Article contents
Electoral Systems, Voters’ Interests and Geographic Dispersion
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 02 April 2012
Abstract
There is general agreement that democratic institutions shape politicians’ incentives to cater to certain constituencies, but which electoral system causes politicians to be most responsive to narrow interests is still debateable. Some argue that plurality electoral rules provide the greatest incentives for politicians to cater to the interests of a few; others say proportional systems prompt politicians to be relatively more prone to narrow interests. This study suggests that both positions can be correct under different conditions. Politicians competing in plurality systems privilege voters with a shared narrow interest when such voters are geographically concentrated, but when they are geographically diffuse, such voters have greater political influence in proportional electoral systems. Government spending on subsidies in fourteen developed countries provides empirical support for this argument.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012
Footnotes
London School of Economics (email: [email protected]). This article was conceived of while the author was a visitor at the Institute for International Integration Studies, Trinity College Dublin. She wishes to thank Philip Lane, Kevin O'Rourke and Ken Benoit for their hospitality, and is particularly grateful to Kevin O'Rourke for his invaluable suggestions and encouragement and to Marius Brülhart for generously sharing his data. An online appendix can be viewed at http://www.journals.cambridge.org/jps; and supplementary tables and replication data are available at http://personal.lse.ac.uk/RICKARD/research.html.
References
1 Franzese, Robert J., Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
2 Kono, Daniel Yuichi, ‘Market Structure, Electoral Institutions, and Trade Policy’, International Studies Quarterly, 53 (2009), 885–906CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanan, ‘A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120 (2005), 1239–1282CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, Torsten and Tabellini, Guido, The Economic Effects of Constitutions (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milesi-Ferretti, Gian MariaPerotti, Roberto and Rostagno, Massimo, ‘Electoral Systems and Public Spending’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (2002), 609–665CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lizzeri, Alessandro and Persico, Nicola, ‘The Provision of Public Goods under Alternative Electoral Incentives’, American Economic Review, 91 (2001), 225–239CrossRefGoogle Scholar
3 Hays, Jude C., Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald and Kayser, Mark A., ‘Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power: Price-level Evidence from the OECD Countries’, American Journal of Political Science, 46 (2002), 526–539CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, EricKayser, Mark A. and Rogowski, Ronald, ‘Electoral Systems and Real Prices: Panel Evidence for the OECD Countries’, British Journal of Political Science, 38 (2008), 739–751CrossRefGoogle Scholar
4 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions.
5 Perdikis, Nicholas and Read, Roberteds, The WTO and the Regulation of International Trade: Recent Trade Disputes between the European Union and the United States (Cheltenham, Glos.: Edward Elgar, 2005)Google Scholar
6 Peter Nelson and Matt Ryder, Forestry Sector Study, Report prepared for the European Commission under Contract No: Trade 05-G3-01 (2007); International Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 2001). The forest sector comprises all industries that are interlinked by the common resource or commodity, wood.
7 Cox, Gary W., ‘Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems’, American Journal of Political Science, 34 (1990), 903–935CrossRefGoogle Scholar
8 Cox, ‘Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems’, p. 906Google Scholar
9 Kono, ‘Market Structure, Electoral Institutions, and Trade Policy’; Grossman and Helpman, ‘A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics’; Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions; Lizzeri and Persico, ‘The Provision of Public Goods under Alternative Electoral Incentives’.
10 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions.
11 Hays, Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism; Rogowski and Kayser, ‘Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power’; Chang, Kayser and Rogowski, ‘Electoral Systems and Real Prices’.
12 Rogowski and Kayser, ‘Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power’; Chang, Kayser and Rogowski, ‘Electoral Systems and Real Prices’.
13 Rogowski and Kayser, ‘Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power’; Chang, Kayser and Rogowski, ‘Electoral Systems and Real Prices’.
14 Rogowski and Kayser, ‘Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power’; Chang, Kayser and Rogowski, ‘Electoral Systems and Real Prices’.
15 Pagano, Marco and Volpin, Paolo F., ‘The Political Economy of Corporate Governance’, American Economic Review, 95 (2005), 1005–1030CrossRefGoogle Scholar
16 Mansfield, Edward and Busch, Marc, ‘The Political Economy of Nontariff Barriers: A Cross National Analysis,’ International Organization, 49 (1995), 723–749CrossRefGoogle Scholar
17 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions.
