therefore, we expect them to favour compensation- and redistribution-oriented policy solutions to the dislocations created by import shocks.

Localized import penetration increases economic and employment volatility, which in turn makes voters more likely to demand increased government spending to compensate for these economic dislocations (Rodrik Reference Rodrik1998; Ruggie Reference Ruggie1982). These demands for compensation make voters more likely to support left-leaning politicians and parties that advocate welfare state expansion and redistribution. Indeed, there is evidence that the economic insecurities created by import shocks have driven affected voters to favour compensatory policies associated with traditional parties on the left (Rommel and Walter Reference Rommel and Walter2018; Scheve and Serlin Reference Scheve and Serlin2023) and left-wing parties and candidates that universally reject neoliberalism, consumerism, and globalized capitalism have become increasingly electorally successful (Bale and Dunphy Reference Bale and Dunphy2011; Hopkin Reference Hopkin2020). This, in turn, has led to greater government spending (Dreher, Sturm, and Ursprung Reference Dreher, Sturm and Ursprung2008; Garrett Reference Garrett1998; Rodrik Reference Rodrik1998) and an expansion of redistributive policies (Bergh and Nilsson Reference Bergh and Nilsson2010; Leibrecht, Klien, and Onaran Reference Leibrecht, Klien and Onaran2011; Meinhard and Potrafke Reference Meinhard and Potrafke2012).

While import shocks directly impact employment outcomes for only a subset of workers within affected regions, the effects of these shocks on voters' economic preferences extend beyond the individual level. Localized trade shocks can trigger sociotropic considerations that influence not just the economic policy preferences of impacted workers but also the preference of all voters in these regions who are concerned with the economic well-being of their community (Rickard Reference Rickard2022). Indeed, there is evidence that awareness of rising unemployment leads many voters in a region, regardless of their employment status, to hold the government accountable for their locality's shifting economic landscape (Mansfield and Mutz Reference Mansfield and Mutz2009). This, in turn, creates incentives for legislators representing these areas to shift their economic ideological position. Therefore, our baseline prediction is:

Hypothesis 1: Legislators representing regions exposed to import shocks will shift to the left along the economic ideological dimension.

Where institutions increase incentives for elected officials to be responsive to local demands, the effect of import shocks on legislator ideology should be magnified. Research shows one type of institution in particular – the electoral system – creates distinct incentives for how politicians respond to local economic conditions (Breunig, Grossman, and Hänni Reference Breunig, Grossman and Hänni2022; Chang et al. Reference Chang2010; Katz Reference Katz1997; Shugart and Taagepera Reference Shugart and Taagepera1989; Taagepera Reference Taagepera1973). Since Duverger (Reference Duverger1954), political scientists have highlighted how electoral systems can induce changes in elite ideology through their mechanical effects on vote-seat elasticities. In majoritarian systems, small vote swings can dramatically distort the relationship between votes and seat shares (Rogowski and Kayser Reference Rogowski and Kayser2002). Because identical vote distributions are often translated into different seat allocations, depending on the electoral system, in majoritarian systems (where small vote swings can dramatically distort the relationship between vote and seat shares), alienating voters by failing to offer policies that address the negative effects of import shocks entails a higher risk for politicians (Wlezien and Soroka Reference Wlezien and Soroka2012).

Existing work suggests another channel through which majoritarianism promotes greater responsiveness: the fact that candidates in majoritarian districts can campaign, at least to some extent, on personal characteristics and are thus less dependent on their party for re-election (Carey Reference Carey2007; Carey and Shugart Reference Carey and Shugart1995; Katz Reference Katz1997; Mitchell Reference Mitchell2000). In districts where the incumbency advantage plays a more pivotal role (Hainmueller and Kern Reference Hainmueller and Kern2008), we similarly expect legislators to face greater incentives to respond to trade-generated dislocations, irrespective of the position taken by their political party (Sieberer Reference Sieberer2010).

Although majoritarian electoral systems create incentives for greater elite economic ideological shifts in regions hard hit by imports, the literature also suggests the extent to which these electoral incentives influence politicians' strategies is contingent on the competitiveness of the election. According to the ‘marginality hypothesis’, legislators elected by narrower margins (for example, those in more competitive districts) will be more attentive to voter demands due to the possibility of voter backlash. Indeed, focusing on legislative responses to trade, Feigenbaum and Hall (Reference Feigenbaum and Hall2015) find that US legislators in competitive electoral districts shift their ideology. Drawing on this research, we predict the following:

Hypothesis 2: Legislators from regions exposed to import shocks who are elected via majoritarian rules will shift further to the left along the economic ideological dimension than legislators in proportional representation (PR) systems. These effects should be stronger in the case of competitive majoritarian elections.

While the literature offers clear expectations of how mainstream legislators will respond economically to trade shocks, the extent to which these legislators shift their ideological position with respect to the second cultural dimension is contingent on the political competition they face. We argue that mainstream legislators will be more likely to adjust their cultural positions in response to trade influxes when they face electoral competition from extremist competitors who, as noted above, define themselves primarily with respect to cultural issues rather than economic ones. Absent competitors that make this second dimension salient, legislators will prefer to focus on the economic policy issues central to their political identity.

Incorporating Cultural Ideology: The Role of Extremist Challengers

In representative democracies, elections create incentives for politicians to adjust their ideological positions. However, the nature and context of these elections also influence these incentives. In addition to electoral institutions and the competitiveness of a constituency, the type of competition politicians face should also shape responses to rising import competition (Watson Reference Watson2015). As extremist parties grow in popular support and, as a result, increase the salience of cultural issues, they pose a direct electoral challenge to mainstream politicians. Indeed, research finds that, when threatened electorally, traditional parties may opt for an accommodative approach wherein they shift their cultural ideology to more closely match that of their extremist competitors in the hopes of drawing in or winning back voters (Meguid Reference Meguid2005). In a direct test of these dynamics, Abou-Chadi and Krause (Reference Abou-Chadi and Krause2020) find mainstream parties are more likely to emphasize anti-immigration positions when the populist radical right received higher vote shares in the previous election.

While work on mainstream party responses to extremists focuses primarily on the far right, the rise of the far left in Europe in recent years suggests a strong radical left presence might similarly influence mainstream elites' policy positions. Building on previous findings to consider individual legislators (rather than parties), we expect mainstream legislators will adopt accommodative strategies when confronted with electoral threats from the far right and the far left. However, the types of threats posed by radical left and right competitors are somewhat distinct.

Populist radical right politicians primarily emphasize second-dimension cultural issues such as immigration. Their stances resonate with working-class voters experiencing significant economic hardship because of globalization, particularly in areas hit hardest by trade (Dippel, Gold, and Heblich Reference Dippel, Gold and Heblich2015; Malgouyres Reference Malgouyres2014). Given the electoral salience of immigration, politicians across the political spectrum have increasingly advocated anti-immigrant policies to win votes and compete with the far right (Abou-Chadi Reference Abou-Chadi2016; Abou-Chadi and Krause Reference Abou-Chadi and Krause2020; Meguid Reference Meguid2005; Schain Reference Schain, Schain, Zolberg and Hossay2002; Spoon and Klüver Reference Spoon and Klüver2020; van Spanje Reference van Spanje2010). Therefore, we predict the following:

Hypothesis 3: Mainstream legislators in districts with strong far-right competitors will shift to the right on the cultural ideological dimension in response to import shocks.

While the far right defines itself primarily with respect to cultural issues, the far left is more ideologically complex. In Europe, the far left is comprised of both post-materialist niche parties, such as the Greens, who focus primarily on second-dimension issues, and materialist radical-left parties, such as the Communists, who define themselves predominantly with respect to economic topics. Despite having distinct ideological foundations, both far-left parties compete for left-wing voters who have become disenchanted with the mainstream left. In times of economic prosperity, the Greens emphasize their core environmental issues. However, during times of economic hardship – such as those that result from import shocks – Communists are particularly successful in attracting voters sympathetic to their economic platforms. In these contexts of economic decline, Green parties shift to emphasizing economic issues to compete with the materialist-oriented far left and attract additional left-leaning voters (Spoon and Williams Reference Spoon and Williams2021). Therefore, while we expect far-right competitors to impact a mainstream legislator's cultural ideological position, we anticipate individual politicians from mainstream parties will shift to the left on both the economic and cultural dimensions when confronted with a strong, far-left challenger.Footnote 5 Formally:

Hypothesis 4: Mainstream legislators in districts with strong far-left competitors will shift to the left on both the economic and cultural ideological dimensions in response to import shocks.

Finally, we also evaluate the possibility of differential responses to competitive contexts across partisan identities. Changing ideologies is politically risky for any politician, as it can signal a weak commitment to core principles. Mainstream politicians should only accommodate these extremist positions if they face real and immediate electoral threats; they should be particularly likely to accommodate policy positions closer to their core ideological foundations (Han Reference Han2015). Therefore, we expect leftist politicians will be more responsive to a far-left challenger than their mainstream right-wing counterparts, while right-leaning politicians will be more vulnerable to challenges from the far right and respond accordingly. In other words, we predict:

Hypothesis 5: Right-wing mainstream politicians will be more responsive to a far-right challenger than their left-wing counterparts.

Hypothesis 6: Leftist mainstream politicians will be more responsive to a far-left challenger than their right-wing counterparts.

To summarize, we predict that, on their own, import shocks will make mainstream legislators more likely to shift their economic ideology to the left, reflecting considerations surrounding redistribution and compensation. However, the competitive context in which these legislators operate should also impact the relationship between import shocks and ideology. First, since majoritarian electoral institutions create incentives for greater responsiveness than PR systems, we expect that legislators elected under majoritarian rules will be particularly likely to shift their economic ideology to the left; this should especially be the case in competitive majoritarian systems. Second, we predict mainstream legislators' ideological shifts in response to import shocks will be influenced by competition from extremist competitors. Specifically, we expect competition from the far right will pull legislators in trade-affected regions to the right on the cultural dimensions, while competition from the far left will induce further shifts to the left on both economic and cultural issues. Right-wing politicians will be particularly responsive to far-right challenges, while left-wing candidates will be more susceptible to challenges from the far left. These predictions are summarized in Table 1.

Table 1. Summary of Predictions

In testing these hypothesized relationships between import shocks, local competitive context, and legislator ideology, it is important to consider the potential mechanisms driving any observed ideological shifts. On the one hand, movements in legislative ideology could be driven by the election of new legislators that are further to the left/right than their predecessor (‘replacement’). Indeed, a substantial literature in political economy finds that economic downturns disadvantage incumbent politicians (Brooks and Brady Reference Brooks and Brady1999; Lewis-Beck and Paldam Reference Lewis-Beck and Paldam2000), as voters punish incumbents at the polls for the adverse economic outcomes, including those caused by greater trade exposure (Jensen, Quinn, and Weymouth Reference Jensen, Quinn and Weymouth2017; Margalit Reference Margalit2011; Reference Margalit2013). There could also be a selection mechanism at work, as competition for votes induces incumbent politicians in trade-exposed districts to strategically shift their ideological stances in response to changing voter preferences (‘realignment’). Below, we test the extent to which our results are driven by realignment or replacement dynamics.

The French Senate as a Lens for Studying Legislative Behaviour

We study the dynamics of trade influxes and elite politics in the context of the French Senate. Like many other advanced industrialized countries, France experienced a dramatic increase in imports from low-wage economies beginning in the mid-1990s, and especially from China after it entered into the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001, leading to substantial local-level disruptions to both employment and wages (Malgouyres Reference Malgouyres2014). Moreover, France has one of the most polarized electorates in Europe, making it an ideal context for exploring how the electoral success of extremist parties impacts individual legislators' ideological positions. Indeed, both the far right and the far left are prominent in French politics, though with significant subnational variations. This allows us to explore how local political geography intersects with trade-generated dislocations to influence the ideology of non-extremist legislators.

The under-studied French Senate also offers a particularly useful setting for exploring how democratic linkages influence elite behaviour. Unlike most legislatures, the Senate employs multiple electoral systems simultaneously, thereby allowing us to test the varying effects of electoral system type on legislator ideology within a single case.Footnote 6 Some French senators are elected via majoritarian rules, others by proportional representation. Approximately two-thirds of senators were elected via majoritarian methods in the period under examination here.Footnote 7

French senators are indirectly elected by a 150,000-member electoral college composed of locally-elected officials. Although indirectly elected, important institutional reasons exist to expect these senators to respond to the local concerns of voters. Until 2017, French senators were permitted to hold ‘dual mandates’ wherein they simultaneously served in the legislature while also holding directly elected local political offices.Footnote 8 Research suggests legislators holding dual mandates have strong incentives to represent local interests (Bach et al. Reference Bach2012; Costa and Kerrouche Reference Costa and Kerrouche2009; Page and Goldsmith Reference Page and Goldsmith2016) and are more likely to feel connected to local grievances (Van de Voorde and de Vet Reference Van de Voorde and de Vet2020).Footnote 9 Concerns with the consequences of globalization, driven by senators' strong local ties, are encapsulated in the words of former senator, Francis Grignon:

Offshoring, deindustrialization, globalization … the decline of France, the economic take-off of China … As senators, the constitutional representatives of the territories who are in many instances also holders of local mandates, we are frequently confronted with the economic difficulties and the human tragedies resulting from the closing of a factory. We know the collective price, the social and economic cost: disarray of families hit by unemployment, immediate effects on the local production of trade and crafts, even industrial subcontractors … dangerous imbalances to which the entire community suddenly finds itself exposed’ (Grignon Reference Grignon2004).

Senators' worries about the consequences of import shocks are reflected in their legislative activity. Following China's accession to the WTO, in 2004 the French Senate created a working group on labour dislocations, holding some fifty hearings (Arthuis Reference Arthuis2005). That year, the Senate's Committee on Economic Affairs produced a 300-page report roundly criticizing liberal responses to France's employment crisis, advocating instead for a neo-Colberiste strategy in which the EU would coordinate a continent-wide industrial policy (Grignon Reference Grignon2004). The Senate Finance Committee subsequently released a report proposing tax strategies to assist beleaguered firms facing intensified global competition – a theme that remained relevant nearly a decade later.Footnote 10

In short, we have theoretical and empirical reasons to believe that French senators should be responsive to local-level labour market developments. Nevertheless, the indirect nature of Senate elections constitutes a hard test for the claim that import competition drives legislative ideological shifts. If we find effects here, they should be even more evident in legislatures where politicians are directly elected.

Measures and Empirical Approach

Dependent Variable: Ideology of French Legislators

We use a spatial model to capture ideological shifts among French senators. Applications of spatial models are extensive in the US Congress (Poole and Rosenthal Reference Poole and Rosenthal1985) but have also been applied in legislatures with more than two political parties (Hix and Noury Reference Hix and Noury2009; Meyerrose Reference Meyerrose2018).Footnote 11 However, only a subset of these models allows for the intertemporal comparisons of ideology needed to test our argument regarding shifts in legislative positions over time in response to import shocks. We use a Bayesian dynamic item response (IRT) model to measure senators' ideological changes. The dynamic IRT model, developed by Martin and Quinn (Reference Martin and Quinn2002), is a more flexible alternative to DW-NOMINATE, another intertemporal spatial model (Poole and Rosenthal Reference Poole and Rosenthal2001). The dynamic IRT model allows individuals' ideologies to change non-monotonically across legislative sessions (Clinton, Jackman, and Rivers Reference Clinton, Jackman and Rivers2004) and produces more precise point estimates than DW-NOMINATE.

Like American senators, not all French senators are elected simultaneously. American politics scholars count each two-year congressional session as a legislative session for the US Senate; we follow a similar strategy. Because French parliamentary sessions only last nine months, we divide the French Senate into sessions coinciding with periods between elections (three years).Footnote 12 We assign a session ID to each three-year period between the Senate elections during the Fifth Republic. Our sample includes voting data from seven sessions: 13 (1996–1998) through 19 (2014–2017).

To estimate the dynamic IRT model, we scraped and cleaned information on public roll call votes for all but two of the Senate sessions between 1996 and 2017.Footnote 13 The result is a dataset of 3,589 roll call votes with information on how each senator voted on a given bill and a text-based description of each bill's content.

We predict mainstream legislators representing import-exposed departments will be more likely to shift their economic ideological position to the left and, depending on their local context and partisan attachment, their cultural position to either the left or the right.Footnote 14 We estimate legislators’ ideological positions on a subset of relevant roll call votes to ensure we capture shifts in the economic and cultural dimensions. Drawing on the economic and cultural categories identified in the Comparative Manifesto Project (Volkens et al. Reference Volkens2020), we use the text descriptions to hand code each of the 3,589 bills as either economic, cultural, or neither.Footnote 15 The result is two mutually exclusive sets of roll call votes: 2,227 economic and 613 cultural.

We validate our hand coding using the Comparative Agendas Project data (Baumgartner et al. Reference Baumgartner, Breunig and Grossman2019), which codes a subset of the bills in our dataset by topic.Footnote 16 Since we identify relatively few cultural bills, we adopt a model-based approach to validate our codings further. DW-NOMINATE models allow the researcher to define the number of ideological dimensions ex-ante and then use patterns in the data to place legislators along the specified number of dimensions. We estimate a DW-NOMINATE model along two dimensions for the French Senate, finding that the first dimension alone correctly classifies about 95 percent of all roll call votes in our dataset. Although somewhat surprising, this gives us further confidence that our codings, which are heavily skewed toward economic bills, are accurate.

To estimate ideological positions in the French Senate, we apply an approximation of the dynamic IRT model using the emIRT package in R (Imai, Lo, and Olmsted Reference Imai, Lo and Olmsted2016).Footnote 17 In preparing the data, we follow conventional practices and exclude individual roll call votes for which the vote was either 97.5 percent for or against. We also remove legislators who did not vote at least twenty-five times within a given parliamentary session.Footnote 18 Finally, given the French Senate's strict legislative voting rules, our view is that abstentions essentially equate to ‘nay’ votes in this context and we code them as such.Footnote 19

The dynamic IRT model requires the modeler to specify a set of prior distributions. We set priors based on a legislator's party affiliation to orient the ideological space. These priors are only used for the first session a senator serves, so they are not overly restrictive. We estimate two IRT models: one for the economic bills and another for the cultural ones.Footnote 20 We operationalize our dependent variables, economic and cultural ideological shifts, simply as changes in the relevant IRT scores, both at the department and individual senator levels.Footnote 21

Independent Variables

To measure trade-induced labour market shocks, we use the shift-share Imports per Worker (IPW) measure pioneered by Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (Reference Autor, Dorn and Hanson2013) and Autor et al. (Reference Autor2020) to estimate local-level exposure to imports from China. The intuitive idea behind this approach is that local labour markets are differentially affected by the growth in imports from low-wage countries depending on their prior industry specialization. Any changes in imports at the industry level will disproportionately impact areas with higher degrees of employment in that industry.

As Fig. 2 shows, there is a substantial geographic variation with respect to trade exposure in France. Here, we see import competition in France operates on roughly a southwestern to northeastern axis. Departments in the northeast have been particularly hard hit. In contrast, the southwestern regions, less intensive in import-competing industries, have far lower IPWs.

Figure 2. Change in Trade Exposure, 1996–2017. This map depicts changes in imports per worker from China in each of France's 95 metropolitan departments disaggregated across 38 employment sectors (NA A38). Source: COMEXT and INSEE.

Following previous studies, we address the possible endogeneity of legislative voting patterns to the import shock by instrumenting IPW using the growth in imports from China to five other wealthy European countries: Germany, Denmark, Sweden, Italy, and the UK (Dauth, Findeisen, and Suedekum Reference Dauth, Findeisen and Suedekum2014).Footnote 22

Our other main independent variables of interest relate to local context: electoral institutions, electoral competitiveness, and patterns of party competition. We use French Senate election data to construct measures indicating whether a department held elections under majoritarian (as opposed to PR) electoral rules, as well as constituency-level vote margins and radical party vote share measures from the prior election.Footnote 23 In addition to our main independent variables, and as shown in Table 2, our models include a measure of the start-of-period political tendency of the department, as well as controls for demographic and economic factors, including a department's start-of-period logged total population, percent female, age structure, percent immigrant population, and percent employed in industry. This data was obtained from INSEE's Estimations de Populations. We also estimate models with two sets of political controls. The first includes a measure of department-level competitiveness, department magnitude, degree of local office holding, and an indicator for a majoritarian electoral system. We also include models that control for other changing features of the political context that might affect legislative behaviour, including indicators for whether, in a particular session, a department experienced a change in its electoral system, there was an expansion of seats, senators in a department were up for re-election in the subsequent session, and if the legislature was divided.

Table 2. Models and Variables

Finally, for all models, we include two-way unit and time-fixed effects,Footnote 24 and we report heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors clustered at the region level to account for spatial autocorrelation. In Appendix L, we report full regression tables, including F-statistics based on robust to weak instrument tests (Pflueger and Wang Reference Pflueger and Wang2015).

Estimation Strategy

To estimate the relationship between trade exposure and legislative behaviour, we follow standard practice by adopting a first-differences model, which allows us to control for time-invariant heterogeneity:

(1)$$\Delta {\rm IR}{\rm T}_{it} = \beta \Delta {\rm IP}{\rm W}_{it} + {X}^{\prime}_{it} + \epsilon _{it}$$

where it refers to department i from time t to t + 1. We defined ΔIPWit previously. ΔIRTit refers to the change in the department ideology score from time (session) t to t + 1. Xit indicates a series of departmental start-of-period political and demographic controls, while ɛit is an idiosyncratic shock we assume is uncorrelated with the regressors. We examine changes in import exposure and its effect on legislator ideology across all elections in our sample. We generate session-by-session IPW measures, IRT scores, and start-of-period controls for each department. This gives us five time periods: the change in trade exposure and legislative ideology from Senate sessions 13 to 14, sessions 14 to 15 and so on, up through session 19. We then pool the data and use stacked first-difference estimation to examine the effects of short-term shifts in localized trade exposure on changes in legislator ideology.Footnote 25

Overall Results

We first examine the effects of changes in trade exposure on legislator economic ideology to test Hypothesis 1 by estimating, in Fig. 3, two-stage least squares (2SLS) models in which the dependent variable is a change in economic ideology.Footnote 26 We report instrumental variable estimates using both individual- and department-level datasets. As noted above, analyzing within-senator changes provides insight into how changes in IPW affect the ideology of incumbent senators, while within-department changes capture shifts in the average ideological disposition of the department via the election of new senators. These two sets of models assess the mechanisms driving ideological shifts by capturing the degree to which change is driven by ideological realignment among sitting senators (individual models) and/or replacement by newly elected senators (department models).

Figure 3. Changes in Imports Per Worker and Ideology (Economic Dimension).

Note: Independent variable is imports per worker, measured in hundreds of euros. All models were estimated using 2SLS.

In Panel A of Fig. 3, we examine the effects of trade on individual-level economic IRT scores.Footnote 27 As Hypothesis 1 predicts, the results show a significant leftward shift among incumbent senators in response to localized increases in import exposure. A shift in imports per worker from the 25th to the 75th percentile results in a leftward shift in economic ideology of approximately one-third of a standard deviation. This suggests that leftward shifts are driven, at least in part, by realignment among sitting senators.

Next, we turn to the department-level models in Panel B of Fig. 3. In our data, approximately one-third to one-half of senators are replaced in any given renewal, making a replacement dynamic plausible.Footnote 28 At the department level, we find greater trade exposure produces a substantively larger ideological shift to the left when compared to the individual-level models.Footnote 29 Although the confidence intervals are wider, the coefficients on ΔIPW are approximately four times larger (−12 versus −3) for the department level as opposed to the senator-level models. This suggests that newly elected senators from trade-affected departments tilt substantially more to the left economically than do their incumbent counterparts. Replacement, in addition to ideological realignment, appears to be an important mechanism in explaining this leftward shift on economic issues.

