Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T10:02:58.096Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Transparency and nudging: an overview and methodological critique of empirical investigations

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 March 2024

Patrik Michaelsen*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Gothenburg, Gothenburg, Sweden
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Transparency is intimately linked to debates about the ethics, political legitimacy and effectiveness of nudging. This paper provides an overview of empirical studies investigating how changes in the transparency of a nudge affect people's choices and evaluations of the nudge. I conclude that the present literature provides generally consistent evidence supporting that the effectiveness of a nudge does not decrease when choosers are given good opportunity to detect and understand the influence it might have on their choices. However, several conceptual and methodological issues are identified, significantly limiting the scope of the conclusions that can be drawn. The limitations are discussed and organized into six themes, with recommendations provided for how future research may address them.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NC
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original article is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained prior to any commercial use.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

A benefit of traditional public policy instruments is that their applications in society tend to be transparent. The implementations of regulatory (bans), financial (taxes and incentives) or information-based (information campaigns) measures are generally publicly disclosed, individuals tend to know in what situations they are applied, and how the tools aim to influence them.

Nudges, however, and similar behaviorally informed interventionsFootnote 1 (hereafter ‘nudges’ for short; Thaler and Sunstein, Reference Thaler and Sunstein2008; Reference Thaler and Sunstein2021), have on occasion been considered not sufficiently transparent. In principle, there is no reason why applications of nudges and individuals’ knowledge thereof need be less clear than that of traditional instruments. However, it is true that at least some nudges, engaging psychological mechanisms that can be hard to introspect about, may influence choosers in ways less obvious to them.

A perception of nudges as lacking some form of transparency is central to influential objections to, or concerns about, nudges as policy tools. One such line of criticism is ethically oriented and focuses on manipulation and autonomy. If a nudge lacks transparency and operates outside of the chooser's awareness, its influence may be considered manipulative and therefore a threat to the decision maker's autonomy (e.g., Hansen and Jespersen, Reference Hansen and Jespersen2013; Wilkinson, Reference Wilkinson2013; Ivanković and Engelen, Reference Ivanković and Engelen2019; Schmidt and Engelen, Reference Schmidt and Engelen2020). A second line is political. In democratic societies, citizens expect being able to scrutinize openly available information about the means and ends of the government. If nudging happens non-transparently, its legitimacy may be called into question (e.g., John, Reference John2018; Thaler and Sunstein, Reference Thaler and Sunstein2021, pp. 326–328). A third line of criticism has doubted whether common nudges are effective when choosers know about them, proposing that the behavior change potential of nudges rests on a lack of transparency. The concern is captured by the seminal quote that nudges ‘work best in the dark’ (Bovens, Reference Bovens, Grüne-Yanoff and Hansson2009, p. 13), with the understanding that the more transparent – ‘the less effective these techniques are’ (p. 13).

The theoretical discussions on transparency and nudging have recently inspired interest from scholars wishing to put these assertions to the empirical test. Do ethical and political appeals for transparency stand in the way of nudges as successful behavior change tools? This paper reviews the empirical literature concerned with providing an answer. In the following, I first provide a brief exposition of the empirical results. Next, I highlight several methodological issues that limit what conclusions can be drawn at present. Recommendations for how to address them in future studies are offered. A final section concludes.

Empirical findings about transparency and nudging

There are several routes one can take to increase transparency about a nudge. Different reasons for increasing transparency can also require that different aspects about the nudge are made salient (an issue returned to later). Policymakers may, for instance, decide to disclose the general use of nudges in public records but leave it open whether people are able to spot individual cases. Or they may embrace a ‘here-and-now approach’ and aim to make nudges transparent to choosers at the time of exposure (cf. type vs token interference transparency, Bovens, Reference Bovens, Grüne-Yanoff and Hansson2009). How transparency is ensured in the latter case is an open question. For instance, it could be accomplished by providing a disclosure statement (i.e., putting up a sign with information about the nudge).

In fact, almost all behavioral studies have manipulated transparency in this way: by providing (vs not providing) a message explicitly informing choosers about the nudge.

In the following review of the literature, the focus will be on outlining main outcomes and general study characteristics. The brief-but-broad approach serves to provide the background for a following methodological discussion. This discussion will challenge the dominant conclusion of the empirical studies: that increasing transparency does not change the outcomes of nudge interventions.

