Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T11:37:57.409Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Political Representation and its Mechanisms: A Dynamic Left–Right Approach for the United Kingdom, 1976–2006

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 June 2010

Abstract

Some scholars use the ‘dynamic representation’ approach to test how much current policy changes reflect past public preferences. This article tests hypotheses derived from this approach in a left–right context for the United Kingdom from 1976 to 2006. This shows that government policy on the left–right scale shifts as public preferences change (‘rational anticipation’). Secondly, a public with right-wing preferences elects the Conservatives, who pursue right-wing policies in office (‘electoral turnover’). However, popular incumbents are less likely to adjust their policy position to the public. The Westminster system is criticized for its weak link between the rulers and the ruled, but dynamic representation on the left–right scale in the United Kingdom seems to have functioned admirably in this period.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Dahl, Robert A., Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1972)Google Scholar; Pitkin, Hanna F., The Concept of Representation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1967)Google Scholar.

2 E.g., Stimson, James A., MacKuen, Michael B. and Erikson, Robert S., ‘Dynamic Representation’, American Political Science Review, 89 (1995), 543565CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 May, John D., ‘Defining Democracy: A Bid for Coherence and Consensus’, Political Studies, 26 (1978), 114CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 1.

4 For comprehensive overviews, see Burstein, Paul, ‘The Impact of Public Opinion on Public Policy: A Review and an Agenda’, Political Research Quarterly, 56 (2003), 2940CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Weakliem, David, ‘Public Opinion Research and Political Sociology’, Research in Political Sociology, 12 (2003), 4980CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Soroka, Stuart N. and Wlezien, Christopher, ‘The Relationship between Public Opinion and Policy’, in Russell Dalton and Hans-Dieter Klingemann, eds, Oxford Handbook of Political Behavior (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007), pp. 799818Google Scholar. The bulk of the literature is concerned with the United States and is reviewed in Manza, Jeff and Cook, Fay L., ‘A Democratic Polity? Three Views of Policy Responsiveness to Public Opinion in the United States’, American Politics Research, 30 (2002), 630667CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 The classic statement is Miller, Warren and Stokes, Donald, ‘Constituency Influence in Congress’, American Political Science Review, 57 (1963), 4556CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Wlezien, Christopher, ‘The Public as Thermostat: Dynamics of Preferences for Spending’, American Journal of Political Science, 39 (1995), 981–100CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Franklin, Mark N. and Wlezien, Christopher, ‘The Responsive Public: Issue Salience, Policy Change, and Preferences for European Unification’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 9 (1997), 347363CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Soroka, Stuart N. and Wlezien, Christopher, ‘Opinion–Policy Dynamics: Public Preferences and Public Expenditure in the United Kingdom’, British Journal of Political Science, 35 (2005), 655689CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 Stimson, , MacKuen, and Erikson, , ‘Dynamic Representation’, p. 544Google Scholar.

8 Soroka and Wlezien, ‘Opinion–Policy Dynamics’; Stuart N. Soroka and Christopher Wlezien, ‘Degrees of Democracy: Government Institutions and the Opinion–Policy Link’ (paper prepared for the General Conference of the European Consortium of Political Research, 2007).

9 Hobolt, Sara B. and Klemmensen, Robert, ‘Responsive Government? Public Opinion and Policy Preferences in Britain and Denmark’, Political Studies, 53 (2005), 379402CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hobolt, Sara B. and Klemmensen, Robert, ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’, Comparative Political Studies, 41 (2008), 309337CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jennings, Will and John, Peter, ‘The Dynamics of Political Attention: Public Opinion and the Queen’s Speech in the United Kingdom’, American Journal of Political Science, 53 (2009), 838854CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

10 To be fair, Stimson and his colleagues include a model that summarizes dynamic representation across all four institutions, but they themselves call this design ‘a fiction’ and ‘a rough answer to a rough question’ (Stimson, MacKuen and Erikson, ‘Dynamic Representation’, p. 556).

11 Lijphart, Arend, Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1999), pp. 1011Google Scholar.

12 Inglehart, Ronald F., Culture Shift in Advanced Industrial Society (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1990), p. 293Google Scholar.