18 Evans, Carolyn L., ‘A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics’, Economics & Politics, 21 (2009), 278–307CrossRefGoogle Scholar
19 Rickard, Stephanie J., ‘Democratic Differences: Electoral Institutions and Compliance with GATT/WTO Agreement’, European Journal of International Relations, 16 (2010), 711–729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
20 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions.
21 Stephanie J. Rickard, ‘A Non-Tariff Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics: Government Subsidies and Electoral Institutions’, International Studies Quarterly, forthcoming.
22 Grossman and Helpman, ‘A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics’.
23 McGillivray, Fiona, ‘Party Discipline as a Determinant of the Endogenous Formation of Tariffs’, American Journal of Political Science, 41 (1997), 584–607CrossRefGoogle Scholar
24 McGillivray, Fiona, Privileging Industry: The Comparative Politics of Trade and Industrial Policy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
25 Hansen, Wendy L., ‘The International Trade Commission and the Politics of Protectionism’, American Political Science Review, 84 (1990), 21–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
26 Mansfield, Edward D. and Milner, Helen V.eds, The Political Economy of Regionalism (New York: Columbia University Press, 1997)Google Scholar
27 McGillivray, ‘Party Discipline as a Determinant of the Endogenous Formation of Tariffs’, p. 604Google Scholar
28 Hiscox, Michael J., International Trade and Political Conflict (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
29 Singer, David A., ‘Capital Rules: The Domestic Politics of International Regulatory Harmonization’, International Organization, 58 (2004), 531–565CrossRefGoogle Scholar
30 Duchêne, François and Shepherd, Geoffreyeds, Managing Industrial Change in Western Europe (London: Frances Pinter, 1987)Google Scholar
31 Duchêne and Shepherd, ‘Sources of Industrial Policy’.
32 This may be particularly true in PR systems that require a party to achieve a minimum percentage of votes to receive any legislative seats. Typically, this threshold is between 2 and 5 per cent of the number of votes cast. Parties which do not reach that level of support gain no representation in parliament.
33 Carlsson, Bo, ‘Industrial Subsidies in Sweden: Macro-Economic Effects and an International Comparison’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 32 (1983), 1–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
34 This type of spending, often referred to as ‘pork barrel’ spending, frequently reflects discretionary spending decisions. See Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions, p. 14.
35 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions, p. 14.
36 Dale T. Mortensen and Christopher A. Pissarides, ‘Taxes, Subsidies and Equilibrium Labour Market Outcomes’ (CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2989, 2001).
37 Mortensen and Pissarides, ‘Taxes, Subsidies and Equilibrium Labour Market Outcomes’.
38 Frieden, Jeffry A.Lake, David A. and Schultz, Kenneth A., World Politics: Interests, Interactions, Institutions (London: W. W. Norton & Co., 2010)Google Scholar
Beghin, John C., Osta, Barbara ElCherlow, Jay R. and Mohanty, Samarendu, ‘The Cost of the US Sugar Program Revisited’, Contemporary Economic Policy, 21 (2003), 106–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
39 Beghin, El Osta, Cherlow and Mohanty, ‘The Cost of the US Sugar Program Revisited’.
40 These spending data come from the International Monetary Fund's Government Financial Statistics. These data include all fiscal outlays targeted to the manufacturing sector. For example, all subsidies, grants, and subsidized loans provided to the manufacturing sector to support manufacturing enterprises and/or development, expansion or improvement of manufacturing are included. Although conventional government accounts are generally not suitable for comparisons between countries and over time, because they reflect the organizational structures of governments, these data, uniquely compiled by the IMF, allow meaningful cross-national comparisons over time. For additional information, see International Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics Manual (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 2001).
41 Rogowski and Kayser, ‘Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power’.
42 McGillivray, Privileging Industry.
43 Rodriguez, Francisco and Rodrik, Dani, ‘Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-national Evidence’, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15 (2000), 261–325CrossRefGoogle Scholar
44 Milesi-Ferreti, Rostagno and Perotti, ‘Electoral Systems and Public Spending’.
45 Persson, Torsten and Tabellini, Guido, ‘The Size and Scope of Government: Comparative Politics with Rational Politicians’, European Economic Review, 43 (1999), 699–735CrossRefGoogle Scholar
46 Robert Ford and Win Suyker, ‘Industrial Subsidies in the OECD Economies’, OECD Department of Economics and Statistics Working Papers, No. 74 (Paris: OECD Publications, 1990); OECD, Improving the Environment through Reducing Subsidies (Paris: OECD Publications, 1998).
