Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T09:12:57.754Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Existence theory for games of pricing and technology

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 February 2009

Kokou Y. Abalo
Affiliation:
Department of Mathematics, Erskine College, Due West, SC 29639, USA.
Michael M. Kostreva
Affiliation:
Department of Mathematical Sciences, Clemson University, Clemson, SC 29634–0975, USA.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

A differential game model of a technological service industry is reformulated as an equivalent game over a function space by direct substitution of the solutions of the state equations. For this game, Nash equilibria are shown to exist under certain mild assumptions. A generalization is considered in which each firm has a choice of three different objective functions, which may reflect distinct management options in a technological service industry. Nash equilibria for the generalized version exist under similar mild assumptions.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Australian Mathematical Society 2002

References

[1]Abalo, K. Y. and Kostreva, M. M., “Fixed points, Nash games and their organizations”, Top. Meth. Nonl. Analysis 8 (1997) 205215.Google Scholar
[2]Cheng, L. C. and Dinopoulos, E., “Schumpeterian growth and international business cycles”, Amer Econ. Rev. 82 (1992) 409414.Google Scholar
[3]Friedman, A., Differential games (American Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, 1974).Google Scholar
[4]Gaimon, C., “The acquisition of new technology and its impact on dynamic pricing policies”, in Studies in the Management Science and Systems (ed. Lev, B.), Volume 13, (North-Holland, New York, 1986) 187206.Google Scholar
[5]Kostreva, M. M., “Strategic analysis for a technological service industry: a differential game model”, J. Oper. Res. Soc. 41 (1990) 573582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Levinson, N., “A class of continuous linear programming problems”, J. Math. Anal. Appl. 16 (1966) 7383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Polyak, B. T., “Existence theorems and the convergence of minimizing sequences in extremum problems with restrictions”, Sov. Math. 7 (1966) 7275.Google Scholar
[8]Riesz, F. and Sz.-Nagy, B., Leçons d'analyse fonctionnelle (Académic des Sciences de Hongrie, Budapest, Hungary, 1955).Google Scholar
[9]Roller, L. H. and Tombak, M. M., “Competition and investment in flexible technologies”, Man. Sci. 39 (1993) 107114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]Tombak, M. M., “A strategic analysis of flexible manufacturing systems”, Euro. J. Oper. Res. 47 (1990) 225238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[11]Tychonoff, A., “Ein fixpunktsatz”, Math. Arm. 111 (1935) 767776.Google Scholar
[12]Varaiya, P., “N-person nonzero sum differential games with linear dynamics”, SIAM J. Control 8 (1970) 441449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13]Vidyasagar, M., “A new approach to N-person, nonzero-sum, linear differential games”, J. Opt. Theory Appl. 18 (1976) 171175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar