No CrossRef data available.
Article contents
Is consequentialism better regarded as a form of reasoning or as a pattern of behavior?
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 04 February 2010
Abstract
An abstract is not available for this content so a preview has been provided. Please use the Get access link above for information on how to access this content.
- Type
- Open Peer Commentary
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1994
References
Adler, J. (1991) An optimist's pessimism: Conversation and conjunction. In: Probability and rationality, ed. Eels, E. & Maruszewski, T.. Rodopi. [JEA]Google Scholar
Alexander, R. (1979) Darwinism and human affairs. University of Washington Press. [JH]Google Scholar
Allais, M. (1953) Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulats et axioms de l'école américaine. Economctrica 21:503–46. [aJB]Google Scholar
Arkes, H. R. (1991) Costs and benefits of judgment errors: Implications for debiasing. Psychological Bulletin 110:486–98. [aJB]Google Scholar
Arkes, H. R. & Blumer, C. (1985) The psychology of sunk cost. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 35:124–40. [DF]Google Scholar
Arnauld, A. (1964) The art of thinking (Port Royal Logic) (trans, by Dickoff, J. & James, P.; originally published in 1662). Bobbs-Merrill. [aJB]Google Scholar
Asch, D., Baron, J., Hershey, J. C., Kunreuther, H., Meszaros, J., Ritov, I. & Spranea, M. (1993) Determinants of resistance to pertussis vaccination. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Psychology, University of Pennsylvania. [aJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. (1986) Tradeoffs among reasons for action. Journal for the Theory of Social Behavior 16:173–95. [arJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. (1988b) Utility, exchange, and commensurability. Journal of Thought 23:111–31. [rJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. (1990) Thinking about consequences. Journal of Moral Education 19:77–87. [aJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. (1991) Beliefs about thinking. In: Informal reasoning and education, ed. Voss, J. F., Perkins, D. N. & Segal, J. W.. J0. [aJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. (1992) The effect of normative beliefs on anticipated emotions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 63:320–30. [arJB, PA]Google Scholar
Baron, J. (1993b) Heuristics and biases in equity judgments: A utilitarian approach. In: Psychological perspectives on justice: Theory and applications, ed. Mellers, B. A. & Baron, J.. Cambridge University Press. [arJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. (1993c) Postscript. In: Psychological perspectives on justice: Theory and applications, ed. Mellers, B. A. & Baron, J.. Cambridge University Press. [rJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J., Baron, J. H., Barber, J. P. & Nolen-Hoeksema, S. (1991) Rational thinking as a goal of therapy. Journal of Cognitive Psychotherapy (special issue) 4:293–302. [aJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. & Brown, R. V., eds. (1991) Teaching decision making to adolescents. Erlbaum. [aJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J., Gowda, R. & Kunreuther, H. (1993) Attitudes toward managing hazardous waste: What should be cleaned up and who should pay for it? Risk Analysis 13:183–92. [aJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. & Jurney, J. (1993) Norms against voting for coerced reform. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 64:347–55. [arJB, PET]Google Scholar
Baron, J. & Ritov, I. (1993) Intuitions about penalties and compensation in the context of tort law. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 7:17–33. [aJB]Google Scholar
Baron, J. & Ritov, I. (in press) Reference points and omission bias. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. [aJB, IR]Google Scholar
Bell, D. E., Raiffa, H. & Tversky, A., eds. (1988) Decision malting: Descriptive, normative, and prescriptive interactions. Cambridge University Press. [aJB]Google Scholar
Brandt, R. B. (1979) A theory of the good and the right. Oxford University Press. [LDK]Google Scholar