Heterogeneous Effects: Import Shocks and Local Context

The previous section presented results suggesting legislators are responsive to localized trade increases on economic issues. The overall finding on the economic dimension provides comparative evidence consistent with Ferrara and Herron's (Reference Ferrara and Herron2005) analysis of the leftward shifting consequences of trade for legislative behaviour and supports our Hypothesis 1. However, one advantage of our study is that we can explore the conditions under which import shocks are more or less likely to influence legislative outcomes. This brings us to our second major question: the intervening effects of varying electoral institutions and local competition from extremist candidates. In this section, we investigate the consequences of both sets of intervening variables.

The Mediating Effect of Electoral Institutions

As discussed in reference to Hypothesis 2, assuming reasonable levels of electoral competition, we expect the economic ideological effects of trade to be magnified in departments where senators are elected using majoritarian rules. To test this prediction, we report estimates from two sets of models. The first focuses on within-senator responses to import shifts, while the second reports department-level effects. Coefficients for the senator-level models are shown in Figs 4a and 4b. Figure 4a suggests that, overall, majoritarian electoral institutions have little effect on changes in economic ideology above and beyond the effects of trade. Figure 4b explores whether the effects of majoritarianism are contingent on the degree of electoral competition by reporting coefficients for the interaction of ΔIPW, majoritarianism, and department vote margin at different levels of electoral competitiveness. For the within-senator models, as political competition tightens in majoritarian districts, the senator's economic ideology shifts to the left in response to higher levels of import competition, providing support for Hypothesis 2.

Figure 4. Imports, Electoral Systems and Competitiveness: Senator vs Department-Level Models.

Note: For Figs 4a and 4c, the plots report the coefficient on ΔIPW interacted with majoritarianism. Model 1 (top) includes economic and demographic controls (as defined in Table 2); Model 2 (middle) adds political controls A; and Model 3 adds Political controls B. Figs 4b and 4d report coefficients on the interaction of ΔIPW, majoritarianism and the vote margin of a department, at different levels of vote margin, using the full set of controls (i.e., Model 3). All models include unit and session fixed effects.

The models reported in Figs 4a and 4b analyze the response of sitting senators but do not consider how the election of new senators shapes ideological shifts within departments. We investigate these dynamics with department-level models, reported in Figs 4c and 4d. Figure 4c shows that as import penetration increases in majoritarian departments, the average economic ideology score of the department shifts further to the left compared to PR departments. Figure 5 shows the marginal effects of the fully saturated model. Interestingly, however, Fig. 4d shows this leftward shift takes place irrespective of the electoral competitiveness of the department. The finding that majoritarianism induces a leftward response, even under low levels of electoral competition, suggests the effects of electoral systems in this context may work not simply through what Duverger (Reference Duverger1954) termed the ‘mechanical’ channel of vote-seat shares but also through a ‘psychological’ channel involving strategic coordination by parties and/or voters over candidate selection. We briefly explore these dynamics in Appendix E and return to this possibility in the conclusion.

Figure 5. Imports and Electoral Systems: Marginal Effects for Department-Level Models.

Note: Marginal effects for change in IPW × Majoritarianism using the full set of controls (economic + demographic controls, plus political controls A and B).

How Radical Party Competition Matters

Finally, in Hypotheses 3 and 4, we predict that mainstream legislators will adopt accommodative strategies when confronted with electoral threats from extremist competitors from both the far right and the far left. Figure 6 begins to explore these dynamics, reporting coefficients on models interacting ΔIPW with the electoral strength of radical left and radical right parties in the previous Senate elections in each department.Footnote 30

Figure 6. Imports and Radical Party Strength: Overall Results.

Results shown in Fig. 6a suggest that in departments with a pre-existing strong radical left, increases in IPW produce an overall modest leftward shift in economic ideology and a small leftward shift in cultural ideology. By contrast, Fig. 6b suggests that as local political support for the radical right increases, higher levels of import exposure shift the ideology of sitting senators to the right. This effect is particularly strong on the economic dimension but also notable on the cultural one.

Since dramatically changing political ideology is risky for any politician, we also predicted in Hypotheses 5 and 6 that mainstream senators on the right will be more responsive to challengers from the far right, while mainstream left senators will be more likely to accommodate competitors from the far left. To further explore these heterogenous treatment effects by party, in Fig. 7, we re-estimate the models from Fig. 6, but this time, we break out responses by party family with several noteworthy findings. First, Figs 7a and 7b find support for Hypothesis 6: mainstream senators on the left representing departments with a higher radical left vote share adopt accommodative strategies, shifting further to the left on economic and cultural dimensions.Footnote 31 Similarly, as predicted in Hypothesis 5, in Figs 7c and 7d, we find far-right competitors only significantly impact the economic and cultural ideology of right-leaning mainstream senators, while the results for left-leaning politicians are statistically insignificant.

Figure 7. Imports and Radical Party Strength By Party Family.

We note the results in Figs 6b and 7c were unexpected. As outlined in Table 1, we did not predict the far right, which defines itself primarily with respect to second-dimension issues, to affect the economic ideology of any mainstream senators. Since this effect is driven by right-leaning mainstream senators, it is perhaps unsurprising that these senators would be willing to shift their economic and cultural positions to compete with the far right since this would not constitute a large change from their core positions. However, the direction of the shift is also puzzling since, as noted in Section ‘Import Shocks, Local Electoral Context, and Legislator Ideology’, the National Rally and other far-right parties in Western Europe have, over time, become associated with left-leaning economic platforms that emphasize welfare chauvinism. However, this shift to the economic left is a relatively recent phenomenon, precipitated by the fallout from the 2008 financial crisis (Mudde Reference Mudde2016). Prior to the 2010s, and thus during much of the time period covered in our analyses, most scholars argue that far-right parties in Western Europe adopted economically right-wing and neoliberal platforms (Kitschelt and McGann Reference Kitschelt and McGann1995; Kriesi et al. Reference Kriesi2012; Minkenberg Reference Minkenberg2000) that more closely align with the economic ideology of the mainstream right.

Conclusion

There now exists substantial evidence of globalization's far-reaching domestic consequences at the mass level, but less about the extent to which these effects are reflected at the elite level. Focusing on one aspect of globalization in particular, we ask: do import shocks lead to ideological shifts among individual legislators? Analyzing voting data from the French Senate between 1996 and 2017, we find increases in trade exposure result in a leftward economic shift at both the individual senator- and the constituency- (department) level. Leftward shifts are larger at the department level, suggesting that a replacement mechanism is at work, as sitting senators are replaced by more left-leaning senators in trade-affected departments. We also show ideological shifts on the economic dimension are stronger in competitive majoritarian districts. Finally, we present evidence that the local competitive context in which elections occur mediates the effects of trade: left and right mainstream politicians respond differently to trade in the face of strong extremist competitors.

How do our results relate to existing findings about the political consequences of trade shocks among political elites? The previous literature, much of it coming from the US context, has generated somewhat conflicting findings. While Autor et al. (Reference Autor2020) show these shocks lead to increased economic polarization, other studies report a link between constituency-level import shocks and legislator support for left-leaning legislation. Our results are consistent with the latter, but there remain important differences of emphasis. For example, Feigenbaum and Hall (Reference Feigenbaum and Hall2015), Kuk, Seligsohn, and Zhang (Reference Kuk, Seligsohn and Zhang2018), and Kleinberg and Fordham (Reference Kleinberg and Fordham2013) find trade generates support for leftward shifts on specific economic issues, such as (protectionist) trade legislation or roll call voting and bill sponsorship activity on legislation hostile to China. By contrast, we find evidence of a generalized economic ideological shift to the left. Because jurisdiction over trade policy lies with the EU in Europe, we cannot make direct comparisons with prior studies on whether import penetration influences the specific issues of protectionism and trade with China. Nevertheless, French Senate reports from this period criticizing the EU's trade policy provide suggestive evidence of rising protectionist inclinations.Footnote 32 Future studies of legislative behaviour around trade policy at the EU level could yield important insights on this question.