13 Hakhverdian, Armèn, ‘Capturing Government Policy on the Left–Right Scale: Evidence from the United Kingdom, 1956–2006’, Political Studies, 57 (2009), 720745CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Powell, G. Bingham, ‘The Chain of Responsiveness’, Journal of Democracy, 15 (2004), 91105CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

15 E.g., Heath, Anthony F., Jowell, Roger M. and Curtice, John K., How Britain Votes (Oxford: Pergamon, 1985)Google Scholar; Rose, Richard and McAllister, Ian, Voters Begin to Choose (London: Sage, 1986)Google Scholar; Heath, Anthony F., Jowell, Roger M., Curtice, John K., Evans, Geoffrey, Field, Julia and Witherspoon, Sharon, Understanding Political Change (Oxford: Pergamon, 1991)Google Scholar; Clarke, Harold D., Sanders, David, Stewart, Marianne C. and Whiteley, Paul, Political Choice in Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. To be sure, issue proximity might not be the most important determinant of voting behaviour, but that is not required for present purposes.

16 Bartle, John, ‘Ideological Considerations and Voting Behaviour’, in Judith Bara and Albert Weale, eds., Democratic Politics and Party Competition (London: Routledge, 2006), pp. 203221Google Scholar.

17 Rose, Richard, Do Parties Make a Difference? 2nd edn (London: Macmillan, 1984), p. 145CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 Hofferbert, Richard I. and Budge, Ian, ‘The Party Mandate and the Westminster Model: Election Programmes and Government Spending in Britain, 1948–85’, British Journal of Political Science, 22 (1992), 151182CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 181.

19 Royed, Terry J., ‘Testing the Mandate Model in Britain and the United States: Evidence from the Reagan and Thatcher Eras’, British Journal of Political Science, 26 (1996), 4580CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20 Bartolini, Stefano, ‘Collusion, Competition, and Democracy: Part II’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 12 (2000), 3365CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 37.

21 See Castles, Francis G. and Mair, Peter, ‘Left–Right Political Scales: Some Expert Judgements’, European Journal of Political Research, 12 (1984), 7388CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Laver, Michael and W. Ben Hunt, Policy and Party Competition (New York: Routledge, 1992)Google Scholar; Huber, John D. and Inglehart, Ronald F., ‘Expert Interpretations of Party Space and Party Locations in 42 Societies’, Party Politics, 1 (1995), 73111CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Benoit, Kenneth and Laver, Michael, Party Policy in Modern Democracies (London: Routledge, 2006)Google Scholar; Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Volkens, Andrea, Bara, Judith, Budge, Ian and McDonald, Michael D., Mapping Policy Preferences II: Estimates for Parties, Electors and Governments in Easter Europe, European Union and OECD 1990–2003 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006)Google Scholar.

22 Schmidt, Manfred G., ‘When Parties Matter: A Review of the Possibilities and Limits of Partisan Influence on Public Policy’, European Journal of Political Research, 30 (1996), 155183CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

23 Soroka, and Wlezien, , ‘Degrees of Democracy’; Hobolt and Klemmensen, ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’Google Scholar.

24 Stimson, , MacKuen, and Erikson, , ‘Dynamic Representation’, p. 545Google Scholar.

25 Downs, Anthony, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper & Row, 1957), p. 28Google Scholar.

26 Friedrich, Carl J., Man and his Government (New York: McGraw Hill, 1963), p. 203Google Scholar.

27 Heath, Anthony F., Jowell, Roger M. and Curtice, John K., The Rise of New Labour (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), p. 6CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Bowler, Shaun and Farrell, David M., eds, Electoral Strategies and Political Marketing (Basingstoke, Hants.: Macmillan, 1992)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Geer, John G., From Tea Leaves to Opinion Polls: A Theory of Democratic Leadership (New York: Columbia University Press, 1996)Google Scholar.