Brink, D. (1989) Moral realism and the foundations of ethics. Cambridge University Press. [PMP]Google Scholar
Broome, J. (1991) Weighing goods: Equality, uncertainty and time. Basil Blackwell. [rJB]Google Scholar
Brown, T. C. (1984) The concept of value in resource allocation. Land Economics 60:231–46. [JRI]Google Scholar
Calabresi, G. (1970) The costs of accidents: A legal and economic analysis. Yale University Press. [aJB]Google Scholar
Calfee, J. E. & Rubin, P. H. (in press) Some implications of damage payments for nonpecuniary losses. Journal of Legal Studies. [aJB]Google Scholar
Camerer, C. & Loewenstein, G. (1993) Information, fairness, and efficiency in bargaining. In: Psychological perspectives on justice: Theory and applications, ed. Mellers, B. A. & Baron, J.. Cambridge University Press. [aJB]Google Scholar
Campbell, D. (1974) Evolutionary epistemology. In: The philosophy of Karl Popper, vol. I, ed. Schilpp, P. A.. Open Court Press. [JH]Google Scholar
Churchland, P. (1979) Scientific realism and the plasticity of mind. Cambridge University Press. [RC]Google Scholar
Churchland, P. (1989) A neurocomputational perspective: The nature of mind and the structure of science. MIT Press. [RG]Google Scholar
Cohen, L. J. (1981) Can human irrationality be experimentally demonstrated? Behavioral and Brain Sciences 4:317–70. [PA, JStBTE]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daniels, N. (1979) Wide reflective equilibrium and theory acceptance in ethics. Journal of Philosophy 76:256–82. [PR]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Danielson, P. (1991) The Lockean proviso. In: Contractarianism and rational choice, ed. Vallentyne, P.. Cambridge University Press. [AM]Google Scholar
Dawes, R. M. (1988) Rational choice in an uncertain world. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. [aJB]Google Scholar
Deber, R. B. & Goel, V. (1990) Using explicit decision rules to manage issues of justice, risk, and ethics in decision analysis: When is it not rational to maximize expected utility? Medical Decision Making 10:181–94. [rJB]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellsberg, D. (1961) Risk, ambiguity, and the Savage axioms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 75:643–99. [aJB, rJB]Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1985) Weakness of will and the free-rider problem. Economics and Philosophy 1:231–65. [rJB]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, J. St. B. T. (1989) Bias in human reasoning: Causes and consequences. Erlbaum. [aJB, JStBTE]Google Scholar
Evans, J. St. B. T. (1993) Bias and rationality. In: Rationality, ed. Manktelow, K. I. & Over, D. E.. Routledge. [JStBTE]Google Scholar
Evans, J. St. B. T., Newstead, S. E. & Byrne, R. M. J. (1993) Human reasoning: The psychology of deduction. Erlbaum. [JStBTE]Google Scholar
Federal Electric Company (1963) A programmed introduction to PERT. Boiling Air Force Base. [GMP]Google Scholar
Fischer, J. M. & Ravizza, M. (1992) Ethics: Problems and principles. Holt, Rinehart & Winston. [aJB]Google Scholar
Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P. & Lichtenstein, S. (1977) Knowing with certainty: The appropriateness of extreme confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 3:552–64. [rJB]Google Scholar
Frank, R. F. (1985) Passions within reason: The strategic role of the emotions. Norton. [aJB]Google Scholar
Friedman, D. (1982) What is “fair compensation” for death or injury? International Review of Law and Economics 2:81–93. [aJB]Google Scholar
Frisch, D. (1993) Reasons for framing effects. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 54:399–429. [arJB]Google Scholar
Frisch, D. & Jones, S. K. (1993) Assessing the accuracy of decisions. Theory and Psychology 3:115–35. [DF]Google Scholar
Fuller, S. (1993) Philosophy of science and its discontents (2nd ed.). Guilford Press. [SF]Google Scholar
Funder, D. C. (1987) Errors and mistakes: Evaluating the accuracy of social judgment. Psychological Bulletin 101:75–90. [aJB]Google Scholar
Garfinkel, H. (1967) Studies of the routine grounds of everyday activities. In: Studies in ethnomethodology, ed. Garfinkel, H.. Erlbaum. [KO]Google Scholar