Among the empirical studies, the largest group of experiments concern default nudges applied in consequential (real stakes) choices. Here, the effects of message-induced transparency have been tested with charity donations (Bruns et al., Reference Bruns, Kantorowicz-Reznichenko, Klement, Luistro Jonsson and Rahali2018; Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Nyström, Luke, Johansson and Hedesström2020, Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a; Gråd et al., Reference Gråd, Erlandsson and Tinghög2021), agreement to extra low-paid/unpaid work in research studies (Steffel et al., Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016; Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Nyström, Luke and Hedesström2021b, experiment 1b; Paunov et al., Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019a, Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019b, Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2020; Wachner et al., Reference Wachner, Adriaanse and De Ridder2020, Reference Wachner, Adriaanse and De Ridder2021; Reference Paunov, Vogel, Ingendahl and Wänke2022; van Rookhuijzen et al., Reference Van Rookhuijzen, De Vet and Adriaanse2023) and food choices (Steffel et al., Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016, experiment 1c; notably the only field experiment in this category). Gråd et al. is the sole study reporting increased transparency to reduce the impact of the nudge, with a drop from 62% to 50% of participants partly donating a 50¢ bonus to charity. The studies by Paunov et al., most of which test several disclosure messages, and van Rookhuijzen et al., report at least one message increasing compliance with the nudge. All other studies in this category failed to find a significant influence from increased transparency on choices.

Transparency about defaults has also been studied in hypothetical (stake-less) choice experiments concerning end-of-life treatments (Loewenstein et al., Reference Loewenstein, Bryce, Hagmann and Rajpal2015), sharing of personal data (Steffel et al., Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016; Dranseika and Piasecki, Reference Dranseika and Piasecki2020) and choices of environmentally friendly apartment amenities (Steffel et al., Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016; Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a) and elective university courses (Paunov et al., Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019a). In an apartment acquisition scenario, Steffel et al. (experiment 2a) found that the presence of a disclosure decreased choices of luxury (but not pro-environmental) amenities. Otherwise, no effects of transparency were found on participants’ choices.

A handful experiments have studied other nudges than defaults. Gråd et al. (Reference Gråd, Erlandsson and Tinghög2021) found no influence from disclosure of a social norm or a moral appeal nudge in an experiment on charitable giving. Zhuo et al. (Reference Zhuo, Ratajczak, Thornton, Jones, Jarchlo and Gold2023) studied a list order salience nudge (products displayed in order of carbon footprint) to encourage green consumption, with the same result. Two field studies on healthy food choices also report null effects for salience nudges (placement of products; Kroese et al., Reference Kroese, Marchiori and De Ridder2016; Cheung et al., Reference Cheung, Gillebaart, Kroese, Marchiori, Fennis and De Ridder2019). Cheung et al. also found no influence from a disclosure statement when a social norm nudge promoted healthier snack choices. Kantorowicz-Reznichenko et al. (Reference Kantorowicz-Reznichenko, Kantorowicz and Wells2022) similarly found no transparency effects on a social norm or two information salience nudges in a vaccination intention study (the nudges were, however, not increasing intentions to begin with). Kantorowicz-Reznichenko and Kantorowicz (Reference Kantorowicz-Reznichenko and Kantorowicz2021) did, however, find a decrease in the effectiveness of a disclosed social norm nudge in a stylized lottery choice experiment where the nudge encouraged choosing the high-risk/high-payoff lottery.

Apart from its influence on choices, another research focus has been on how changes in transparency influence people's evaluations of nudges. In the survey literature, where people judge descriptions of nudges without engaging in choices, the general finding is that overt interventions are considered more acceptable than less overt ones (Felsen et al., Reference Felsen, Castelo and Reiner2013; Jung and Mellers, Reference Jung and Mellers2016; Reisch and Sunstein, Reference Reisch and Sunstein2016; Sunstein et al., Reference Sunstein, Reisch and Rauber2017; Davidai and Shafir, Reference Davidai and Shafir2020; Gold et al., Reference Gold, Lin, Ashcroft and Osman2020). For instance, Jung and Mellers found higher support for a policy where employees were provided information about the benefits of enrolling in a basic medical plan than for a policy of a default enlisting in the same plan.

