Published online by Cambridge University Press: 13 April 2018
William Harvey's famous quantitative argument from De motu cordis (1628) about the circulation of blood explained how a small amount of blood could recirculate and nourish the entire body, upending the Galenic conception of the blood's motion. This paper argues that the quantitative argument drew on the calculative and rhetorical skills of merchants, including Harvey's own brothers. Modern translations of De motu cordis obscure the language of accountancy that Harvey himself used. Like a merchant accounting for credits and debits, intake and output, goods and moneys, Harvey treated venous and arterial blood as essentially commensurate, quantifiable and fungible. For Harvey, the circulation (and recirculation) of blood was an arithmetical necessity. The development of Harvey's circulatory model followed shifts in the epistemic value of mercantile forms of knowledge, including accounting and arithmetic, also drawing on an Aristotelian language of reciprocity and balance that Harvey shared with mercantile advisers to the royal court. This paper places Harvey's calculations in a previously underappreciated context of economic crisis, whose debates focused largely on questions of circulation.
1 Harvey, William, Exercitatio Anatomica de Motu Cordis et Sanguinis in Animalibus, Frankfurt, 1628, p. 43CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
2 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 48.
3 Bylebyl, Jerome J., ‘The growth of Harvey's De motu cordis’, Bulletin of the History of Medicine (1973) 47(5), pp. 427–490, 433Google ScholarPubMed. For Bylebyl, Harvey built notably on the work of Colombo, who had treated the ‘left ventricle … as a complete functional analogue of the right ventricle’. As Bylebyl argued, this meant that in the context of a heart with an imperforate septum, systole pushed forth blood through the right heart and pulmonary circulation, and into the left heart and systemic circulation. This symmetry between right and left heart, and pulmonary and systemic circulations, pushed ‘a minority of late Renaissance physicians’ to begin to ‘approximate the modern concepts of the movement of blood through the hearts, lungs, and arteries’.
4 Robert Frank has provided a summary of the state of the literature, which, although published two decades ago, remains relevant: ‘Sometime about 1625 or 1626 Harvey seems to have realized – by what course of reasoning is still under scholarly debate – that his concepts of the heart's motion had an unforeseen, yet necessary, consequence: the blood of vertebrates must circulate throughout the body’. See Frank, Robert G., ‘Viewing the body: reframing man and disease in Commonwealth and Restoration England’, in Marshall, W. Gerald (ed.), The Restoration Mind, Newark: University of Delaware Press, 1997, pp. 65–110, 71Google Scholar, original emphasis. Jerome Bylebyl demonstrated similarly that Harvey's description of the systemic circulation and his quantitative argument in particular emerged subsequent to the 1616 Prelectiones on anatomy, after Harvey began his career as a courtier; see Bylebyl, op. cit. (3), pp. 427–490, 439–440.
5 Jevons, F.R., ‘Harvey's quantitative method’, Bulletin of the History of Medicine (1962) 36, pp. 462–466Google ScholarPubMed; Kilgour, Frederick G., ‘William Harvey's use of the quantitative method’, Yale Journal of Biology and Medicine (1954) 26, pp. 462–467Google ScholarPubMed.
6 Bylebyl, Jerome J., ‘Nutrition, quantification and circulation’, Bulletin of the History of Medicine (1977) 51, pp. 369–384Google ScholarPubMed; Shank, Michael H., ‘From Galen's ureters to Harvey's veins’, Journal of the History of Biology (1985) 18, pp. 331–355CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.