Gibbard, A. (1988) Hare's analysis of “ought” and its implications. In: Hare and critics: Essays on moral thinking, ed. Seanor, D. & Fotion, N.. Clarendon Press. [rJB]Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. (1993) Cognitive illusions illusory? Rethinking judgement under uncertainty. In: Rationality, ed. Manktelow, K. I. & Over, D. E.. Routledge. [LJC]Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. & Hug, K. (1992) Domain-specific reasoning: Social contracts, cheating and perspective change. Cognition 43:127–71. [JStBTE]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gouran, D. S., Hirokawa, R. Y., Julian, K. M. & Leatham, G. B. (1993) The evolution and current status of the functional perspective on communication in decision-making and problem-solving groups. In: Communication yearbook 16, ed. Deetz, S. A.. Sage Publishing. [GMP]Google Scholar
Gregory, R. (1986) Interpreting measures of economic loss: Evidence from contingent valuation and experimental studies, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 13:325–37. [JRI]Google Scholar
Gregory, R., Lichtenstein, S. & Slovic, P. (1993) Valuing environmental resources: A constructive approach. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 7:177–97. [JRI]Google Scholar
Griffin, J. (1986) Well-being: Its meaning, measurement, and importance. Oxford University Press. [LDK]Google Scholar
Haidt, J., Koller, S. H. & Dias, M. G. (in press) Affect, culture, and morality, or. Is it wrong to eat your dog? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. [aJB]Google Scholar
Hammond, P. H. (1988) Consequentialist foundations for expected utility. Theory and Decision 25:25–78. [aJB]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hare, R. M. (1952) The language of morals (reprinted in 1972). Clarendon Press. [rJB, RAM]Google Scholar
Hare, R. M. (1981) Moral thinking: Its levels, method and point. Clarendon Press. [arJB, JEA]Google Scholar
Hommers, W. (1986) 1st “Voller Ersatz” immer “Adäquater Ersatz”? Zu einer Diskrepanz Regelungen des Gesetzbuches im EXODUS und der Adäquatheits-These der Equity-Theorie. Psychologische Beiträge 28:164–79. [aJB]Google Scholar
Inglehart, J. K. (1987) Compensating children with vaccine-related injuries. New England Journal of Medicine 316:1283–88. [aJB]Google Scholar
Irwin, J. R. (in press) Buying/selling price preference reversals: Preference for environmental changes in buying versus selling modes. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. [JRI]Google Scholar
Irwin, J. R., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S. & McClelland, G. H. (1993) Preference reversals and the measurement of environmental values. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 6:5–18. [JRI]Google Scholar
Johnson, A. (1943) An experimental study in the analysis and measurement of reflective thinking. Speech Monographs 10(1):83–96. [GMP]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, M. (1987) The body in the mind: The bodily basis of meaning, imagination, and reason. University of Chicago Press. [RG]Google Scholar
Johnson, R. H. & Blair, J. A. (1983) Logical self-defense (2nd ed.). McGraw-Hill Ryerson. [aJB]Google Scholar
Johnson-Laird, P. (1983) Mental models: Towards a cognitive science of language, inference and consciousness. Harvard University Press. [RG]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. & Knetsch, J. L. (1993) Valuing public goods: The purchase of moral satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management (in press). [PET]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L. & Thaler, R. H. (1986) Fairness and the assumptions of economies. Journal of Business 59:S285–5300. [HRA]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L. & Thaler, R. H. (1990) Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy 98:1325–48. [aJB]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. & Miller, D. T. (1986) Norm theory: Comparing reality to its alternatives. Psychological Review 93:136–53. [aJB]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P. & Tversky, A. (1982) Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press. [JStBTE]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. & Snell, J. (1992) Predicting changing taste: Do people know what they will like? Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 5:187–200. [rJB]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (1972) Subjective probability. A judgment of representativeness. Cognitive Psychology 3:430–54. [aJB]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (1979) Prospect theory: An analysis of decisions under risk. Econometrica 47:263–91. [aJB, DF]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (1984) Choices, values, and frames. American Psychologist 39:341–50. [aJB, DF]Google Scholar