29 Jacobs, Lawrence R., ‘The Recoil Effect: Public Opinion and Policymaking in the U.S. and Britain’, Comparative Politics, 24 (1992), 199217CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

30 Jacobs, , ‘The Recoil Effect’, pp. 208 and 213.Google Scholar

31 Ferejohn, John, ‘Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control’, Public Choice, 50 (1986), 525CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Some have argued that policy responsiveness might still occur when uncertainty is low. Parties that realize that their seats are quite safe could for example opt to respond to the public out of a sense of duty. See Bartels, Larry, ‘Constituency Opinion and Congressional Policy Making: The Reagan Defense Buildup’, American Political Science Review, 85 (1991), 457474CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32 Stimson, , MacKuen, and Erikson, , ‘Dynamic Representation’, p. 544.Google Scholar

33 Griffin, John D., ‘Electoral Competition and Democratic Responsiveness: A Defense of the Marginality Hypothesis’, Journal of Politics, 68 (2006), 911921CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 919.

34 Alt, James E., ‘Some Social and Political Correlates of County Borough Expenditures’, British Journal of Political Science, 1 (1971), 4962CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Boyne, George A., ‘Median Voters, Political Systems, and Public Policies: an Empirical Test’, Public Choice, 53 (1987), 201219CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Boyne, George A., ‘Party Competition and Local Spending Decisions’, British Journal of Political Science, 28 (1998), 185222CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35 Boyne, , ‘Party Competition and Local Spending Decisions’, p. 221Google Scholar, emphasis in original.

36 Hobolt, and Klemmensen, , ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’, p. 326Google Scholar.

37 Budge, Ian, ‘New Patterns of Party Competition?’ in Geoffrey Evans and Pippa Norris, eds, Critical Elections: British Parties and Voters in Long-term Perspective (London: Sage, 1999), pp. 121Google Scholar, at p. 4.

38 Webb, Paul D., The Modern British Party System (London: Sage, 2000), p. 111Google Scholar.

39 Webb, , The Modern British Party System, p. 111Google Scholar.

40 Benoit, and Laver, , Party Policy in Modern DemocraciesGoogle Scholar.

41 Bartle, John, Dellepiane-Avellaneda, Sebastian and StimsonJames, A. James, A., ‘The Moving Centre: Policy Preferences in Britain, 1945–2005’ (paper prepared for the General Conference of the European Consortium for Political Research, 2007Google Scholar; Soroka, and Wlezien, , ‘Opinion–Policy Dynamics’Google Scholar.

42 Brooks, Clem and Manza, Jeff, Why Welfare States Persist: The Importance of Public Opinion in Democracies (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43 The latest CMP publication is Klingemann, Volkens, Bara, Budge and McDonald, Mapping Policy Preferences II. The CMP uses human coders to classify sentences in election manifestos into more than fifty policy categories. The left–right score of each manifesto, and hence government, is calculated by subtracting the percentage of right-wing categories from the percentage of left-wing categories. The CMP scale thus has a range of −100 (for a party devoting its entire manifesto to left-wing issues) to +100 (for a party devoting its complete programme to right-wing issues). Substantively, the scale ‘opposes emphases on peaceful internationalism, welfare and government intervention of the left, to emphases on strong defence, free enterprise and traditional morality on the right’, see Budge, Ian and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, ‘Finally! Comparative Over-Time Mapping of Party Policy Movement’Google Scholar, in Budge, Ian, Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Volkens, Andrea, Bara, Judith and Tanenbaum, Eric, Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945–1998 (Oxford: Oxford University Press: 2001), pp. 1950Google Scholar, at p. 21.

44 Hobolt, and Klemmensen, , ‘Responsive Government?’ Hobolt and Klemmensen, ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’; Jennings and John, ‘The Dynamics of Political Attention’Google Scholar.

45 On average, the Budget speech is almost ten times as long as the ‘Queen’s Speech’, which is likely to contribute to the reliability of position estimates, see Laver, Michael, Benoit, Kenneth and Garry, John, ‘Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts: Using Words as Data’, American Political Science Review, 97 (2003), 311331CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Klemmensen, Robert, Hobolt, Sara B. and Hansen, Martin E., ‘Estimating Policy Positions Using Political Texts: An Evaluation of the Wordscores Approach, Electoral Studies, 26 (2007), 746755CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

46 Webb, , The Modern British Party System; Hobolt and Klemmensen, ‘Responsive Government?’; Jennings and John, ‘The Dynamics of Political Attention’Google Scholar.