7 Bates, Don, ‘Closing the circle: how Harvey and his contemporaries played the game of truth, part 1’, History of Science (1998) 36, pp. 213–232CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bates, ‘Closing the circle: how Harvey and his contemporaries played the game of truth, part 2’, History of Science (1998) 36, pp. 245–267CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
8 The possibility of economic metaphors – but not commercial ways of thinking – was suggested briefly in Webster, Charles, ‘William Harvey and the crisis of medicine in Jacobean England’, in Bylebyl, Jerome J. (ed.), William Harvey and His Age: The Professional and Social Context of the Discovery of the Circulation, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 1–27, 27 n. 84Google Scholar. Various works on aquatic metaphors include Pagel, Walter, William Harvey's Biological Ideas: Selected Aspects and Historical Background, Basel: S. Karger, 1967, pp. 82–90Google Scholar; French, Roger, William Harvey's Natural Philosophy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994, pp. 357–360CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed; Pulkkinen, Jarmo, ‘The role of metaphors in William Harvey's thought’, in Zittel, Claus, Engel, Gisela, Nanni, Romano and Karafyllis, Nicole C. (eds.), Philosophies of Technology: Francis Bacon and His Contemporaries, Leiden: Brill, 2008, pp. 266–273Google Scholar.
9 Cook, Harold J., Matters of Exchange: Commerce, Medicine, and Science in the Dutch Golden Age, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2007CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Harkness, Deborah, The Jewel House: Elizabethan London and the Scientific Revolution, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2007Google Scholar; Schiebinger, Londa and Swan, Claudia (eds.), Colonial Botany: Science, Commerce, and Politics in the Early Modern World, Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2004Google Scholar; Kaye, Joel, Economy and Nature in the Fourteenth Century: Money, Market Exchange, and the Emergence of Scientific Thought, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000Google Scholar.
10 Power, D'Arcy, William Harvey, London: T. Fisher Unwin, 1897, p. 114Google Scholar.
11 Hofmann's critique of Harvey is summarized in French, op. cit. (8), pp. 92–93. Hofmann called Harvey a logistician (logist/a), a mere accountant who tricked his ‘ignorant’ spectators into believing they ‘have seen miracles’. Thomas Blount's 1661 Glossographia defined the logists as ‘ten men, elected out of the Tribes’ among the Athenians who ‘were to render an account of all such affairs as they had then adminstration of; They not only kept the moneys, but of all other matters appertained to the Kings revenue’. See Caspar Hofmann to William Harvey, undated, in Whitteridge, Gwyneth (ed.), William Harvey and the Circulation of the Blood, New York: Elsevier, 1971, pp. 240–241Google Scholar; Blount, Thomas, Glossographia, London, 1661Google Scholar.
12 The general thrust of other early critiques was broadly similar to Hofmann's, if less severe, as in Ole Worm's concern over the use of quantification in lieu of a lack of observable evidence; see Grell, Ole Peter, ‘In search of true knowledge: Ole Worm (1588–1654) and the new philosophy’, in Smith, Pamela H. and Schmidt, Benjamin (eds.), Making Knowledge in Early Modern Europe: Practices, Objects, and Texts, 1400–1800, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2007, pp. 214–232, 232Google Scholar.
13 Harvey's use of mathematics constituted a transgression of disciplinary boundaries, reminiscent of those made by Kepler or Galileo, whose application of mathematics to astronomy was thought inappropriate. Like Galileo, Harvey made this transgression among royal patrons, where the lesser arts of accounting and arithmetic had different epistemic value; see Biagioli, Mario, Galileo, Courtier: The Practice of Science in the Culture of Absolutism, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1993, p. 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On Kepler see Jardine, Nicholas, ‘The forging of modern realism: Clavius and Kepler against the sceptics’, Studies in the History and Philosophy of Science (1979) 10, pp. 141–173Google Scholar. For one of the seminal studies on these disciplinary boundaries see Westman, Robert S., ‘The astronomer's role in the sixteenth century: a preliminary study’, History of Science (1980) 18, pp. 105–147CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
14 Examples include Thomas Hobbes describing a theory of philosophy in De corpore (1655) under the rubric ‘computatio sive logica’. The term computatio is generally construed as meaning ‘reckoning’, but having a philosophic use in some texts, such as De corpore.