Kamm, F. M. (1986) Harming, not aiding, and positive rights. Philosophy and Public Affairs 15:3–32. [aJB]Google Scholar
Katz, D. (1960) The functional approach to the study of attitudes. Public Opinion Quarterly 24:163–204. [PET]Google Scholar
Katz, L. D. (1986) Hedonism as metaphysics of mind and value. Ph.D. dissertation. Princeton University Microfilms. [LDK]Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1936) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Macmillan. [PA]Google Scholar
Kierkegaard, S. (1938) The journals of Søren Kierkegaard (trans, and ed. by Dru, A.). Oxford University Press. [KO]Google Scholar
Knetsch, J. L. & Sinden, J. A. (1984) Willingness to pay and compensation: Experimental evidence of an unexpected disparity in measures of value. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99:508–22. [aJB]Google Scholar
Kohlberg, L. (1970) Stages of moral development as a basis for moral education. In: Moral education, ed. Beck, C. & Sullivan, E.. University of Toronto Press. [aJB]Google Scholar
Kuhse, H. (1987) The sanctity of life doctrine in medicine: A critique. Oxford University Press. [arJB]Google Scholar
Lakoff, G. (1987) Women, fire and dangerous things: What categories reveal about the mind. University of Chicago Press. [RG]Google Scholar
Larrick, R. P., Nisbett, R. E. & Morgan, J. N. (in press) Who uses the cost-benefit rules of choice? Implications for the normative status of economic theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. [aJB]Google Scholar
Levin, I. P. & Gaeth, C. J. (1988) How consumers are affected by the framing of attribute information before and after consuming the product. Journal of Consumer Research 15:374–78. [DF]Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, S., Gregory, R., Slovic, P. & Wagenaar, W. (1990) When lives are in your hands: Dilemmas of the societal decision maker. In: Insights in decision making: A tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn, ed. Hogarth, R. M.. University of Chicago Press. [HRA]Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, S. & Slovic, P. (1971) Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions. Journal of Experimental Psychology 89:46–55. [DF]Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G. F., Thompson, L. & Bazerman, M. (1989) Social utility and decision making in interpersonal contexts. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57:426–41. [HRA]Google Scholar
Machina, M. J. (1989) Dynamic consistency and non-expected utility models of choice under uncertainty. Journal of Economic Literature 17:1622–68. [DF]Google Scholar
Magat, W. A., Viscusi, W. K. & Huber, J. (1988) Paired comparison and contingent valuation approaches to morbidity risk reduction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15:395–411. [JRI]Google Scholar
Malm, H. M. (1989) Killing, letting die, and simple conflicts. Philosophy and Public Affairs 18:238–58. [aJB]Google Scholar
McBurney, J. H. (1935) The principles and methods of discussion. Harper & Brothers. [GMP]Google Scholar
McCain, R. A. (1991a) Deontology, consequentialism, and rationality. Review of Social Economy 49:168–96. [RAM]Google Scholar
McCain, R. A. (1991b) A linguistic theory of rationality. Social Science Information 30:233–55. [RAM]Google Scholar
Meszaros, J. R., Asch, D. A., Baron, J., Hershey, J. C., Kunreuther, H. & Schwartz, J. (1992) Cognitive influences on parents' decisions to forgo pertussis vaccination for their children. Unpublished manuscript, Center for Risk Management and Decision Processes, University of Pennsylvania. [aJB]Google Scholar
Miller, D. T. & McFarland, C. (1986) Counterfactual thinking and victim compensation. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 12:513–19. [aJB]Google Scholar