47 Blais, André, Blake, Donald and Dion, Stephane, ‘Do Parties Make a Difference? Parties and the Size of Government in Liberal Democracies’, American Journal of Political Science, 37 (1993), 4062CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 43.

48 Benoit, and Laver, , Party Policy in Modern DemocraciesGoogle Scholar.

49 Laver, , Benoit, and Garry, , ‘Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts’, p. 312Google Scholar.

50 See, respectively, Proksch, Sven-Oliver and Slapin, Jonathan B., ‘Institutions and Coalition Formation: The German Election of 2005’, West European Politics, 29 (2006), 540559CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Laver, Michael, Benoit, Kenneth and Sauger, Nicolas, ‘Policy Competition in the 2002 French Legislative and Presidential Elections’, European Journal of Political Research, 45 (2006), 667697CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bertelli, Anthony M. and Grose, Christian R., ‘The Spatial Model and the Senate Trial of President Clinton’, American Politics Research, 34 (2006), 535559CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Klemmensen, , Hobolt, and Hansen, , ‘Estimating Policy Positions Using Political Texts’Google Scholar.

51 Laver, , Benoit, and Garry, , ‘Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts’, p. 330Google Scholar.

52 For a detailed exposition on Wordscores, see Laver, , Benoit, and Garry, , ‘Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts’Google Scholar.

53 In the example above, the left–right score of ‘business’ would be 0.17(2) + 0.83(7) = 6.15, which as expected lies closer to the score of the Conservative text score than the Labour text.

54 Laver, , Benoit, , and Garry, , ‘Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts’, p. 316Google Scholar.

55 Laver, Benoit, and Garry have written a Wordscores algorithm for STATA, which was used to analyse the speeches; available from www.tcd.ie/Political_Science/wordscores/.

56 Laver, , Benoit, and Garry, , ‘Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts’Google Scholar.

57 On the CMP scale, which runs from −100 on the left to +100 on the right, the respective scores for the Budget Speeches from 1987, 2005 and 1974 are 30.5, −2.9 and −48.5. These scores are identical to the left–right score of the election manifesto of the relevant governing party at that time (Conservative party in 1987 and Labour in 1974 and 2005).

58 Klemmensen, , Hobolt, and Hansen, , ‘Estimating Policy Positions Using Political Texts’Google Scholar.

59 Klingemann, et al. , Mapping Policy Preferences II, p. 104Google Scholar, fn. 6.

60 These eight combinations are 1987–2005–1974, 1987–2005–1975, 1987–1971–1974, 1987–1971–1975, 1983–2005–1974, 1983–2005–1975, 1983–1971–1974, and 1983–1971–1975.

61 In fact, factor analysis of these eight time series results in a one-factor solution with an eigenvalue of 6.93 that explains 87 per cent of the variance. All of the eight reference sets have factor loadings between 0.87 and 0.96. Comparable results are found for Danish government speeches by Klemmensen, Hobolt and Hansen, ‘Estimating Policy Positions Using Political Texts’.

62 The mean score is identical to the one-factor solution (Pearson’s r = 0.994).

63 These four sources of cross-validation are described in detail in Hakhverdian, , ‘Capturing Government Policy on the Left–Right Scale’Google Scholar.

64 The question is formulated as follows: ‘In political matters, people talk about “the Left” and “the Right”. How would you place your views on this scale, generally speaking?’ The scale runs from 1 on the left to 10 on the right.

65 Huber, John D., ‘Values and Partisanship in Left–Right Orientations: Measuring Ideology’, European Journal of Political Research, 17 (1989), 599621CrossRefGoogle Scholar, p. 618.

66 For the United Kingdom, the classic statement is Butler, David and Stokes, Donald E., Political Change in Britain, 2nd edn (London: Macmillan, 1974)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

67 Knutsen, Oddbjorn, ‘European Move towards the Centre: A Comparative Longitudinal Study of Left–Right Self-Placement in Western Europe’, International Journal of Public Opinion Research, 10 (1998), 292316CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

68 Following Stevenson, Randolph T., ‘The Economy and Public Mood: A Fundamental Dynamic of Democratic Politics?’ American Journal of Political Science, 45 (2001), 620633CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Also see Sani, Giacomo and Sartori, Giovanni, ‘Polarization, Fragmentation, and Competition in Western Democracies’, in Hans Daalder and Peter Mair, eds, Western European Party Systems (London: Sage, 1983), pp. 307340Google Scholar. This measure is only consistently available since 1976 (Eurobarometer, 5).