Behavioral studies, where participants engage firsthand in a choice task, have found more mixed results. For instance, Michaelsen et al. (Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a, study 3) found no effect from increased transparency on how much participants objected to the choice format. Similarly, choice experiences, such as of autonomy and satisfaction, have been found unaltered (Wachner et al., Reference Wachner, Adriaanse and De Ridder2020; Reference Wachner, Adriaanse and De Ridder2021; Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a). Other studies have tested whether transparency increased perceptions of the nudge as pressuring or manipulative, finding no (Bruns et al., Reference Bruns, Kantorowicz-Reznichenko, Klement, Luistro Jonsson and Rahali2018; Wachner et al., Reference Wachner, Adriaanse and De Ridder2020; Gråd, et al., Reference Gråd, Erlandsson and Tinghög2021; Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a, study 2) or minor increases (Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a, study 3). Some studies looked at reputational effects for implementers of nudges (‘choice architects’). Among these, some found no influence from proactive transparency (Paunov et al., Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019a; Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Nyström, Luke and Hedesström2021b, study 1), and others that perceptions deteriorated when people learned about the nudge after the fact (Steffel et al., Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016, experiment 2b; Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Nyström, Luke and Hedesström2021b, study 2). Paunov et al. (Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019a, Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019b, study 2) also found that (proactive) transparency may lead to increased feelings of being deceived, but the result failed to replicate in a subsequent study (Paunov et al., Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019b). Notably, and differently from the survey studies, all of these studies focused solely on default nudges.

Methodological limitations and how they may be addressed

The literature thus generally concurs on transparency not obstructing the effectiveness of nudges. However, a number of methodological issues challenge the generality of the conclusion. These include conceptual matters such as what purpose transparency is intended to serve, how transparency is operationalized and what criteria decide whether a nudge is ‘transparent’. They also include matters at the level of study design, such as risks of confounding effects, of demand effects and method invariance at several levels. Together these suggest a verdict on whether ‘nudges work best in the dark’ might be premature, or at least that any present-day statement needs to be complemented with significant caveats.

I next discuss these issues organized into six themes and provide recommendations for how to address them in future research. To my knowledge, no single study is free from all issues raised, and most are affected by several.

Problem 1: Operationalizations of transparency lack correspondence

Transparency about a nudge can mean several things,Footnote 2 and perhaps unsurprisingly, transparency-enhancing messages in the literature contain a wide range of content. One mapping of the research literature suggests no less than nine separate aspects of transparency being disclosed (Bruns and Paunov, Reference Bruns and Paunov2021). At the conceptual level, different reasons for promoting transparency (e.g., ethical or political) may favor transparency about different details. At the practical level, resulting operationalizations may differ both within and between different purposes. Accordingly, there is a risk of research findings being comparable only in name. To develop a cumulative body of evidence transparency, researchers must talk about the same thing or acknowledge when not.

Let us take an example. The dominant backdrop in empirical studies has been the ethics of nudging, with transparency conceived as a countermeasure to manipulation (and thereby protection of autonomy). The philosophical treatment of manipulation is longstanding and rich (Coons and Weber, Reference Coons and Weber2014). Generally, however, the term revolves around interference with choosers’ conscious decision-making processes and (lack of) respect for rational deliberation capacity (Wilkinson, Reference Wilkinson2013). To mitigate manipulation so understood, and facilitate free and independent deliberation about the choice at hand, at least two senses of transparency about nudges seem relevant for choosers to know: (1) that a nudge aiming to influence their behavior is present and (2) to what aim the nudge attempts to influence them (e.g., toward more pro-environmental choices) (cf. Bovens, Reference Bovens, Grüne-Yanoff and Hansson2009; Hansen and Jespersen, Reference Hansen and Jespersen2013). If these criteria are accepted, notable cases in the literature are not ethically informative (regarding manipulation) since sufficient information is not disclosed to choosers.Footnote 3 Arguably, some other cases could themselves be manipulative from containing too much information in the form of pressuring phrasings of the disclosure messages (cf. Problems 2 and 4).

To improve knowledge accumulation, future research ought to explicate the purpose transparency aims to fulfill and how the operationalization achieves this end. Similarities and differences in results could fruitfully be discussed in light of studies’ differences in operationalizations. The practical demands of transparency will vary with its intended purpose. However, from the perspective of counteracting manipulation and protecting autonomy, a proposal for what core aspects are relevant is offered above.

