Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T07:11:33.909Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Welfare optimization and multinational monopolies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 February 2009

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

This paper examines the role of import tariffs and consumption taxes when a product is supplied to a domestic market by a foreign monopoly via a subsidiary. It is assumed that there is no competition in the domestic market from internal suppliers. The home country is able to levy a profits tax on the subsidiary. The objective of our analysis is to determine the mix of tariff and consumption tax which simultaneously maximizes national welfare. We show that national welfare does not have an internal maximum, but attains its maximum on a boundary of the consumption tax–tariff parameter space. Furthermore, the optimal value of national welfare increases as the tariff decreases and the consumption tax increases. The results obtained generalize the results of an earlier paper in which national welfare was maximized with respect to either a tariff or consumption tax, but not both.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Australian Mathematical Society 1996

References

[1]Brander, J. and Spencer, B., “Trade warfare: Tariffs and cartels”, J. Int. Econ. 16 (1984) 227242.Google Scholar
[2]Brander, J. and Spencer, B., “Tariff protection and imperfect competition”, in Monopolistic competition in international trade (ed. Kierzkowski, H.), (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1984).Google Scholar
[3]Corden, W. M., Trade policy and economic welfare (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1974).Google Scholar
[4]Dasgupta, P. and Stiglitz, J. E., “Benefit–cost analysis and trade policies”, J. Pol. Econ. 82 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[5]De Meza, D., “Commercial policy towards multinational monopolies – reservations on Katrak”, Ox. Econ. Pap 31 (1979) 334337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Helleiner, G. K., “Manufactured exports from less developed countries and multinational firms”, Econ. J. 83 (1973) 2147.Google Scholar
[7]Horst, T., “The theory of the multinational firm: Optimal behaviour under different tariff and tax rates”, J. Pol. Econ. 79 (1971) 10591072.Google Scholar
[8]Katrak, H., “Multinational monopolies and commercial policy”, Ox. Econ. Pap 29 (1977) 283291.Google Scholar
[9]Katrak, H., “Multinational monopolies and commercial policy: A qualification and a reply”, Ox. Econ. Pap 31 (1979) 508511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]Katrak, H., “Multinational monopolies and monopoly regulation”, Ox. Econ. Pap 32 (1980) 451466.Google Scholar
[11]Katrak, H., “Multinational firms' global strategies, host country indigenisation of ownership and welfare”, J. Devel. Econ. 13 (1983) 331348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[12]Katrak, H., “Pricing policies of multinational enterprises: Host country regulation and welfare”, J. Int. Econ. 16 (1984) 327340.Google Scholar
[13]Ng, Yew-Kwang, “Quasi-pareto social improvements”, Am. Econ. Rev. 74 (1984) 10331050.Google Scholar
[14]Rickard, J. A., Russell, A. M. and Martini, C. A., “Welfare policy and multinational monopolies”, J. Austral. Math. Soc. Ser. B 34 (1992) 133152.Google Scholar
[15]Vernon, R., “International investment and international trade in the product cycle”, Quart. J. Econ. 80 (1966) 190207.Google Scholar