15 Vickers, Brian (ed.), Francis Bacon: Major Works, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1996, p. 302Google Scholar.
16 Milton, John, The Works: Historical, Political, and Miscellaneous, vol. 2, London, 1753, p. 498Google Scholar.
17 Milton, op. cit. (16), p. 498.
18 Milton, op. cit. (16), p. 498.
19 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 47.
20 Harvey, William, Movement of the Heart and Blood in Animals: An Anatomical Essay (tr. Franklin, Kenneth J.), Springfield, IL: Charles C. Thomas, 1957, p. 68Google Scholar.
21 Harvey, William, The Anatomical Exercises of Dr. William Harvey Professor of Physick, and Physician to the Kings Majesty, Concerning the motion of the Heart and Blood, London, 1653, p. 57Google Scholar.
22 Bates, Don, ‘Harvey's account of his discovery’, Medical History (1992) 36, pp. 361–378, 367–368CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.
23 Lewis, Charlton T. and Short, Charles (eds.), A Latin Dictionary Founded on Andrews’ Edition of Freund's Latin Dictionary, Revised, Enlarged, and in Great Part Rewritten, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1879, p. 395Google Scholar; Latham, R.E. (ed.), Revised Medieval Latin Word-List from British and Irish Sources, with Supplement, London: The British Academy, 1980, p. 102Google Scholar.
24 Niermeyer, J.F., van de Kieft, C. and Burgers, J.W.J. (eds.), Mediae Latinitatis Lexicon Minus, 2nd edn, 2 vols., Leiden: Brill, 1976–2002, vol. 1, p. 305Google Scholar.
25 Niermeyer, op. cit. (24), vol. 1, p. 305.
26 Lewis and Short, op. cit. (23), p. 1525; see also ‘computation, n’, OED Online, June 2017, which includes the definitions ‘The action or process of computing, reckoning, or counting; arithmetical or mathematical calculation; an instance of this’, dated to the fifteenth century onwards, and ‘A computed number or amount, a reckoning’, dated first to 1586 and onward, and relating sometimes but not exclusively to money.
27 Lewis and Short, op. cit. (23), p. 1774.
28 William Harvey, Exercitatio Anatomica de Motu Cordis et Sanguinis in Animalibus (tr. Robert Willis), in The Works of William Harvey: Physician to the King, Professor of Anatomy and Surgery to the College of Physicians (ed. Willis, Robert), London: Sydenham Society, 1847, pp. 1–86, 53Google Scholar.
29 Mun, Thomas, England's benefit and advantage, London, 1698, p. 4Google Scholar.
30 Mun, op. cit. (29), p. 4.
31 Mun, op. cit. (29), pp. 4–7.
32 Finkelstein, Andrea, Harmony and the Balance: An Intellectual History of Seventeenth-Century English Economic Thought, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2000, p. 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Finkelstein likewise treats Malynes as distinct, as Malynes ‘actually belonged to the generation prior to that of his opponents’.
33 On the Aristotelianism of all three see Wennerlind, Carl, Casualties of Credit: The English Financial Revolution, 1620–1720, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2011, pp. 17–43, esp. 43CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
34 ‘Several treatises and notes relating to foreign exchanges, and to the balance of trade; 1622–23’, BL Add. MSS 34324, ff. 153–178, 153r.
35 ‘Several treatises and notes relating to foreign exchanges, and to the balance of trade; 1622–23’, op. cit. (34), f. 153r.
36 Malynes, Gerard, The maintenance of free trade, London, 1622, pp. 32–34Google Scholar.
37 Though produced by a committee of merchants, this tract followed Mun's writings on the economy closely; see Supple, Barry, Commercial Crisis and Change in England, 1600–1642, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1964, p. 269Google Scholar.
38 ‘Several treatises and notes relating to foreign exchanges, and to the balance of trade; 1622–23’, op. cit. (34), f. 155r.
39 ‘Several treatises and notes relating to foreign exchanges, and to the balance of trade; 1622–23’, op. cit. (34), f. 155r.
40 Thomas Mun, A discourse of trade, London, 1621, p. 20.
41 Mun, op. cit. (40), p. 20.
42 Mun, op. cit. (40), p. 20.
43 Mun, op. cit. (40), p. 20.
44 Mun, op. cit. (40), p. 27.
45 Yamey, Basil S., ‘Daniel Harvey's ledger, 1623–1646, in context’, Accounting, Business, & Financial History (2010) 20, pp. 163–176CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Yamey, ‘Duplicate accounting records: historical notes’, Accounting History Review (2006) 16, pp. 447–455Google Scholar.
46 John Williams to Daniel Harvey, 23 December 1645, loose scrap contained in ‘Ledger, Daniel Harvey and Company, 1623–1646’, LMA CLC/B/227/MS35025; ‘Subsidiary accounts of Daniel Harvey and company's agent in Rouen, 1631–1633’, LMA CLC/B/227/MS35025a.
47 ‘Subsidiary accounts of Daniel Harvey and company's agent in Rouen, 1631–1633’, LMA CLC/B/227/MS35025a.
48 A similar shorthand is described in later treatises on arithmetic; see, for example, Abram, John, A Complete Treatise on Practical Arithmetic: Containing, Besides the Common Rules, New Principles of Mental, Visual, and Expeditious Calculation, Canterbury: S. Prentice, 1842, pp. 121–122Google Scholar.
49 Thomas, Keith, ‘Numeracy in early modern England: the Prothero Lecture’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society (1987) 37, pp. 103–132, 111Google Scholar.
50 ‘Dr. Wallis's Account of some Passages of his own Life’, in Hearne, Thomas (ed.), Peter Langtoft's Chronicle, Oxford: 1725, pp. cxl–clxx, cxlvii–cxlviiiGoogle Scholar.
51 Hunt, Margaret, ‘Time-management, writing, and accounting in the eighteenth-century English trading family: a bourgeois enlightenment’, Business and Economic History (1989) 18, pp. 150–159, 156–157Google Scholar.
52 Aubrey, John, Brief Lives, with an Apparatus for the Lives of Our English Mathematical Writers (ed. Bennett, Kate), Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2015, p. 198Google Scholar.
53 Feingold, Mordechai, The Mathematician's Apprenticeship: Science, Universities, and Society in England, 1560–1640, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984, pp. 82, 114–115Google Scholar.
54 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 43.
55 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 43.
56 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 43.
57 ‘Several treatises and notes relating to foreign exchanges, and to the balance of trade; 1622–23’, op. cit. (39), f. 169r.
58 See Mun, Thomas, England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, London, 1664, pp. 94–104Google Scholar; Misselden, Edward, The circle of commerce, or the ballance of trade, London, 1623, p. 105Google Scholar.
59 Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 16.
60 Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 17.
61 Misselden, op. cit. (58).
62 Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 69.
63 Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 28.
64 Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 28.
65 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 47.
66 Harvey, op. cit. (1), pp. 127–129, original emphasis.
67 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 130.
68 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 43.
69 Mun, op. cit. (58), p. 20.
70 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 42.
71 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 46.
72 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 46.
73 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 46.
74 Annals of the Royal College of Physicians, London: Royal College of Physicians of London, 1518–1915, vol. 3, p. 228/f. 72a and 72bGoogle Scholar; see also Cook, Harold J., ‘Policing the health of London: the College of Physicians and the early Stuart monarchy’, Social History of Medicine (1989) 2, pp. 1–34, 18CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.
75 White, Stephen D., Sir Edward Coke and the ‘Grievances of the Commonwealth’, Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1979, pp. 95–97Google Scholar.
76 TNA SP 14/135, f. 118 .
77 Brenner, Robert, Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change, Political Conflict, and London's Overseas Traders, 1550–1653, London: Verso Books, 2003, pp. 113–184, esp. 140–148Google Scholar.