Our findings relating to electoral systems also suggest the value of analyzing comparative cases that provide new analytic leverage. Existing work on the elite political consequences of import penetration comes from the US and Brazil, countries with majoritarian and open-list PR electoral systems, respectively. And yet, more than half of the world's legislatures use a different system for aggregating votes into seats: closed-list PR (Cruz, Keefer, and Scartascini Reference Cruz, Keefer and Scartascini2020). Our study enables us to directly compare ideological responses under majoritarian and closed-list PR systems. The substantially weaker effects in departments with PR elections suggest the possibility of more muted elite responses to trade in many advanced democracies.

Another important question is how our micro-level findings relate to political dynamics in France and elsewhere. The broad leftward economic shift we identify is consistent with existing accounts of the evolution of French economic policy prior to the 2010s, which has been characterized as one of ‘social anaesthesia’ (Levy Reference Levy2008), highlighting the fact that state authorities were expanding labour market and social welfare programmes to pacify the victims of economic liberalization. After 2010, the picture becomes more complex. On the one hand, the state moved to liberalize the labour market and rationalize some welfare programmes (Howell Reference Howell2018). Nevertheless, this shift toward ‘uncompensated liberalism’ faced substantial political resistance (Vail, Watson, and Driscoll Reference Vail, Watson and Driscoll2023), and presidents from both the left and the right chose to push through major liberalizing reforms via executive fiat rather than through normal legislative channels (Levy Reference Levy2023).

At first glance, our findings relating to the cultural dimension of politics stand in some tension with research from both the French and broader European context. Overall, we find that a rise in import competition causes an ideological shift to the left on economic issues but has little effect on cultural ideology. It is only in contexts where mainstream legislators face strong radical party competition that they alter their cultural positions. How does this finding square with common characterizations of France as a case in which globalization has voters actively rewarding the far right and in which there exists a growing hostility to European integration and ‘globalism’? Some of the seeming disjuncture may be driven by the fact that France's institutional structure historically made it difficult for the far right to gain a political foothold.Footnote 33 Despite being a strong contender in the 2002, 2017, and 2022 presidential elections, a prominent force in municipal elections, and winning close to one-quarter of France's seats in the 2014 and 2019 European Parliament elections, the Front National (FN) has been historically underrepresented in national legislative politics.

Rising support for nativism and anti-globalism in response to trade exists in many other Western democracies beyond France (Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Dippel, Gold, and Heblich Reference Dippel, Gold and Heblich2015; Gingrich Reference Gingrich2017; Malgouyres Reference Malgouyres2014). And yet, as Rodrik (Reference Rodrik2021) observes, there is a paucity of work on the relationship between globalization, party-political dynamics, and the emergence of sociocultural cleavages (Rodrik Reference Rodrik2021). Our paper offers one possible answer to this ongoing dialogue about the disconnect between mainstream elite (economic) and voter (cultural) responses to globalization: mainstream elites will respond to cultural demands, but only when the dynamics of party competition incentivize them to do so. Returning to the French case specifically, in light of the recent breakthrough of the Front National (now the National Rally) into national legislative politics, we expect mainstream politicians will respond with more accommodation on the cultural dimension in the future.

Finally, although we explore in a preliminary fashion one potential channel through which legislator ideological changes occur – via the dynamics of realignment and/or by electoral replacement – important questions remain. For example, in several of our department-level models, we find evidence of stronger ideological shifts among newly elected as opposed to sitting senators. This raises additional questions about how globalization affects underlying supply-side dynamics, especially those related to candidate entry and selection. Do rising rates of import penetration affect the ideological leanings of new candidates? If so, how? To what degree does intensifying import competition heighten incentives for parties and voters to respond strategically to the anticipated effects of electoral rules by, for example, presenting fewer candidates in majoritarian elections (Blais and Indridason Reference Blais and Indridason2007; Cox Reference Cox1997; Crisp and Demirkaya Reference Crisp and Demirkaya2020; Duverger Reference Duverger1954)? Investigating these and other related questions should offer important insights into the mechanisms through which contemporary global economic forces impact the very functioning of the supply side of the political market.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123423000662.

Data availability statement

Replication data for this article can be found in Harvard Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/FXRQUJ.

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge valuable feedback from Diane Bolet, Bjorn Bremer, Christian Breunig, Richard Clark, Jose Fernandez-Albertos, Philipp Rehm, Stephanie Rickard, Hanna Schwander, Alexander Thompson, Milada Vachudova, the reviewers and editors at BJPolS, contributors at APSA, CES, IPES, MPSA, and ISA conferences, as well as participants in workshops at the Max Planck Institute, Humboldt University, and Princeton University.

Financial support

We gratefully acknowledge grant support from Ohio State University's Mershon Center for International Security Studies.

Competing interest

None.

Footnotes

1 For example, majoritarian versus proportional representation (PR) systems.

2 The only exception of which we are aware focuses on Brazil (Campello and Urdinez, Reference Campello and Urdinez2021). In the European context most elite-centred research on trade focuses on political parties, particularly at the national level (Adams, Haupt and Stoli, Reference Adams, Haupt and Stoli2009; Haupt, Reference Haupt2010; O'Grady and Abou-Chadi, Reference O'Grady and Abou-Chadi2019; Scheve and Serlin, Reference Scheve and Serlin2023), rather than individual politicians. There is substantial work in Europe on individual legislator responsiveness to voters, but this work has been largely limited to stable economic contexts (André, Depauw, and Martin Reference André, Depauw and Martin2015; Bol et al. Reference Bol2021; Broockman Reference Broockman2013; De Vries, Dinas, and Solaz Reference De Vries, Dinas and Solaz2016; Habel and Birch Reference Habel and Birch2019).

3 On the voter side, economic integration has been linked to increased demand for far-right populism (Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Dippel, Gold, and Heblich Reference Dippel, Gold and Heblich2015; Gingrich Reference Gingrich2017), anti-immigrant sentiment (Autor et al. Reference Autor2020; Ballard-Rosa, Jensen, and Scheve Reference Ballard-Rosa, Jensen and Scheve2021; Coffé, Heyndels, and Vermeir Reference Coffé, Heyndels and Vermeir2007; Dippel et al. Reference Dippel2017; Malgouyres Reference Malgouyres2017a), and increasingly authoritarian attitudes among voters (Gidron and Hall Reference Gidron and Hall2017; Norris and Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2019; Werts, Scheepers, and Lubbers Reference Werts, Scheepers and Lubbers2013). Until recently, the consensus was that identity and values, rather than economic self-interest, drive voters' trade attitudes (Rho and Tomz Reference Rho and Tomz2017). Nevertheless, a growing body of scholarship acknowledges the economic effects of globalization vary sub-nationally and argues that the resulting long-term economic dislocations can lead affected individuals to shift their cultural and economic policy preferences (Rickard Reference Rickard2022; Rommel and Walter Reference Rommel and Walter2018; Scheve and Serlin Reference Scheve and Serlin2023).

4 This second ideological dimension has been alternatively referred to as the ‘transnational’, ‘sociocultural’, or ‘identity’ dimension. We treat these as equivalent but use the term ‘cultural’ to describe this dimension.

5 Theoretically, whether mainstream politicians shift right or left in response to a strong radical left movement should depend on the radical left's linkages to social organizations (Watson, Reference Watson2015). We might expect a rightward shift when strong radical left parties are closely linked to ‘encapsulating’ civil society organizations that render far-left voters electorally unavailable to mainstream centre-left and centre-right parties. Alternatively, when strong, radical-left parties lack these connections to social organizations, there are few disincentives for mainstream left parties to respond to electoral threats on their left flank. We hypothesize a leftward shift in this study because the past thirty years have seen the weakening of both the transmission belt model of PCF-CGT party-union relations and also of municipal socialism (Kriegel Reference Kriegel1970; Kriegel, Braun and Muresianu Reference Kriegel, Braun and Muresianu1979). With this slow but steady organizational disembedding of communist voters, we believe there are few disincentives for mainstream left parties to respond to electoral threats on their left flank.

6 It is generally agreed that electoral systems are chosen strategically (Boix Reference Boix1999; Colomer Reference Colomer2005; Rokkan Reference Rokkan1970) in ways likely correlated with determinants of elite responsiveness, such as party system type or the nature of societal cleavages (Eggers Reference Eggers2015). By exploring variation in electoral rules within a single case, we can better identify how these institutions mediate trade's political consequences.