Mitchell, R. C. & Carson, R. T. (1989) Using surveys to value public goods: The contingent valuation method. Resources for the Future. [aJB]Google Scholar
Morton, A. (1991) Disasters and dilemmas: Strategies for real-life decision-making. Basil Blackwell. [AM]Google Scholar
New York Times (1969) Section Bl, p.l. [GMP]Google Scholar
Nisbett, R. E. & Ross, L. (1980) Human inference: Strategies and shortcomings of social judgment. Prentice-Hall. [aJB]Google Scholar
Nozick, R. (1969) Newcomb's problem and two principles of choice. In: Essays in honor of Carl G. Hempel, ed. Rescher, N.. Reidel. [FJ]Google Scholar
Nussbaum, M. C. (1986) The fragility of goodness: Luck and ethics in Greek tragedy and philosophy. Cambridge University Press. [KO]Google Scholar
Oatley, K. (1992) Best laid schemes: The psychology of emotions. Cambridge University Press. [KO]Google Scholar
O'Brien, D. P. (1993) Mental logic and irrationality: We can put a man on the moon, so why can't we solve those logical reasoning problems? In: Rationality, ed. Manktelow, K. I. & Over, D. E.. Routledge. [JStBTE]Google Scholar
Oswald, M. (1989) Schadenshöhe, Strafe und Verantwortungsattribution. Zeitschrift für Sozialpsychologie 20:200–210. [aJB]Google Scholar
Over, D. E. & Manktelow, K. I. (1993) Rationality, utility and deontic reasoning. In: Rationality, ed. Manktelow, K. I. & Over, D. E.. Routledge. [JStBTE]Google Scholar
Pareto, V. (1971) Manual of political economy (trans. A. S. Schweir; originally published in 1909). A. M. Kelley. [aJB]Google Scholar
Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R. & Johnson, E. J. (1992) Behavioral decision research: A constructive processing perspective. Annual Review of Psychology 43:87–131. [JRI]Google Scholar
Peterson, C. R. & Beach, L. R. (1967) Man as an intuitive statistician. Psychological Bulletin 68:29–46. [aJB]Google Scholar
Pietroski, P. (1993) Prima facie obligations, ceteris paribus laws in moral theory. Ethics 103:489–515. [PMP]Google Scholar
Pollock, J. L. (1986) Contemporary theories of knowledge. Rowan and Littlefield. [RAM]Google Scholar
Popper, K. R. (1962) Conjectures and refutations: The growth of scientific knowledge. Basic Books. [aJB]Google Scholar
Rachlin, H., Logue, A., Gibbon, J. & Frankel, M. (1986) Cognition and behavior in studies of choice. Psychological Review 93:33–45. [SF]Google Scholar
Railton, P. (1984) Alienation, eonsequentialism, and the demands of morality. Philosophy and Public Affairs 13:134–71. [aJB, JH]Google Scholar
Reason, J., Manstead, A., Stradling, S., Baxter, J. & Cambell, K. (1990) Errors and violations on the roads: A real distinction? Ergonomics 33:1315–22. [PA]Google Scholar
Ritov, I. & Baron, J. (1990) Reluctance to vaccinate: Omission bias and ambiguity. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 3:263–77. [aJB, PET]Google Scholar
Ritov, I. & Baron, J. (1992) Status-quo and omission bias. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5:49–61. [aJB]Google Scholar
Ritov, I. & Baron, J. (in press) Judgments of compensation for misfortune: The role of expectation. European Journal of Social Psychology. [aJB]Google Scholar
Ritov, I., Baron, J. & Hershey, J. C. (1993) Framing effects in the evaluation of multiple risk reduction, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 6:145–59. [IR]Google Scholar
Sabini, J. & Silver, M. (1981) Moralities of everyday life. Oxford University Press. [aJB]Google Scholar
Samuelson, W. & Zeckhauser, R. (1988) Status-quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1:7–59. [aJB]Google Scholar
Scanlon, T. (1993) Value, desire and quality of life. In: The quality of life, ed. Nussbaum, M. & Sen, A.. Oxford University Press. [rJB, LDK]Google Scholar
Schick, F. (1991) Understanding action: An essay on reasons. Cambridge University Press. [arJB, SF, FS]Google Scholar
Schmitt, D. R. & Marwell, G. (1972) Withdrawal and reward allocation in response to inequity. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 8:207–21. [HRA]Google Scholar
Schweitzer, M. E. (in press) Untangling the status-quo and omission effects: An experimental analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. [aJB]Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1980/1981) Plural utility. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society (new series) 81:193–215. [LDK]Google Scholar