69 Hall, Stuart, ‘The Great Moving Right Show’, Marxism Today, January 1979, pp. 1420Google Scholar.

70 Stephens, Philip, ‘Middle Britain wants value for money’, Financial Times, 15 October 2007Google Scholar.

71 Stimson, James, Tides of Consent: How Public Opinion Shapes American Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kim, HeeMin and Fording, Richard, ‘Voter Ideology in Western Democracies, 1946–1989’, European Journal of Political Research, 33 (1998), 7397CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kellstedt, Paul, The Mass Media and the Dynamics of American Racial Attitudes (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. A question on left–right self-placement was included in the 1973 European Community Study, which was the precursor of the Eurobarometer series. The mean value for that year is 5.37, indicating that the opinion time series is distinctively sine-shaped from the early 1970s to the present.

72 Campbell, Angus, Converse, Philip E., Miller, Warren E. and Stokes, Donald E., The American Voter (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1960)Google Scholar; Converse, Philip E., ‘The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics’, in David E. Apter, ed., Ideology and Discontent (New York: Free Press, 1964), pp. 206261Google Scholar; Butler, and Stokes, , Political Change in BritainGoogle Scholar.

73 Durr, Robert H., ‘What Moves Policy Sentiment?’ American Political Science Review, 87 (1993), 158170CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stevenson, , ‘The Economy and Public Mood’Google Scholar.

74 Pearson’s r equals 0.40, 0.74 and 0.85, respectively for these economic indicators. The ‘Misery Index’ represents the sum of unemployment and inflation and it is used by some as a proxy for the state of the economy. See Franklin, and Wlezien, , ‘The Responsive Public’; Soroka and Wlezien, ‘Opinion-Policy Dynamics’Google Scholar.

75 Wlezien, , ‘The Public as Thermostat’; Franklin and Wlezien, ‘The Responsive Public’; Stevenson, ‘The Economy and Public Mood’Google Scholar; Erikson, Robert S., Michael B. MacKuen and James A. Stimson, The Macro Polity (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002)Google Scholar; Soroka, and Wlezien, , ‘Opinion–Policy Dynamics’Google Scholar.

76 Soroka, and Wlezien, , ‘Opinion–Policy Dynamics’, p. 666Google Scholar.

77 E.g., Evans, Geoffrey, Heath, Anthony F. and Lalljee, Mansur, ‘Measuring Left–Right and Libertarian–Authoritarian Values in the British Electorate’, British Journal of Sociology, 47 (1996), 93112CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

78 Evans, , Heath, and Lalljee, , ‘Measuring Left–Right and Libertarian–Authoritarian Values in the British Electorate’, p. 98Google Scholar.

79 See Stimson, , MacKuen, and Erikson, , ‘Dynamic Representation’, p. 546Google Scholar. In the bivariate case, x ‘Granger causes’ y if past values of x contain information that helps predict y above and beyond the information contained in past values of y alone. For present purposes, lagged opinion adds to predicting policy, while the reverse does not hold. These results are available upon request.

80 Stimson, , MacKuen, and Erikson, , ‘Dynamic Representation’Google Scholar; Smith, , ‘Public Opinion, Elections and Representation within a Market Economy: Does the Structural Power of Business Undermine Popular Sovereignty?’, American Journal of Political Science, 46 (1999), 842863CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wlezien, Christopher, ‘Patterns of Representation: Dynamics of Public Preferences and Policy’, Journal of Politics, 66 (2004), 124CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Soroka, and Wlezien, , ‘Opinion–Policy Dynamics’; Hobolt and Klemmensen, ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’Google Scholar.

81 Assuming, of course, that the first stage of electoral turnover is met (the coincidence of right-wing mood and Conservative election victories).