7 See Appendix C for details on electoral rules. Due to the availability of trade data, our analysis focuses exclusively on metropolitan departments.

8 The average senator in our senator-level dataset held 2.3 local offices.

9 In Appendix E, we show electoral support for left-leaning Senate candidates is higher in trade-affected regions, suggesting a willingness among voters to hold their elected representatives to account.

11 See Appendix A for an overview of spatial models of voting.

12 For most of the Fifth Republic, one-third of the Senate faced re-election every three years. There are exceptions: for example, a Constitutional Council ruling requires the Senate to have a four-year period between elections (2004 to 2008) to avoid too many elections (National Assembly, local, regional) in a single year.

13 http://www.senat.fr/. The endpoint of 2017 was driven by trade data availability. We could not collect information for 2004/5 and 2005/6 for which individual roll call votes were not published.

14 While our theoretical argument is focused on the ideological responses of mainstream legislators, approximately 8 percent of our sample are from non-mainstream parties, mainly the Communist Party, for whom economic issues are highly salient. Appendix H shows results breaking down responses by type of left party; results are substantively similar.

15 Some bills mention economic and cultural issues; for example, some bills discuss equal pay for women and minority groups. In these cases, we code the bill as economic since the primary issue is economic in nature.

16 See Appendix B for a detailed discussion.

17 See Appendix A.1 for details.

18 We do not apply these exclusions in the cultural models since our dataset has relatively few cultural bills.

19 See Appendices A.2 and A.3 for a review of the literature on the treatment of abstentions in roll call voting and a discussion of the French Senate's voting rules.

20 We report the mean IRT score by party in Appendix B.

21 As discussed in Section ‘Incorporating Cultural Ideology: The Role of Extremist Challengers’ and below, distinguishing between department and individual-level shifts allows us to test the mechanisms, namely, if realignment or replacement dynamics are driving any observed ideological shifts in trade-exposed regions.

22 See Appendix D for a description of the IPW measure and the instrument. We also include robustness checks usinga broader range of less developed countries to generate the IPW measure and the instrument; results remain substantively unchanged.

23 Our senator-level analysis dataset contains 1,428 observations, while our department-level dataset contains 570 observations.

24 We include senator fixed effects for individual models and department fixed effects for department models.

25 We note that our analysis should not be viewed as estimating the total impact of trade openness on legislator ideology since, as discussed in Section ‘The Domestic Consequences of Import Shocks’, trade openness can have both positive and negative economic effects. Rather, the findings reported below capture the localized political effects of one particularly salient aspect of trade:import shocks. Nevertheless, in Appendix J, we report additional models that account for potentially positive effects of trade. The results remain substantively similar.

26 In the figures, we report only the coefficients for the central variables of interest: change in imports for workers and, for the interaction models, majoritarianism or radical party strength. See Appendix L for full regression tables.

27 Controls are identical in the individual senator-level and department-level models.

28 Electoral defeats, retirement, and leaving for positions in the National Assembly or the government are among the most common reasons for replacement.

29 In Appendix E, we report results that suggest an increase in trade reduces the percentage of right-wing and centre senators being elected and a roughly equivalent increase in the percentage of left-wing senators – a finding consistent with the substantial leftward shift driven by replacement.

30 In this subsection, we report only individual senator-level results.

31 See Appendix H for additional analyses on partisan differences in responses to strong radical left competitors.

32 Protectionist discourse included calls for a European industrial policy featuring harmonized tax and social policy systems, support for strategic sectors, and the ‘alignment’ of industrial and competition policy.

33 Indeed, between 1988 and 2017, there were between 0 and 2 FN members of the National Assembly. Similarly, there were no FN members in the Senate until 2014, when they won two seats.