78 Keynes, Geoffrey, The Life of William Harvey, Oxford: University of Oxford Press, 1966, p. 187Google Scholar.
79 See note 8 above regarding the possibility of economic or aquatic metaphors, which were suggested by Webster and others.
80 Harvey, op. cit. (1), pp. 2, 42.
81 Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 2.
82 Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 3.
83 Hill, Christopher, ‘William Harvey and the idea of monarchy’, Past & Present (1964) 27, pp. 54–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Whitteridge, Gwyneth, ‘William Harvey: a royalist and no parliamentarian’, Past & Present (1965) 30, pp. 104–109CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hill, Christopher, ‘William Harvey (no parliamentarian, no heretic) and the idea of monarchy’, Past & Present (1965) 31, pp. 97–103CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
84 Rose, Jacqueline, ‘Kingship and counsel in early modern England’, Historical Journal 54(1) (2011), pp. 47–71, 53CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
85 Harvey, op. cit. (1), pp. 2, 42; Misselden, op. cit. (58), p. 142.
86 Pagel, Walter, New Light on William Harvey, New York: S. Karger, 1976, pp. 14–19Google Scholar; Bylebyl, op. cit. (3).
87 Graham, Peter, ‘Harvey's De motu cordis: The rhetoric of science and the science of rhetoric’, Journal of the History of Medicine (1978) 33, pp. 469–476Google ScholarPubMed.
88 Wear, Andrew, ‘William Harvey and the “way of the anatomists”’, History of Science (1983) 21, pp. 223–249, 223–224CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
89 Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, in The Complete Works of Aristotle: The Revised Oxford Translation (ed. Barnes, Jonathan), vol. 2, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995, pp. 1729–1867, 1788Google Scholar (Arist. NA V.5, 1133a7–20).
90 Wennerlind, Carl, Casualties of Credit: The English Financial Revolution, 1620–1720, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2011, p. 34CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
91 Aristotle, Nicomachean Ethics, op. cit. (89), p. 1789 (Arist. NA V.5, 1133a13–14); see also Aristotle, Politics, in The Complete Works of Aristotle, op. cit. (89), pp. 1986–2129, 1998 (Pol. I.12, 1259a10–12).
92 Sharpe, Kevin, Criticism and Compliment: The Politics of Literature in the England of Charles I, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987, p. 289Google Scholar.
93 Malynes wrote that ‘Money then (as the Bloud in the bodie) containeth the Soule which infuseth life; for if Money be wanting, Trafficke doth decrease’; see Malynes, Gerard, Lex mercatoria, London, 1622, p. 253Google Scholar. In the context of a longer section on trade, Misselden similarly stressed the life-giving qualities of blood/money: ‘the Hepatitis of this great Body of ours being opened, & such profusions of the life blood let out’; see Misselden, Edward, Free trade, or the meanes to make trade florish, London, 1622, p. 10Google Scholar.
94 Davanzati, Bernardo, A discourse upon coins by Signor Bernardo Davanzati, a gentleman of Florence, being publickly spoken in the academy there, anno 1588 (tr. Toland, John), London, 1696, p. 18Google Scholar. See also Davanzati, Lezione delle monete, in Scrittori classici italiani di economia politica, Parte Antica, vol. 2, Milan: 1804, pp. 36–38Google Scholar.
95 Davanzati, A discourse upon coins, op. cit. (94), p. 18.
96 This assertion might call to mind Joel Kaye's recent work on balance in the late medieval period, in which Galen figured prominently. Galen may have played some role in shifting Harvey's thinking about circulation, but one critical difference is that Kaye describes the ‘potentially subversive recognition’ of ‘systemic self-ordering’, which challenges precisely the kind of centralized – that is, monarchical – order that Harvey and the merchants advocated. See Kaye, op. cit. (9), pp. 6–7.
97 Brenner, op. cit. (77), p. 651.
98 Harvey, op. cit. (1), p. 58.