47 International Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 2001); Shenggen Fan and Neetha Rao, ‘Public Spending in Developing Countries’, EPTD Discussion Paper No. 99 (Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute, 2003).
48 Blais, André, ‘The Political Economy of Public Subsidies’, Comparative Political Studies, 19 (1986), 201–217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verdier, Daniel, ‘The Politics of Public Aid to Private Industry’, Comparative Political Studies, 28 (1995), 3–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E., Carlsen, FredrikHeum, Per and Johansen, Kåre, ‘Asset Specificity and the Political Behavior of Firms: Lobbying for Subsidies in Norway’, International Organization, 53 (1999), 99–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zahariadis, Nikolaos, ‘Asset Specificity and State Subsidies in Industrialized Countries’, International Studies Quarterly, 45 (2001), 603–616CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aydin, Umut, ‘Promoting Industries in the Global Economy: Subsidies in OECD Countries, 1989 to 1995’, Journal of European Public Policy, 14 (2007), 115–131CrossRefGoogle Scholar
49 Brülhart, Marius and Traeger, Rolf, ‘An Account of Geographic Concentration Patterns in Europe’, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35 (2005), 597–624CrossRefGoogle Scholar
50 Busch, Marc L. and Reinhardt, Eric, ‘Industrial Location and Protection: The Political and Economic Geography of U.S. Nontariff Barriers’, American Journal of Political Science, 43 (1999), 1028–1050CrossRefGoogle Scholar
51 It is not, however, a measure of political concentration. At present, measures of political concentration are only possible in the data-rich United States.
52 Unfortunately, due to data limitations mapping the geographic dispersion of manufacturing employment into electoral districts is not possible for even the limited sample of countries under investigation here.
53 Bawn, Kathleen and Rosenbluth, Frances, ‘Short Versus Long Coalitions: Electoral Accountability and the Size of the Public Sector’, American Journal of Political Science, 50 (2006), 251–265CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, TorstenRolland, Gerard and Tabellini, Guido, ‘Electoral Rules and Government Spending in Parliamentary Democracies’, Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2 (2007), 155–188CrossRefGoogle Scholar
54 The 14 sample countries are: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom.
55 Beck, Thorsten, Clarke, George, Groff, AlbertoKeefer, Philip and Walsh, Patrick, ‘New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions’, World Bank Economic Review, 15 (2001), 165–176CrossRefGoogle Scholar
56 Shugart, Matthew and Wattenberg, Martineds, Mixed-Member Electoral Systems: The Best of Both Worlds? (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001)Google Scholar
Thames, Frank C. and Edwards, Martin S., ‘Differentiating Mixed-Member Electoral Systems’, Comparative Political Studies, 39 (2006), 905–927CrossRefGoogle Scholar
57 Shugart and Wattenberg, ‘Mixed-Member Electoral Systems’.
58 Moser, Robert G., ‘The Effects of Electoral Systems on Women's Representation in Post-communist States’, Electoral Studies, 20 (2001), 353–369CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Karen and Schoppa, Len, ‘Interaction Effects and Mixed Member Systems: Theory and Evidence from Germany, Japan and Italy’, Comparative Political Studies, 35 (2002), 1027–1053CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrara, Frederico and Herron, Erik, ‘Going it Alone? Strategic Entry Under Mixed Electoral Rules’, American Journal of Political Science, 49 (2005), 16–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
59 This measure is calculated for each country-election-year. For non-election years, the least squares index from the most recent previous election is used. If two elections occur in the same year, the average of the least squares index (LSq) for that country-year is used.
60 These data are from Joel W. Johnson and Jessica S. Wallack, ‘Electoral Systems and the Personal Vote’, available at http://polisci2.ucsd.edu/jwjohnson/espv.htm (accessed 14 April 2011).
61 Johnson and Wallack, ‘Electoral Systems and the Personal Vote’.
62 Bawn and Rosenbluth, ‘Short Versus Long Coalitions’.
63 Stephanie J. Rickard, ‘Welfare versus Subsidies: Governmental Spending Decisions in an Era of Globalization’ (unpublished manuscript, London School of Economics and Political Science, 2011).
64 Ronald Rogowski, ‘Pork, Patronage, and Protection: How Geographic Concentration Affects Representation of Interests in Small-District Systems’ (UCLA, unpublished manuscript, 1997).