References

Abou-Chadi, T (2016) Niche party success and mainstream party policy shifts – How green and radical right parties differ in their impact. British Journal of Political Science 46(2), 417–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abou-Chadi, T and Krause, W (2020) The causal effect of radical right success on mainstream parties’ policy positions: A regression discontinuity approach. British Journal of Political Science 50, 829–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, J, Haupt, AB and Stoli, H (2009) What moves parties?: The role of public opinion and global economic conditions in Western Europe. Comparative Political Studies 42(5), 611–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allan, J and Scruggs, L (2004) Political partisanship and welfare state reform in advanced industrial societies. American Journal of Political Science 48, 496512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
André, A, Depauw, S and Martin, S (2015) Electoral systems and legislators’ constituency effort: The mediating effect of electoral vulnerability. Comparative Political Studies 48, 464–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthuis, J (2005) Délocalisations: rompre avec les modalités pour sauver le modèle français. Technical report Senat Rapport d'information no 416, tome II. Available from https://www.senat.fr/rap/r04-416-2/r04-416-21.pdfGoogle Scholar
Autor, D, Dorn, D and Hanson, GH (2013) The China syndrome: Local labor market effects of import competition in the United States. The American Economic Review 103(6), 2121–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D et al. (2020) Importing political polarization? The electoral consequences of rising trade exposure. American Economic Review 110(10), 3139–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bach, L et al. (2012) Faut-il Abolir le Cumul des Mandats? Paris: Rue d'Ulm Paris.Google Scholar
Bale, T and Dunphy, R (2011) In from the cold? Left parties and government involvement since 1989. Comparative European Politics 9, 269–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballard-Rosa, C, Jensen, A and Scheve, K (2021) Economic decline, social identity, and authoritarian values in the United States. International Studies Quarterly 66(1), 114.Google Scholar
Balsvik, R, Sissel, J and Salvanes, KG (2015) Made in China, sold in Norway: Local labor market effects of an import shock. Journal of Public Economics 127, 137–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumgartner, FR, Breunig, C and Grossman, E (2019) Comparative Policy Agendas: Theory, Tools, Data. Oxford: Oxford University Press, p. 424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, K and Laver, M (2007) Estimating party policy positions: Comparing expert surveys and hand-coded content analysis. Electoral Studies 26(1), 90107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergh, A and Nilsson, T (2010) Do liberalization and globalization increase income inequality? European Journal of Political Economy 26, 488505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betz, H-G and Meret, S (2012) Right-wing populist parties and the working-class vote: What have you done for us lately? In Rydgren, J (ed.) Class Politics and the Radical Right. London: Routledge, 107–21.Google Scholar
Blais, A and Indridason, IH (2007) Making candidates count: The logic of electoral alliances in two-round legislative elections. The Journal of Politics 69(1), 193205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, C (1999) Setting the rules of the game: The choice of electoral systems in advanced democracies. American Political Science Review 93, 609–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bol, D et al. (2021) The importance of personal vote intentions for the responsiveness of legislators: A field experiment. European Journal of Political Research 60, 455–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breunig, C, Grossman, E and Hänni, M (2022) Responsiveness and democratic accountability: Observational evidence from an experiment in a Mixed Member proportional system. Legislative Studies Quarterly 47(1), 7994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broockman, DE (2013) Black politicians are more intrinsically motivated to advance blacks’ interests: A field experiment manipulating political incentives. American Journal of Political Science 57, 521–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, C and Brady, D (1999) Income, economic voting, and long-term political change in the U.S., 1952–1996. Social Forces 77(4), 1339–74.Google Scholar
Butler, DM and Nickerson, DW (2011) Can learning constituency opinion affect how legislators vote? Results from a field experiment. Quarterly Journal of Political Science 6(1), 5583.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campello, D and Urdinez, F (2021) Voter and legislator responses to localized trade shocks from China in Brazil. Comparative Political Studies 54, 1131–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, J (2007) Competing principals, political institutions, and party unity in legislative voting. American Journal of Political Science 51(1), 92107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, JM and Shugart, MS (1995) Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: A rank ordering of electoral formulas. Electoral Studies 14(4), 417–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caughey, D, O'Grady, T and Warshaw, C (2019) Policy ideology in European mass publics, 1981–2016. American Political Science Review 113(3), 674–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, EC et al. (2010) Electoral Systems and the Balance of Consumer-Producer Power. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clinton, J, Jackman, S and Rivers, D (2004) The statistical analysis of roll call data. American Political Science Review 98(2), 355–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coffé, H, Heyndels, B and Vermeir, J (2007) Fertile grounds for extreme right-wing parties: Explaining the Vlaams Blok's electoral success. Electoral Studies 26(1), 142–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colantone, I and Stanig, P (2018) The trade origins of economic nationalism: Import competition and voting behavior in Western Europe. American Journal of Political Science 62(4), 936–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colomer, JM (2005) It's parties that choose electoral systems (or, Duverger's laws upside down). Political Studies 53, 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa, O and Kerrouche, E (2009) Representative roles in the French national assembly: The case for a dual typology? French Politics 7(3–4), 219–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costinot, A and Rodríguez-Clare, A (2014) Trade theory with numbers: Quantifying the consequences of globalization. In Gopinath, G, Helpman, E and Rogoff, K (eds), Handbook of International Economics. Oxford: Elsevier B.V, 197261.Google Scholar
Cox, GW (1997) Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World's Electoral Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crisp, BF and Demirkaya, B (2020) Strategic entry and strategic voting in majoritarian systems. The Journal of Politics 82(1), 5771.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cruz, C, Keefer, P and Scartascini, C (2020) The Database of Political Institutions 2020. Technical report Inter-American Development Bank.Google Scholar
Dauth, W, Findeisen, S and Suedekum, J (2014) The rise of the East and the Far East: German labor markets and trade integration. Journal of the European Economic Association 12(6), 1643–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Vries, C, Dinas, E and Solaz, H (2016) You have got mail! How Intrinsic and extrinsic motivations shape constituency service in the European Parliament. IHS Political Science Series No. 140, May 2016.Google Scholar
Dippel, C, Gold, R and Heblich, S (2015) Globalization and its (dis-) content: Trade shocks and voting behavior. (No. w21812). National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dippel, C et al. (2017) Instrumental variables and causal mechanisms: Unpacking the effect of trade on workers and voters. No. w23209. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donoso, V et al. (2014) Exposure to Chinese imports and local labor market outcomes. An Analysis for Spanish provinces (No. 1406). Universidad Complutense de Madrid, Instituto Complutense de Estudios Internacionales.Google Scholar
Dreher, A, Sturm, J-E and Ursprung, HW (2008) The impact of globalization on the composition of government expenditures: Evidence from panel data. Public Choice 134, 263–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duverger, M (1954) Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Eggers, AC (2015) Proportionality and turnout: Evidence from French municipalities. Comparative Political Studies 48(2), 135–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ennser-Jedenastik, L (2022) The impact of radical right parties on family benefits. West European Politics 45(1), 154–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feigenbaum, JJ and Hall, AB (2015) How legislators respond to localized economic shocks: Evidence from Chinese import competition. The Journal of Politics 77(4), 1012–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrara, F and Herron, ES (2005) Going it alone? Strategic entry under mixed electoral rules. American Journal of Political Science 49(1), 1631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fordham, BO and McKeown, TJ (2003) Selection and influence: Interest groups and congressional voting on trade policy. International Organization 57(3), 519–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G (1998) Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gidron, N and Hall, PA (2017) The politics of social status: Economic and cultural roots of the populist right. The British Journal of Sociology 68(S1), S57S84.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gingrich, J (2017) Changing Labor Markets, Changing Voters? Working paper.Google Scholar
Grignon, F (2004) “Délocalisations: pour un néo-colbertisme européen.” Senat Rapport d'information no. 374.Google Scholar
Guisinger, A (2009) Determining trade policy: Do voters hold politicians accountable? International Organization 63(3), 533–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habel, P and Birch, S (2019) A field experiment on the effects of ethnicity and socioeconomic status on the quality of representation. Legislative Studies Quarterly 44, 389420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, J and Hiscox, MJ (2006) Learning to love globalization: Education and individual attitudes toward international trade. International Organization 60(2), 469–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, J and Kern, HL (2008) Incumbency as a source of spillover effects in mixed electoral systems: Evidence from a regression-discontinuity design. Electoral Studies 27(2), 213–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Han, KJ (2015) The impact of radical right-wing parties on the positions of mainstream parties regarding multiculturalism. West European Politics 38, 557–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haupt, AB (2010) Parties’ responses to economic globalization. Party Politics 16(1), 527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellwig, T (2014) Balancing demands: The world economy and the composition of policy preferences. Journal of Politics 76(1), 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helpman, E, Itskhoki, O and Redding, S (2010) Inequality and unemployment in a global economy. Econometrica 78, 1239–83.Google Scholar
Hix, S and Noury, A (2009) After enlargement: Voting patterns in the sixth European Parliament. Legislative Studies Quarterly 34(2), 159–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe, L and Marks, G (2018) Cleavage theory meets Europe's crises: Lipset, Rokkan, and the transnational cleavage. Journal of European Public Policy 25(1), 109–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopkin, J (2020) Anti-System Politics: The Crisis of Market Liberalism in Rich Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howell, C (2018) The French road to neoliberalism. Catalyst 2(3). https://catalyst-journal.com/vol2/no3/the-french-road-to-neoliberalism.Google Scholar
Hummels, D et al. (2014) The wage effects of offshoring: Evidence from Danish matched worker-firm data. American Economic Review 104(6), 1597–629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imai, K, Lo, J and Olmsted, J (2016) Fast estimation of ideal points with massive data. American Political Science Review 110(4), 631–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, JB, Quinn, DP and Weymouth, S (2017) Winners and losers in international trade: The effects on US presidential voting. International Organization 71, 423–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karol, D (2007) Does constituency size affect elected officials’ trade policy preferences? The Journal of Politics 69(2), 483–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, RS (1997) Democracy and Elections. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kitschelt, H and McGann, AJ (1995) The Radical Right in Western Europe. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Kleinberg, KB and Fordham, BO (2013) The domestic politics of trade and conflict. International Studies Quarterly 57(3), 605–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kriegel, A (1970) Les Communistes Français. Paris: Éditions du Seuil.Google Scholar
Kriegel, A, Braun, J and Muresianu, J (1979) The nature of the communist system: Notes on state, party, and society. Daedalus 108(4), 139–53.Google Scholar
Kriesi, H et al. (2012) Political Conflict in Western Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuk, JS, Seligsohn, D and Zhang, JJ (2018) From Tiananmen to outsourcing: The effect of rising import competition on congressional voting towards China. Journal of Contemporary China 27(109), 103–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lefkofridi, Z and Michel, E (2014) The electoral politics of solidarity. The welfare state agendas of radical right. In Banting, KG and Kymlicka W (eds), The Strains of Commitment. The Political Sources of Solidarity in Diverse Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 233–67.Google Scholar
Leibrecht, M, Klien, M and Onaran, O (2011) Globalization, welfare regimes and social protection expenditures in Western and Eastern European countries. Public Choice 148, 569–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, JD (2008) From the dirigiste state to the social anaesthesia state: French economic policy in the longue durée. Modern & Contemporary France 16(4), 417–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, JD (2023) Contested Liberalization: Historical Legacies and Contemporary Conflict in France. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis-Beck, MS and Paldam, M (2000) Economic voting: An Introduction. Electoral Studies 19(2000), 113–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malgouyres, C (2014) Chinese imports competition's impact on employment and the wage distribution: Evidence from French local labor markets. Department of Economics, European University Institute. EUI Working paper ECO 2014/12.Google Scholar
Malgouyres, C (2017a) Trade shocks and far-right voting: Evidence from French presidential elections. Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies Research Paper No. RSCAS, 21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malgouyres, C (2017b) The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages: Evidence from France. Journal of Regional Science 57(3), 411–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, ED and Mutz, DC (2009) Support for free trade: Self-interest, sociotropic politics, and out-group anxiety. International Organization 63(3), 425–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Margalit, Y (2011) Costly jobs: Trade-related layoffs, government compensation, and voting in US elections. American Political Science Review 105, 166–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Margalit, Y (2013) Explaining social policy preferences: Evidence from the great recession. American Political Science Review 107(01), 80103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, AD and Quinn, KM (2002) Dynamic ideal point estimation via Markov Chain Monte Carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953–1999. Political Analysis 10(2), 134–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meguid, B (2005) Competition between unequals: The role of mainstream party strategy in niche party success. American Political Science Review 99, 347–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meinhard, S and Potrafke, N (2012) The globalization–welfare state nexus reconsidered. Review of International Political Economy 20(2), 271–87.Google Scholar
Melitz, MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6), 1695–725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyerrose, AM (2018) It is all about value: How domestic party brands influence voting patterns in the European parliament. Governance 31(4), 625–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyerrose, AM (2020) The unintended consequences of democracy promotion: International organizations and democratic backsliding. Comparative Political Studies 53(1011), 1547–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyerrose, AM (2023) Building strong executives and weak institutions: How European integration contributes to democratic backsliding. Review of International Organizations.Google Scholar
Meyerrose, AM and Watson, S (2023) Replication Data for: The Effects of Import Shocks, Electoral Institutions, and Radical Party Competition on Legislator Ideology: Evidence From France. Available from https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/FXRQUJ, Harvard Dataverse, V1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, HV (2021) Voting for populism in Europe: Globalization, technological change, and the extreme right. Comparative Political Studies 54, 2286–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, H and Tingley, D (2011) Who supports global economic engagement? The sources of preferences in American foreign economic policy. International Organization 65(Winter), 3768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minkenberg, M (2000) The renewal of the radical right: Between modernity and anti-modernity. Government and Opposition 35(2), 170–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, P (2000) Voters and their representatives: Electoral institutions and delegation in parliamentary democracies. European Journal of Political Research 37, 335–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mudde, C (2016) The study of populist radical right parties: Towards a fourth wave. C-Rex Working Paper Series 1(1).Google Scholar
Nanou, K and Dorussen, H (2013) European integration and electoral democracy: How the European Union constrains party competition in the Member States. European Journal of Political Research 52, 7193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, P and Inglehart, R (2019) Cultural Backlash: Trump, Brexit, and Authoritarian Populism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Grady, T and Abou-Chadi, T (2019) Not so responsive after all: European parties do not respond to public opinion shifts across multiple issue dimensions. Research & Politics 6(4), 17.Google Scholar
Page, E and Goldsmith, M (2016) Centre and locality: Explaining cross-national variation. French Politics 14(1), 3054.Google Scholar
Pflueger, CE and Wang, S (2015) A robust test for weak instruments in Stata. The Stata Journal 15(1), 216–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, KT and Rosenthal, H (1985) A spatial model for legislative roll call analysis. American Journal of Political Science 29(2), 357–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, KT and Rosenthal, H (2001) D-Nominate after 10 years: A comparative update to Congress: A political-economic history of roll call voting. Legislative Studies Quarterly 26(1), 529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rho, S and Tomz, M (2017) Why don't trade preferences reflect economic self-interest? International Organization 71(S1), S85S108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rickard, SJ (2018) Spending to Win: Political Institutions, Economic Geography, and Government Subsidies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rickard, SJ (2022) Economic geography, politics, and the world trade regime. World Trade Review 21, 367–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D (1998) Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy 106, 9971032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D (2011) The Globalization Paradox: Democracy and the Future of the World Economy. New York: WW Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D (2021) Why does globalization fuel populism? Economics, culture, and the rise of right-wing populism. Annual Review of Economics 13, 133–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogowski, R and Kayser, MA (2002) Majoritarian electoral systems and consumer power: Price-level evidence from the OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science 46(3), 526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rokkan, S (1970) Citizens, Elections, Parties: Approaches to the Comparative Study of the Process of Development. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
Rommel, T and Walter, S (2018) The electoral consequences of offshoring: How the globalization of production shapes party preferences. Comparative Political Studies 51(5), 621–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rovny, J (2013) Where do radical right parties stand? Position blurring in multidimensional competition. European Political Science Review 5, 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruggie, JG (1982) International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International organization 36(2), 379415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schain, MA (2002) The impact of the French national front on the French political system. In Schain, M, Zolberg, A and Hossay, P (eds), Shadows Over Europe: The Development and Impact of the Extreme Right in Western Europe. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 223–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheve, K and Serlin, T (2023) The German trade shock and the rise of the neo-welfare state in early twentieth-century Britain. American Political Science Review 117, 557–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, M (2010) Parties. In Castles, F, Leibfried, S, Lewis, J, Obinger, H and Pierson, C (eds), The Oxford Handbook of the Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 211–26.Google Scholar
Shugart, MS and Taagepera, R (1989) Seats and Votes. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Sieberer, U (2010) Behavioral consequences of mixed electoral systems: Deviating voting behavior of district and list MPs in the German Bundestag. Electoral Studies 29(3), 484–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spoon, J-J and Klüver, H (2020) Responding to far right challengers: Does accommodation pay off? Journal of European Public Policy 27(2), 273–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spoon, JJ and Williams, CJ (2021) ‘It's the economy, stupid’: When new politics parties take on old politics issues. West European Politics 44, 802–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taagepera, R (1973) Seats and votes: A generalization of the cube law of elections. Social Science Research 2(3), 257–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vail, MI, Watson, S and Driscoll, D (2023) Representation and displacement: Labor disembedding and contested neoliberalism in France. Comparative Politics 55(3), 377400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van de Voorde, N and de Vet, B (2020) Is all politics indeed local? A comparative study of dual mandate-holders’ role attitudes and behaviours in parliament. Swiss Political Science Review 26(1), 5172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Spanje, J (2010) Contagious parties: Anti-immigration parties and their impact on other parties’ immigration stances in contemporary Western Europe. Party Politics 16(5), 563–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volkens, A et al. (2020) The Manifesto Data Collection. Manifesto Project (MRG/CMP/MARPOR). Version 2020b.Google Scholar
Watson, SE (2015) The Left Divided : The Development and Transformation of Advanced Welfare States. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Werts, H, Scheepers, P and Lubbers, M (2013) Euro-scepticism and radical rightwing voting in Europe, 2002–2008: Social cleavages, socio-political attitudes and contextual characteristics determining voting for the radical right. European Union Politics 14(2), 183205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wlezien, C and Soroka, SN (2012) Political institutions and the opinion–policy link. West European 35(6), 1407–432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Politics in Western democracies takes place along two distinct ideological dimensions: the economic dimension and the cultural one.