Problem 2: Nudge disclosures confound transparency with message features

While their contents may vary, disclosure statements as the primary means of increasing transparency have been firmly established. Yet, such messages introduce methodological confound problems. Adding a disclosure statement is a multifaceted act that could influence choosers in several ways and not only ways related to the transparency of the nudge. For instance, choosers might react to other parts of the message than intended: to features of the message delivery (e.g., tone, timing and placement), or simply to the act of providing the message at all. Influence from any of these elements blurs the contribution from transparency per se. Instead, a shift may occur where the psychological decision-making process is dominated by increased or decreased sympathy for the choice architect, or similar. In a sense, providing a disclosure statement turns the intervention into a ‘double nudge’, with the disclosure potentially adding unique or multiplicative effects on behavior and experiences. As an empirical illustration, consider a study by Paunov et al. (Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2020). The study re-examined a disclosure statement from a previous study on transparency and nudging (Paunov et al., Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019b) and found the message to have a separate impact on behavior, nominally greater than the default nudge itself. With nudge and disclosure statement combined, the impact increased further.

Disentangling the constituent drivers of transparency effects is vital for theoretical understanding and extrapolation beyond known cases. Future research would benefit from developed theorizing on the moderators of transparency effects, and, once more, from greater reflexivity concerning operationalizations used. Researchers may also consider other means to manipulate transparency than by means of messages (cf. Problem 6). For instance, transparency can be manipulated through increasing the ‘internal’ salience of the nudge (makes it stand out), or from exposing choosers to different choice architectures, effectively disclosing nudges ‘from experience’ (cf. Bang et al., Reference Bang, Shu and Weber2020, study 2). An altogether different approach is to direct research focus toward applied behavioral problems where confound issues may be acceptable as long as impact is achieved.

Problem 3: Differences in transparency are rarely established

When evaluating if nudges ‘work best in the dark’, how should we conceive of the darkness? One could view transparency as arbitrated by objective features of the nudge or by subjective outcomes. On the objective account, transparency can be settled on theoretical grounds. For instance, one could consider a particular nudge not transparent, but that adding a disclosure statement makes it so. On the subjective, transparency is an empirical matter and decided by whether choosers successfully identify the nudge.Footnote 4 Policymakers might (have to) settle for the former, but many interesting research questions, such as relating to perceptions of transparency and nudging, likely require the latter.

Whether or not there is a subjective difference between ‘transparent’ and ‘non-transparent’ nudges also casts the null effects for choice outcomes in different lights. If enough people do not notice or understand ‘transparent’ nudges better – this could explain why their effectiveness do not change. In fact, the scarce data available suggest participants often do fail to comprehend nudge disclosures supposed to increase transparency. Several studies find correctness levels around or below 50% in manipulation checks with simple multiple-choice alternatives (Wachner et al., Reference Wachner, Adriaanse and De Ridder2020; Michaelsen et al. Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a, Reference Michaelsen, Nyström, Luke and Hedesström2021b; Zhuo et al., Reference Zhuo, Ratajczak, Thornton, Jones, Jarchlo and Gold2023; but see also Paunov et al., Reference Paunov, Vogel, Ingendahl and Wänke2022).Footnote 5 Correspondingly, null findings for transparency are not surprising if participants are able to also identify the ‘non-transparent’ version of the nudge. That risk is also non-negligible as the transparency literature relies heavily on online/lab studies with highly ‘prompted’ choice tasks. Presumably, these serve to make unexpected choice architecture salient to choosers. For instance, a study by Dhingra et al. (Reference Dhingra, Gorn, Kener and Dana2012) found that 71% of their student sample noticed a ‘non-transparent’ default, and that most identified it as an influence attempt (see also Jung et al., Reference Jung, Sun and Nelson2018; McKenzie et al., Reference McKenzie, Leong and Sher2021). In the two studies by van Rookhuijzen et al. (Reference Van Rookhuijzen, De Vet and Adriaanse2023, see appendix 2), about one-third of participants noticed that a choice option had been preselected (subjected to a default nudge). Numbers rose to almost 60% when a disclosure pointed out the preselection – still indicating, however, that the difference in subjective transparency can be far from profound even in terms of basic identification of the nudge.

Objective and subjective approaches to transparency inform different research questions. Clarifying one's position can mean an important improvement in precision. For instance, terms such as ‘disclosed’ and ‘non-disclosed’ are sometimes more exact than ‘transparent’ and ‘non-transparent’ (i.e., when comprehension has not been assessed), and the implications can differ significantly.