65 Blais, André and Massicotte, Louis, ‘Electoral Formulas: A Macroscopic Perspective’, European Journal of Political Research, 32 (1997), 107–129CrossRefGoogle Scholar
66 Dixit, Avinash and Londregan, John, ‘The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics’, Journal of Politics, 58 (1996), 1132–1155CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar and Weibull, Jorgen, ‘Balanced Budget Redistribution and the Outcome of Political Competition’, Public Choice, 52 (1987), 273–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
67 Huber, EvelyneRagin, Charles and Stephens, John D., ‘Social Democracy, Christian Democracy, Constitutional Structure and the Welfare State’, American Journal of Sociology, 99 (1993), 711–749CrossRefGoogle Scholar
68 Persson and Tabellini, The Economics Effects of Constitutions.
69 Persson and Tabellini, The Economics Effects of Constitutions.
70 McGillivray, Privileging Industry.
71 Verdier, ‘The Politics of Public Aid to Private Industry’.
72 Iversen, Torben and Soskice, David, ‘Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More than Others’, American Political Science Review, 100 (2006), 165–181CrossRefGoogle Scholar
73 Ronald Rogowski, Mark A. Kayser, and Daniel Kotin, ‘How Geographical Concentration Affects Industrial Influences: Evidence from US Data’ (unpublished manuscript, UCLA, 1999), 1–23, p. 7; McGillivray, Privileging Industry, pp. 15–16.
74 Brambor, ThomasClark, William Roberts and Golder, Matt, ‘Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses’, Political Analysis, 14 (2006), 63–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, Robert J. and Kam, Cindy D., Modelling and Interpreting Interactive Hypotheses in Regression Analyses (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2007)Google Scholar
75 Cox, Gary W. and McCubbins, Mathew D., ‘Electoral Politics as a Redistributive Game’, Journal of Politics, 48 (1986), 370–389CrossRefGoogle Scholar
76 Aiken and West, Multiple Regression: Testing and Interpreting Interactions (London: Sage Publications, 1991)Google Scholar
77 Brambor, Clark and Golder, ‘Understanding Interaction Models’, p. 76Google Scholar
78 Garrett, Geoffrey, ‘Globalization and Government Spending Around the World’, Studies in Comparative International Development, 35 (2001), 3–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita, ‘Globalization and the Decline of the Welfare State in Less-Developed Countries’, International Organization, 56 (2002), 411–445CrossRefGoogle Scholar
79 Rickard, ‘Welfare versus Subsidies’.
80 Dixit and Londregan, ‘The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics’; Lindbeck and Weibull, ‘Balanced Budget Redistribution and the Outcome of Political Competition’.
81 For example, excluding the United Kingdom from the sample does not change the key results. Similarly, the key results are robust to alternative model specifications including ordinary least squares (OLS) models with Driscoll–Kraay standard errors and the Newey and West estimator with lag length 1. These results are reported in an online appendix.
82 This holds for approximately 10 per cent of the sample.
83 Boix, Carles, ‘Setting the Rules of the Game: The Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies’, American Political Science Review, 93 (1999), 609–624CrossRefGoogle Scholar
84 Cusack, Thomas R.Iversen, Torben and Soskice, David, ‘Economic Interests and the Origins of Electoral Systems’, American Political Science Review, 101 (2007), 373–391CrossRefGoogle Scholar
85 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions; Evans, ‘A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics’.
86 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions.
87 Persson and Tabellini, The Economic Effects of Constitutions, demonstrate that these periods best describe the pattern of electoral system adaptation.
88 If anything, correcting for potential endogeneity appears to reduce the standard errors on the estimated marginal effect of PR.
89 Wacziarg, Romain and Wallack, Jessica Seddon, ‘Trade Liberalization and Intersectoral Labor Movements’, Journal of International Economics, 64 (2004), 411–439CrossRefGoogle Scholar
90 However, Rickard finds evidence that labour mobility mediates the effect of electoral rules on governments’ willingness to provide narrow transfers in violation of GATT/WTO rules. As the costs of adjustment increase, the number of narrow transfers increases in both PR and majoritarian systems.
Rickard, Stephanie J., ‘Strategic Targeting: The Effect of Institutions and Interests on Distributive Transfers’, Comparative Political Studies, 42 (2009), 670–695CrossRefGoogle Scholar
91 Bawn and Rosenbluth, ‘Short Versus Long Coalitions’.
92 Robert J. Franzese, ‘Effective Representation in Democratic Policymaking’ (unpublished manuscript, University of Michigan: 2008).
- 52
- Cited by