Figure 1

Table 1. Summary of Predictions

Figure 2

Figure 2. Change in Trade Exposure, 1996–2017. This map depicts changes in imports per worker from China in each of France's 95 metropolitan departments disaggregated across 38 employment sectors (NA A38). Source: COMEXT and INSEE.

Figure 3

Table 2. Models and Variables

Figure 4

Figure 3. Changes in Imports Per Worker and Ideology (Economic Dimension).Note: Independent variable is imports per worker, measured in hundreds of euros. All models were estimated using 2SLS.

Figure 5

Figure 4. Imports, Electoral Systems and Competitiveness: Senator vs Department-Level Models.Note: For Figs 4a and 4c, the plots report the coefficient on ΔIPW interacted with majoritarianism. Model 1 (top) includes economic and demographic controls (as defined in Table 2); Model 2 (middle) adds political controls A; and Model 3 adds Political controls B. Figs 4b and 4d report coefficients on the interaction of ΔIPW, majoritarianism and the vote margin of a department, at different levels of vote margin, using the full set of controls (i.e., Model 3). All models include unit and session fixed effects.

Figure 6

Figure 5. Imports and Electoral Systems: Marginal Effects for Department-Level Models.Note: Marginal effects for change in IPW × Majoritarianism using the full set of controls (economic + demographic controls, plus political controls A and B).

Figure 7

Figure 6. Imports and Radical Party Strength: Overall Results.

Figure 8

Figure 7. Imports and Radical Party Strength By Party Family.

Supplementary material: File

Meyerrose and Watson supplementary material

Meyerrose and Watson supplementary material
Download Meyerrose and Watson supplementary material(File)
File 4.4 MB
Supplementary material: File

Meyerrose_and_Watson_Dataset

Dataset

Download Meyerrose_and_Watson_Dataset(File)
File