82 Hobolt, and Klemmensen, , ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’Google Scholar (data are taken from the Gallup Poll (pre-1980) and Ipsos-MORI). These polls have monthly data on party support, so an annual mean is a more reliable measure than one item from the Eurobarometer.

83 A similar logic concerning American presidential responsiveness is used by Hicks, Alexander, ‘Elections, Keynes, Bureaucracy and Class: Explaining U.S. Budget Deficits, 1961–1978’, American Sociological Review, 49 (1984), 165182CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hibbs, Douglas A. Jr, The American Political Economy: Macroeconomics and Electoral Politics (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1987)Google Scholar.

84 See Hendry, David F., Dynamic Econometrics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; DeBoef, Suzanna and Keele, Luke, ‘Taking Time Seriously’, American Journal of Political Science, 52 (2008), 184200Google Scholar.

85 DeBoef, and Keele, , ‘Taking Time Seriously’, p. 185Google Scholar.

86 Similar post-war policy trends for Anglo-Saxon democracies are found by Budge, Ian and McDonald, Michael D., ‘Election and Party System Effects on Political Representation: Bringing Time into a Comparative Perspective’, Electoral Studies, 26 (2007), 168179CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

87 Budge, and McDonald, , ‘Election and Party System Effects on Political Representation’, p. 171Google Scholar, fn. 1.

88 Budge, and McDonald, , ‘Election and Party System Effects on Political Representation’, p. 171Google Scholar, fn. 1.

89 These results are not reported here, because differencing has serious disadvantages. Most notably, it becomes impossible to identify long-term dynamic effects.

90 Hailsham, Lord, Elective Dictatorship (London: BBC, 1976)Google Scholar.

91 A skeletal model was estimated with Conservative party seat share as the dependent variable and left–right self-placement as the independent variable, while controlling for party identification. This design has obvious limits, not least because we only have seven points of observation, but the results confirm the link between macro-level public preferences and election outcomes. Similar results are found with vote shares on the left-hand side of the equation and whether or not public preferences are lagged one year. Election results were acquired from Rallings, Colin and Thrasher, Michael, British Electoral Facts, 1832–2006 (Aldershot, Surrey: Ashgate, 2006)Google Scholar. The party identification data were taken from the British Election Studies. Conservative Seat Sharet = 159.3 + 0.6 Macropartisanshipt + 33.6 Public Preferencest. All coefficients are statistically significant and the adjusted R 2 = 0.92. As the public moves to the right with one standard deviation, the Conservative party’s share of seats increases by 0.30 × 33.6 = 10.1. The size of the House of Commons fluctuates around 640 seats, and therefore 10 per cent is roughly equal to 60 seats.

92 Brambor, Thomas, Clark, William R. and Golder, Matt, ‘Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses’, Political Analysis, 14 (2006), 6382CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

93 Some have argued that the relationship between policy responsiveness and popularity is Λ-shaped, or non-monotonic, see Canes-Wrone, Brandice and Shotts, Kenneth W., ‘The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion’, American Journal of Political Science, 48 (2004), 690706CrossRefGoogle Scholar. In other words, both highly popular and unpopular governments are said to reduce the likelihood of responsiveness. However, using the present data, no evidence of non-linearity of the conditional effect of opinion on policy is found.

94 E.g., Lijphart, , Patterns of Democracy; G. Bingham Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 2000)Google Scholar.

95 Andersen, Christopher, ‘The Dynamics of Public Support for Coalition Governments’, Comparative Political Studies, 28 (1995), 350383CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

97 Downs, , An Economic Theory of Democracy, p. 237Google Scholar.

98 Dahl, Robert A., Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1961), p. 1Google Scholar.

99 Bartels, Larry, Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2008)Google Scholar; Gilens, Martin, ‘Inequality and Democratic Responsiveness’, Public Opinion Quarterly, 69 (2005), 778796CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

100 Manza, and Cook, , ‘A Democratic Polity?’ p. 658Google Scholar.

101 Powell, , Elections as Instruments of Democracy; Soroka and Wlezien, ‘Degrees of Democracy’; Hobolt and Klemmensen, ‘Government Responsiveness and Political Competition in Comparative Perspective’Google Scholar.