Manipulation check questions are a straightforward way to assess participants’ understanding of a nudge. However, if the desire is to exclude participants from subsequent analyses, it is important that such questions apply equally across experimental conditions. Stricter demands on some experimental groups leads to asymmetrical exclusions and groups composed of participants with differing characteristics. As a result, the experimental effect becomes confounded. For instance, this could occur if the manipulation check concerns features of the choice architecture and these differ in salience (e.g., an opt-in default might be more intuitive than an opt-out default). Another example is if the check concerns contents of a disclosure statement that cannot be posed to a control group not receiving the disclosure. A general attention check, not relating to the nudge, can therefore be a better option since it enables for equally applied exclusions. Its relation to participants’ ability to identify the nudge or comprehend the disclosure statement can be inferred from a pretest (cf. Michaelsen et al., Reference Michaelsen, Nyström, Luke, Johansson and Hedesström2020, study 3).

Finally, it should be noted that the data above are taken from research studies drawn mostly from a few online panels. While these panels are the same as for most other studies in this literature, it is not clear how well the results generalize beyond them. Also, once more, what constitutes a chooser's proper understanding of a nudge's influence depends on a normative stance. Passing a manipulation check might not count if the check is too shallow and spotting a ‘non-transparent’ nudge might not mean sufficiently acknowledging it.

Problem 4: Common study characteristics invite demand effects

Transparency about a nudge amplifies the nudge's information signal; the recommended course of action becomes clearer to the chooser. Potentially, this could lead to an increase in the effectiveness of the intervention (Michaelsen and Sunstein, Reference Michaelsen and Sunstein2023). However, with increased clarity that a particular behavior is encouraged comes also the risk of demand effects – that participants feel obligated to behave in ways thought desired by the researcher. It is doubtful whether research results generalize to real-world policymaking scenarios if they depend on demand effects. The change of context likely means that the same psychological mechanisms, such as the same power dynamics, are not at play.

Widely shared study characteristics contribute to the risk of demand effects. At the heart of the problem lies the fact that almost all studies with incentivized/consequential choice tasks have the researcher act as the choice architect. This means that when transparency amplifies the recommendation implicit in the nudge, it amplifies the recommendation to do as the researcher wishes. In many studies, the nudged behavior also transparently benefits the researcher: The most used choice task consists of doing them a favor by answering extra, unpaid, survey questions. An added disclosure statement about the nudge may be interpreted by participants as a directive to comply. Some disclosure statements in the literature make the request to acquiesce rather salient, for example: ‘Please note the following: [by acting in line with the nudge], you guarantee that we will be able to accomplish our research objectives’. Exacerbating the issue, samples in the above and most other studies are recruited from online panels (e.g., Mturk, Prolific) where participants depend on researchers’ approval for crediting work quality and even for payment. Independently, but in particular in combination, these factors effectively incentivize participants not to be deterred by increased transparency.

One effective countermeasure would be to not rely on the researcher as choice architect. Field studies, where researchers partner with organizations or governmental agencies, seem a promising arena for achieving this without having to resort to non-incentivized choice tasks. Researchers may also explore further ways of clearly decoupling participants’ behavior from their work approval and other researcher-related feedback, such as through increased anonymization or other data management practices. Stronger protection against demand effects will enable future research to better explore the potentially boosting effects of increased transparency.

Problem 5: Survey studies confound transparency and nudge type

Survey studies finding transparency to be associated with higher acceptability have generally compared purportedlyFootnote 6 covert interventions to fundamentally different, purportedly overt, interventions. For instance, some have compared default enlisting as an organ donor (‘non-transparent intervention’) to information provision about the benefits of enlisting (‘transparent intervention’). It is not possible from such a design to separate whether people's preference is for more transparency, or some other element of the intervention. Future research can address this issue by varying levels of transparency for one and the same nudge intervention, for instance, by comparing a nudge with and without an accompanying disclosure.Footnote 7

Problem 6: Method invariance limits generalizability

The literature features considerable homogeneity in methodology, which could affect how well findings generalize to many policymaking contexts. This is exemplified by the following three issues.

Low choice stakes

Studies predominantly rely on hypothetical or low-cost choices where participants forsake low effort or windfall money.Footnote 8 An argument can be made that the lack of negative outcomes from increased transparency could stem from participants not being sufficiently invested to react adversely.