Shafir, E. & Tversky, A. (1992) Thinking through uncertainty: Nonconsequentialist reasoning and choice. Cognitive Psychology 24:449–74. [PA]Google Scholar
Sharp, D., Cole, M. & Lave, C. (1979) Education and cognitive development: The evidence from experimental research. Monographs of the Society for Research in Child Development 44 (1–2, Serial No. 178). [aJB]Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1967) Motivational and emotional controls of cognition. Psychological Review 74:29–39. [KO]Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1990) A mechanism for social selection and successful altruism. Science 250:1665–68. [aJB]Google Scholar
Singer, P. (1972) Famine, affluence, and morality. Philosophy and Public Affairs 1:229–43. [PR]Google Scholar
Singer, P. (1981) The expanding circle: Ethics and sociobiology. Farrar, Straus & Giroux. [aJB]Google Scholar
Slovic, P. & Lichtenstein, S. (1983) Preference reversals: A broader perspective. American Economic Review 73:596–605. [IR]Google Scholar
Spranca, M. D. (1993) Raising standards in discussions of the rationality of human choice and judgment. Unpublished manuscript, Psychology Department, University of California, Berkeley. [MDS]Google Scholar
Spranca, M., Minsk, E. & Baron, J. (1991) Omission and commission in judgment and choice. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 27:76–105. [aJB]Google Scholar
Stich, S. (1990) The fragmentation of reason: Preface to a pragmatic theory of cognitive evaluation. MIT Press. [RG]Google Scholar
Tetlock, P. E. (1992) The impact of accountability on judgment and choice: Toward a social contingency model. In: Advances in experimental social psychology (vol. 25), ed. Zanna, M.. Academic Press. [PET]Google Scholar
Tetlock, P. E. & Boettger, R. (1993) Accountability amplifies the status quo effect when change creates victims. Unpublished manuscript, University of California, Berkeley. [PET]Google Scholar
Tetlock, P. E. & Mitchell, G. (1993) Liberal and conservative approaches to justice: Conflicting psychological portraits. In: Psychological perspectives on justice: Theory and applications, ed. Mellers, B. A. & Baron, J.. Cambridge University Press. [aJB]Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1988) The ultimatum game. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2:195–206. [aJB]Google Scholar
Thomson, J. J. (1986) Rights, restitution, and risk: Essays in moral theory. Harvard University Press. [SDw]Google Scholar
Thomson, J. J. (1990) The realm of rights. Harvard University Press. [rJB, JEA, SDw, PMP]Google Scholar
Tversky, A. (1967) Additivity, utility, and subjective probability. Journal of Mathematical Psychology 4:175–202. [aJB]Google Scholar
Tversky, A. & Kahneman, D. (1974) Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science 185:1124–31. [PA]Google Scholar
Tversky, A. & Kahneman, D. (1981) The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211:453–58. [IR]Google Scholar
Tversky, A., Sattath, S. & Slovic, P. (1988) Contingent weighting in judgment and choice. Psychological Review 95:371–84. [IR]Google Scholar
Walster, E., Walster, G. W. & Berscheid, E. (1978) Equity: Theory and research. Allyn & Bacon. [aJB]Google Scholar
Walton, D. N. (1989) Informal logic: A handbook for critical argumentation. Cambridge University Press. [aJB]Google Scholar
Wason, P. C. (1966) Reasoning. In: New horizons in psychology (vol. 1), ed. Foss, B. M.. Penguin. [PA]Google Scholar
Weed, L. L. (1991) Knowledge coupling: New premises and new tools for medical care and education. Springer-Verlag. [GMP]Google Scholar
Wertheimer, M. (1959) Productive thinking (rev. ed.; originally published in 1945). Harper & Row. [aJB]Google Scholar
Williams, B. (1973) A critique of utilitarianism. In: Utilitarianism for and against, Smart, J. C. C. & Williams, B.. Cambridge University Press. [HRA]Google Scholar
Young, K. S. (1993) The use of a procedural model of problem solving by students in a group discussion class. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Pennsylvania State University. [GMP]Google Scholar