Homogeneity in operationalizations of transparency

Ironically, in relation to ‘Problem 1’, operationalizations of transparency have also been notably narrow. It largely remains to be seen what outcomes result from other means of increasing transparency than through disclosure messages. Disclosures stand out in that their provision is clearly intentional. It is possible that more ambiguous methods of increasing transparency would produce stronger negative reactions, such as if choosers notice the presence of the intervention but infer no ambition to make it known (a few suggestions how are provided in Problem 2).

Homogeneity of nudges and applications

Defaults are widespread nudge interventions and frequently characterized as non-transparent (e.g., Smith et al., Reference Smith, Goldstein and Johnson2013). This might explain why transparency studies have relied on them so heavily. They are, however, far from the only nudges in policymakers’ toolboxes. To advance knowledge on transparency and nudging, more studies with other nudges are needed. Similarly, a more diverse set of implementation contexts and causes benefitting from the nudge would be informative. The extent to which the behavior encouraged by the nudge aligns the chooser's preferences appears a likely, yet understudied, moderator of transparency effects in behavioral studies.

Concluding remarks

Fourteen years after Bovens’ conjecture that nudges ‘work best in the dark’ (2009, p. 13) evidence exists to evaluate it. The empirical literature on transparency and nudges provides plentiful examples where choosers are given fair opportunity to detect and understand the influence a nudge might have on their choices. Almost unanimously, results support that effectiveness does not decrease, and in this sense, the claim has been proven wrong. Choosers also generally do not appear to evaluate the nudge or the choice architect unfavorably upon being disclosed of the nudge's presence, while people do express a preference for transparency when asked in surveys.

However, important caveats exist. While the experimental data tell us what happens when choosers are told upfront about a nudge, we are not as well equipped to conclude what happens when choosers are aware of the nudge, since awareness generally is not confirmed (but see Wachner et al. (Reference Wachner, Adriaanse and De Ridder2020) and Michaelsen et al. (Reference Michaelsen, Nyström, Luke, Johansson and Hedesström2020; Reference Michaelsen, Johansson and Hedesström2021a) for indications that aware choosers act similarly). In this latter sense, one could argue that Boven's conjecture has not been dealt a fatal blow. Speculatively, whether or not transparency about a nudge changes people's behavior will have a lot to do with whether the behavior fits with the chooser's values and interests (Michaelsen & Sunstein, Reference Michaelsen and Sunstein2023). We also need future empirical work to tackle challenges raised by the possibility of confounding and demand effects in current study designs and to find out how results generalize to more costly or effortful choices.

Perhaps most pressing of all, future research should increasingly move beyond the lab and assess the effects of transparency in field settings valuable to policymakers. The present literature's heavy reliance on low-stakes online experiments remains a focal constraint on generalizability. The few existing field studies use brief operationalizations of transparency and concern rather uncontroversial behaviors, leaving it uncertain whether their insights transfer to more costly or contentious situations.

Finally, I have viewed it as beyond the scope of this text to attempt a concerted response to the criticisms raised. Instead, that space has been allotted to discussing some ideas for how future research may do it better. It should be noted that individual counterexamples exist to several of the issues brought up.

In sum, despite notable limitations, the multitude of documented trials suggests that had transparency about a nudge led people to strongly disagree with it, then the present studies would have caught evidence of this. At present, no such pattern is found.

Footnotes

1 See Nova and Lades (Reference Nova and Lades2022) for a typology.

2 For instance, it can mean that choosers are able notice the nudge, understand its purpose, why the purpose is promoted, who is implementing the nudge, why the nudge is chosen over another intervention or what psychological mechanisms are activated by it.

3 Of course, mitigating manipulation as per the criteria here proposed was not necessarily the intention of these studies.

4 Several ethicists have favored an in-between account, requiring that sufficiently attentive and knowledgeable observers should be able to identify the nudge (Bovens, Reference Bovens, Grüne-Yanoff and Hansson2009; Ivanković & Engelen, Reference Ivanković and Engelen2019).

5 Paunov et al. (Reference Paunov, Wänke and Vogel2019a, study 2) also report having assessed disclosure comprehension but do not report the outcome separately. Combined for three checks however, only 17% were excluded.

6 Gold et al. (Reference Gold, Lin, Ashcroft and Osman2020) is an exception from actually measuring perceived transparency (‘ease of identification’).

7 Yan and Yates (Reference Yan and Yates2019) provide rich data on perceptions of defaults with disclosures but do not include a non-disclosed comparison point.

8 Bruns et al. (Reference Bruns, Kantorowicz-Reznichenko, Klement, Luistro Jonsson and Rahali2018) constitute a positive exception in that participants were nudged to give away €8 of a €10 sign-up fee, which is both a more severe trade-off (less ‘windfall’), and constitute comparatively high stakes.

References

Bang, H., Shu, S. and Weber, E. (2020), ‘The role of perceived effectiveness on the acceptability of choice architecture’, Behavioural Public Policy, 4(1): 5070. doi:10.1017/bpp.2018.1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bovens, L. (2009), ‘The ethics of nudge’, in Grüne-Yanoff, T. and Hansson, S. O. (eds), Preference Change, Dordrecht: Springer, 207220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruns, H. and Paunov, Y. (2021), Why Policymakers Should Be Transparent About the Behavioural Interventions They Use: A Systematic, Policy-Oriented Review. Retrieved from: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3948978.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruns, H., Kantorowicz-Reznichenko, E., Klement, K., Luistro Jonsson, M. and Rahali, B. (2018), ‘Can nudges be transparent and yet effective?’, Journal of Economic Psychology, 65: 4159. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2018.02.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheung, T. T. L., Gillebaart, M., Kroese, F. M., Marchiori, D., Fennis, B. M. and De Ridder, D. T. D. (2019), ‘Cueing healthier alternatives for take-away: a field experiment on the effects of (disclosing) three nudges on food choices’, BMC Public Health, 19(1): 14712458.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Coons, C. and Weber, M. (2014), Manipulation: Theory and Practice. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidai, S. and Shafir, E. (2020), ‘Are ‘nudges’ getting a fair shot? Joint versus separate evaluation’, Behavioural Public Policy, 4(3): 273291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhingra, N., Gorn, Z., Kener, A. and Dana, J. (2012), ‘The default pull: An experimental demonstration of subtle default effects on preferences’, Judgment and Decision Making, 7(1): 6976. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1930297500001844.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dranseika, V. and Piasecki, J. (2020), ‘Transparent defaults and consent for participation in a learning health care system: an empirical study’, Journal of Empirical Research on Human Research Ethics, 15(4): 261270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Felsen, G., Castelo, N. and Reiner, P. B. (2013), ‘Decisional enhancement and autonomy: public attitudes towards overt and covert nudges’, Judgment and Decision Making, 8(3): 202213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gold, N., Lin, Y., Ashcroft, R. and Osman, M. (2020), ‘‘Better off, as judged by themselves’: do people support nudges as a method to change their own behavior?’, Behavioural Public Policy, 130.Google Scholar
Gråd, E., Erlandsson, A. and Tinghög, G. (2021), ‘Do nudges crowd out prosocial behavior?’, Behavioural Public Policy, 114. doi:10.1017/bpp.2021.10.Google Scholar
Hansen, P. and Jespersen, A. (2013), ‘Nudge and the manipulation of choice: a framework for the responsible use of the nudge approach to behaviour change in public policy’, European Journal of Risk Regulation, 4(1): 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ivanković, V. and Engelen, B. (2019), ‘Nudging, transparency, and watchfulness’, Social Theory and Practice, 45(1): 4372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
John, P. (2018), How Far to Nudge? Assessing Behavioural Public Policy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jung, J. Y. and Mellers, B. A. (2016), ‘American attitudes toward nudges’, Judgment & Decision Making, 11(1): 6274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jung, M., Sun, C. and Nelson, L. (2018), ‘People can recognize, learn, and apply default effects in social influence’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 115(35): E8105E8106.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kantorowicz-Reznichenko, E. and Kantorowicz, J. (2021), ‘To follow or not to follow the herd? Transparency and social norm nudges’, Kyklos, 74: 362377. https://doi.org/10.1111/kykl.12274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantorowicz-Reznichenko, E., Kantorowicz, J. and Wells, L. (2022), ‘Can vaccination intentions against COVID-19 be nudged?’, Behavioural Public Policy, 125. doi:10.1017/bpp.2022.20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kroese, F. M., Marchiori, D. R. and De Ridder, D. T. D. (2016), ‘Nudging healthy food choices: a field experiment at the train station’, Journal of Public Health, 38: E1333842.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loewenstein, G., Bryce, C., Hagmann, D. and Rajpal, S. (2015), ‘Warning: you are about to be nudged’, Behavioral Science & Policy, 1(1): 3542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, C. R. M., Leong, L. M. and Sher, S. (2021), ‘Default sensitivity in attempts at social influence’, Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 28(2): 695702. https://doi.org/10.3758/s13423-020-01834-4.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Michaelsen, P. and Sunstein, C. R. (2023), Default Nudges: From People's Experiences to Policymaking Implications. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michaelsen, P., Nyström, L., Luke, T. J., Johansson, L.-O. and Hedesström, M. (2020), Are Default Nudges Deemed Fairer When They Are More Transparent? People's Judgments Depend on the Circumstance of the Evaluation. Available at https://psyarxiv.com/5knx4/.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michaelsen, P., Johansson, L.-O. and Hedesström, M. (2021a), ‘Experiencing default nudges: autonomy, manipulation, and choice-satisfaction as judged by people themselves’, Behavioural Public Policy, 122. https://doi.org/10.1017/bpp.2021.5.Google Scholar
Michaelsen, P., Nyström, L., Luke, T. J. and Hedesström, M. (2021b), ‘Downstream consequences of disclosing defaults: influences on perceptions of choice architects and subsequent behavior’, Comprehensive Results in Social Psychology, 5(1–3): 2548. https://doi.org/10.1080/23743603.2021.1983720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nova, F. and Lades, L. K. (2022), ‘Nudges and Other Behavioural Public Policy Instruments to Encourage Environmentally Friendly Behaviour’, UCD Geary Institute Report Series.Google Scholar
Paunov, Y., Wänke, M. and Vogel, T. (2019a), ‘Transparency effects on policy compliance: disclosing how defaults work can enhance their effectiveness’, Behavioural Public Policy, 122.Google Scholar
Paunov, Y., Wänke, M. and Vogel, T. (2019b), ‘Ethical defaults: which transparency components can increase the effectiveness of default nudges?’, Social Influence, 14(3-4): 104116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paunov, Y., Wänke, M. and Vogel, T. (2020), ‘Combining defaults and transparency information to increase policy compliance’, Social Psychology, 51(5): 354359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paunov, Y., Vogel, T., Ingendahl, M. and Wänke, M. (2022), ‘Transparent by choice: proactive disclosures increase compliance with digital defaults’, Frontiers in Psychology, 13: 981497. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2022.981497.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Reisch, L. and Sunstein, C. (2016), ‘Do Europeans like nudges?’, Judgment and Decision Making, 11(4): 310325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, A. T. and Engelen, B. (2020), ‘The ethics of nudging: An overview’, Philosophy Compass, 15(4): 113. https://doi.org/10.1111/phc3.12658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, N. C., Goldstein, D. G. and Johnson, E. J. (2013), ‘Choice without awareness: Ethical and policy implications of defaults’, Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 32(2): 159172. https://doi.org/10.1509/jppm.10.114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steffel, M., Williams, E. and Pogacar, R. (2016), ‘Ethically deployed defaults: transparency and consumer protection through disclosure and preference articulation’, Journal of Marketing Research, 53(5): 865880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R., Reisch, L. and Rauber, J. (2017), ‘A worldwide consensus on nudging? Not quite, but almost’, Regulation & Governance, 12(1): 322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. and Sunstein, C. R. (2008), Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness. New York, NY: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. and Sunstein, C. R. (2021), Nudge: The Final Edition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Van Rookhuijzen, M., De Vet, E. and Adriaanse, M. A. (2023), ‘The effect of transparency on the temporal spillover effect of default nudges’, British Journal of Social Psychology, 113.Google ScholarPubMed
Wachner, J., Adriaanse, M. and De Ridder, D. T. D. (2020), ‘The influence of nudge transparency on the experience of autonomy’, Comprehensive Results in Social Psychology, 116.Google Scholar
Wachner, J., Adriaanse, M. and De Ridder, D. T. D. (2021), ‘The effect of nudges on autonomy in hypothetical and real life settings’, PLoS One, 16(8): E0256124.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wilkinson, T. (2013), ‘Nudging and manipulation’, Political Studies, 61(2): 341355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yan, H. and Yates, J. F. (2019), ‘Improving acceptability of nudges: learning from attitudes towards opt-in and opt-out policies’, Judgment and Decision Making, 14(1): 2639.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhuo, S., Ratajczak, M., Thornton, K., Jones, P., Jarchlo, A. I. and Gold, N. (2023), ‘Testing the impact of overt and covert ordering interventions on sustainable consumption choices: a randomised controlled trial’, Appetite, 181: 106368. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.appet.2022.106368.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed