Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T17:27:05.677Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Agricultural Systems, Land Tenure, and the Reforms of Solon

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 September 2013

Extract

The reforms of Solon have been a source of debate for many years now. The number of articles, chapters, and books written about them is legion. The justification for the present attempt is that it approaches the problem from a slightly different angle. The overriding aims of this paper are: (a) to elucidate what the agricultural system was in this period and to demonstrate that it did not ‘change with glacial slowness’ and that farmers were not incapable of increasing production; (b) to propose the adoption of a slightly different theoretical framework for analysing the culture of Greece in the eighth and seventh centuries B.C. Here, as in so many studies of archaic economies, the main schools of thought are the formalists and the substantivists; the formalists can be further broken down into the capitalists and the Marxists (see below p. 119). Proponents of both sides use predominantly, though not exclusively, analogies derived from Medieval Europe; this, as I shall argue shortly, has led to some serious misunderstandings. Feudal Europe was the culmination of a long development which was very different from that which preceded archaic Greece. Although it is possible to see some resemblances, on the whole they were two distinct cultures.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Council, British School at Athens 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Starr, C. G., The Economic and Social Growth of Early Greece (New York 1977) 147.Google Scholar

2 There is a long-standing debate among anthropologists concerning the formalist versus substantivist argument. For an introduction to the problem, see: Firth, R. (ed.), Themes in Economic Anthropology (New York 1967)Google Scholar; Sahlins, M., Stone Age Economics (New York 1974) xi–xivGoogle Scholar; Cook, S., ‘Structural Substantivism: A Critical Review of Marshall Sahlins, Stone Age Economies’, Comp. Studies in Society and History, 16 (1974) 355–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dupré, G. and Rey, P.-P., ‘Reflections on the Pertinence of a Theory of the History of Exchange’, reprinted in Wolpe, H. (ed.), The Articulation of Modes of Production (London 1980) 128–61.Google Scholar

3 Kraay, C., ‘The Archaic Owls of Athens: Classification and Chronology’, NC, 6th series, 15 (1956) 65–6Google Scholar; ‘The Asyut Hoard: some comments on Chronology’, NC, 7th series, 17 (1977) 198; Wallace, W. P., ‘The Early Coinages of Athens and Euboea’, NC, 7th series, 2 (1962) 23Google Scholar; Price, M. and Waggoner, N., Archaic Greek Coinage: The Asyut Hoard (London 1975) 122.Google Scholar By non-monetary I mean that there was no coinage. There seems to have been a type of value standard—cattle -but the basis of the standard did not form part of the exchange (Finley, M. I., The World of Odysseus (London 1977 2) 67–8)Google Scholar; the two objects being exchanged have a use-value to each of the individuals. With the introduction of metallic coinage, an object with use-value is exchanged for one with only an exchange-value. This will alter the relationship behind the exchange. (K. Marx, Capital i reprinted in McLellan, D., Karl Marx: Selected Writings (Oxford 1974) 443–5.)Google Scholar

4 Works 349–51.

5 357–8.

6 Evans-Pritchard, E. E., The Nuer (Oxford 1940) 85Google Scholar; Radcliffe-Brown, A. R., The Andaman Islanders (Glencoe 1948) 43.Google Scholar These are intended only as parallels of how reciprocity is viewed in other rank/order societies.

7 Plut. Solon 2. 1, 3. 1.

8 Op. cit. 191 6; Tribesmen (Englewood Cliffs, N.J., 1968) 82–3; against: MacCormack, G., ‘Reciprocity’, Man 11 (1976) 89–104CrossRefGoogle Scholar; for: Schwimmer, E., ‘Reciprocity and Structure: A Semiotic Analysis of Some Orokaiva Exchange Data’, Man 14 (1979) 271–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 Woodhouse, W. G., Solon the Liberator (Oxford 1938) 47Google Scholar; Hammond, N. G. L., ‘Land Tenure in Athens and Solon's Seisachtheia’, JHS 81 (1961) 76–99.Google Scholar

10 Works 355.

11 Finley, M. I., ‘The Alienability of Land in Ancient Greece: a point of viewEirene 7 (1968) 25 32.Google Scholar

12 J. V. A. Fine, Horoi. Studies in Mortgage, Real Security, and Land Tenure in Ancient Athens (Hesperia Supp. 9, 1951); Finley, M. I., Studies in Land and Credit in Ancient Athens, 500–200 B.C. The Horos Inscriptions (New Brunswick, N.J., 1951).Google Scholar

13 Plut. Them. 18.8.

14 Meiggs and Lewis, GHI 14; SEG III. 73, b/c.

15 Finley, Land and Credit 28–9.

16 Levy, H. L., ‘Inheritance and Dowry in classical Athens’, in Pitt-Rivers, J. A. (ed.), Mediterranean Countrymen (Westport, Conn. 1972 2) 139Google Scholar; Walcot, P., Greek Peasants, Ancient and Modern (Manchester 1970) 14.Google Scholar

17 The Conditions of Agricultural Growth (Chicago 1965) 15–16.

18 Sherratt, A., ‘Water, Soil and Seasonally in Early Cereal Cultivation’, World Archaeology, 11, 3 (1980) 313–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

19 Works 480.

20 De R.R. 2. 4. 6. His advice is quite correct, as the ploughing of too wet soil will lead to water-logging and a collapse of the pore structure, or ‘jamming’; ploughing too dry soil will breakdown the soil aggregates and will be conducive to leaching when the rains do come.

21 Works 573 5.

22 Works 596–600.

23 Works 462 4.

24 Works 606 7.

25 De R.R. 2. 10. 25; Nat. Hist. 18. 146.

26 Works 607.

27 Oikonomikos 16. 14–15.

28 De R.R. 1. 44. 2–3; De R.R.2. 17. 4.

29 Nat. Hist.18. 187.

30 Odyssey, 17. 297–9.

31 White, K. D., Roman Farming (London 1970) 126–8.Google Scholar

32 Works 452.

33 Snodgrass, A. M., Archaeology and the Rise of the Greek State. An Inaugural Lecture (Cambridge 1977) 13Google Scholar; Archaic Greece (London 1980) 22–4.

34 Bintlift, J. L., Natural Environment and Human Settlement in Prehistoric Greece (BAR Supp. 28, 1977), 259–61.Google Scholar

35 McDonald, W. A. and Simpson, R. Hope, ‘Archaeological Exploration’, in McDonald, and Rapp, , The Minnesota Messenia Expedition (Minneapolis 1972) 144.Google Scholar

36 Camp, J. McK. II, ‘A Drought in the Late Eighth Century B.C.’, Hesperia 48 (1979) 397–411Google Scholar, has come to a very different conclusion. Using a number of wells that went out of use in the Agora as his starting-point he constructs an elaborate argument that Athens was struck by a devastating drought, famine, and plague. His argument fails to convince. For one thing, wells may go out of use for a number of reasons: social (the area in which they were located changed function) or geological (the underlying impermeable layer developed a fissure). Further more, the length of the drought he argues for would be one of the longest ever supposed. It would be very surprising, then, that it is never mentioned. In addition, the only reference to plague in this period is a very suspect passage in Plutarch (Moralia, 773 AB) which refers to Corinth. On the whole, Camp's argument has little to recommend it.

37 Op. cit. n. 33, 13, 15.

38 Boserup, op. cit. 41.

39 Brookfield, H. C., ‘Intensification and Disintensification in Pacific Agriculture: A Theoretical Approach’, Pacific Viewpoint 13 (1972) 30–48Google Scholar; Whartonjr, C. R.., ‘Subsistence Agriculture: Concept and Scope’, in Wharton, (ed.), Subsistence Agriculture and Economic Development (Chicago 1965) 13Google Scholar; Datoo, Bashir A., ‘Relationship between Population Density and Agricultural Systems in the Uluguru Mountains Tanzania’, Journal of Tropical Geography 41 (1976) 1–112Google Scholar; Grigg, D. B., ‘Population Pressure and Agricultural Change’, in Board, C.et al., Progress in Geography, vol. 8 (London 1976).Google Scholar

40 Turner, B. L. II, Hanham, R. Q., and Portararo, A. U., ‘Population Pressure and Agricultural Intensity’, Annals Ass. Am. Geogrs. 67 (1977) 384–97.Google Scholar

41 Ibid. 393.

42 Boserup, op. cit. 41.

43 To name a few: French, A., ‘The Economic Background to Solon's Economic Reforms’, CQ 50 (1956) 11CrossRefGoogle Scholar; The Growth of the Athenian Economy (London 1964) 10; Ferrara, G., ‘Suun'interpretazione delle riforme di Solone’, PdP 15 (1960) 23Google Scholar; Ehrenberg, V., From Solon to Socrates (London 1973 2) 60Google Scholar; Langdon, M., A Sanctuary of Zeus on Mount Hymettos (Hesperia Supp. 16 (1976)), 91Google Scholar; Murray, O., Early Greece (Glasgow 1980) 183.Google Scholar While not putting as much emphasis on it as the others, Murray does cite this sequence as a causal factor.

44 Usher, A. P., ‘Soil Fertility, Soil Exhaustion and their Historical Significance’, Quart. Journ. Econ. 37 (1923), 403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

45 Forbes, H. A. and Koster, H. A., ‘Fire, Axe and Plow: Human Influence on Local Plant Communities in the southern Argolid’, Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 268 (1976) 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

46 Jameson, M. H., ‘Agriculture and Slaves in Classical Athens’, CJ 73, 2 (19771978) 122–46.Google Scholar

47 ‘Praxis’ here refers to the unity of theory and practice in regards to the economic activity of production. For a more in-depth definition, see Sahlins, M., Culture and Practical Reason (Chicago 1976) vii.Google Scholar

48 Works 313, 308.

49 Page, D., Sappho and Alcaeus (Oxford1955) Z 37.Google Scholar

50 West, M. L., Iambi et Elegi Graeci II (Oxford 1972) 24.Google Scholar

51 Works 325 6.

52 Diehl, E., Anthologia Lyrica Graeca (Leipzig 1935) F 7.Google Scholar

53 Finley, M. I., The Ancient Economy (London 1972), ch. 3.Google Scholar

54 Rousseau, J.-J., ŒEuvres complètes. Vol. 3. Du contrat social; écrits politiques (Paris 1964) 601.Google Scholar

55 Kurtz, D. and Boardman, J., Greek Burial Customs (London, 1971) 61–7Google Scholar, 75, 88; Humphreys, S. C., ‘Family Tombs and Tomb Cult in Ancient Athens: Tradition or Traditionalism’, JHS 100 (1980) 98–101, 105–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

56 Archaic Greece 53.

57 Dunbabin, T. J., Perachora II (Oxford 1962) 403–48Google Scholar; only objects which could be dated with some degree of certainty were tabulated.

58 Heurtley, W. A. and Robertson, M., ‘Excavations at Ithaca V: The Geometric and Later Finds from Aetos’, BSA 43 (1948) 1125Google Scholar; Benton, S., ‘Further Excavations at Aetos’, BSA 48 (1953) 255–363Google Scholar; ‘Excavations in Ithaca III: The Cave at Polis II’, BSA 39 (1938–9) 1 52.

59 Odyssey 14. 96–104.

60 Aristotle, , Politics 1305 a24–6.Google Scholar

61 It should suffice to name but a few: Nussbaum, G., ‘Labour and Status in the Works and Days’, CQ 10 (1960) 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar, n. 2; French, The Growth of the Athenian Economy 11; Forrest, W. G., The Emergence of Greek Democracy (London 1966) 55Google Scholar; Andrewes, A., Greek Society (Harmondsworth 1968) 99100Google Scholar; Ehrenberg, op. cit. 58 9; Pečírka, J., ‘Homestead Farms in Classical and Hellenistic Hellas’, in Finley, M. I. (ed.), Problèmes de la terre en Grèce ancienne (Paris 1973) 114 n. 1.Google Scholar

62 Popham, M. R. and Sackett, L. H., and, with Themelis, P. G., Lefkandi i. Text. The Cemeteries (London, BSA Supp. 11 (1980)) appendix I.Google Scholar

63 A Delt 29 (1973–4) Chron. 108–10.

64 Blegen, C. W., Palmer, H., and Young, R. S., The North Cemetery. Corinth, vol xiii (Princeton, N.J. 1964) 13–65.Google Scholar

65 Cambitoglou, Zagora: A., Coulton, J. J., Birmingham, J., and Green, J. R., Zagora i (Sydney 1971) plan IGoogle Scholar; Praktika (1972) 251–73; Praktika (1974) 163–80; Emporio: Boardman, J., Excavations in Chios 1952–1955 (London, BSA Supp. 6 (1967)) 31–51.Google Scholar

66 See the dates given for the various isolated farmsteads in Pečírka, op. cit. 113–47.

67 Op. cit. (n. 35) 264–321.

68 Sackett, L. H., Hankey, V., Howell, R. J., Jacobsen, T. W., and Popham, M. R., ‘Prehistoric Euboea: Contributions towards a Survey’, BSA 61 (1966) 110–13.Google Scholar

69 French, The Growth of the Athenian Economy 2–20; Langdon, op. cit. 89–92.

70 Langdon, ibid. 91.

71 French, op. cit. (n. 43) 15–16.

72 Polanyi, K., Arensberg, C. M., and Pearson, H. W. (eds.), Trade and Market in the Early Empires (New York 1957)Google Scholar; Polanyi, K., Primitive, Archaic, and Modern Economies: Essays of Karl Polanyi (Garden City 1968), ed. Dalton, G.Google Scholar; Finley, op. cit. (n. 53) 150–76.

73 Starr, op. cit., 14–20.

74 Ibid. 124–6, 163, 170–4.

75 Ibid. 124–5.

76 Ibid. 162–4, ‘83–4, 189–91.

77 Thomson, G., Studies in Greek Society vol i. The Prehistoric Aegean (London 1954) 591Google Scholar; ii. The First Philosophers (London 1955) 178–214. I use the term formalist here to describe the use of Marx's works on the advanced capitalist economies instead of his work on pre-capitalist economies because by doing so one is forced into creating classes and institutions that did not exist. Another term that could be used for this is ‘vulgar Marxism’. (See: E. Hobsbawm, ‘Karl Marx's Contribution to History’, reprinted in Blackburn, R. (ed.), Ideology in Social Science (Glasgow 1972) 265 83Google Scholar; Cartledge, P., ‘Towards the Spartan Revolution’, Arethusa 8 (1975) 66.Google Scholar For pre-capitalist economies: Marx, K., Pre-capitalist Economic Formations (London 1964)Google Scholar; Llobera, J. R., ‘Techno-economic Determinism and the Work of Karl Marx on Pre-capitalist Societies’, Man 14, 2 (1979) 249–71 with refs.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

78 Greek Geometric Pottery (London 1968) 29–82.

79 Cook, R. M., Greek Painted Pottery (London 1972) 273Google Scholar; ‘Die Bedeutung der bemalten Keramik für den griechischen Handel’, JdI 74 (1959) 119–21.

80 Webster, T. B. L., Potter and Patron in Classical Athens (London 1972) 2.Google Scholar

81 Snodgrass, op. cit. 53; Works 25; West, op. cit. F 3.

82 Laiou-Thomadakis, A. E., Peasant Society in the Late Byzantine Empire (Princeton, N.J., 1977) 126.Google Scholar

83 Schaps, D. M., Economic Rights of Women in Ancient Greece (Edinburgh 1979) 18–20.Google Scholar

84 Murray, op. cit. 69.

85 Works 629–30, 670–5.

86 Works 634.

87 Kolaios: Hdt. 4. 151–2; Murray, op. cit. 212, 215; Snodgrass, op. cit. 138–9. Sostratos: Johnston, A. W., ‘The Rehabilitation of Sostratos’, PdP 27 (1972), 416–23Google Scholar; Harvey, F. D., ‘Sostratos of Aegina’, PdP 31 (1976), 206–14.Google ScholarMele, A., Il commercio greco arcaico: Prexis ed Emporie (Naples 1979) 93109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

88 Humphreys, S. C., ‘Homo Politicus and Homo Economicus’, reprinted in Anthropology and the Greeks (London 1978) 168Google Scholar; Bravo, B., ‘Une lettre sur plomb de Beresan: colonisation et modes de contact dans le Pont’, Dialogues dhistoire ancienne 1 (1974) 111–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar; ‘Le commerce maritime et la noblesse dans la Gréce archaïque’, Dialogues d'histoire ancienne 3 (1977) 1–87; Mele, op. cit.; Snodgrass, op. cit. 136–9. Bravo argues that trade was in the hands of agents of the rich, whereas Mele argues that it was at first the élite themselves and later a class of professional merchants. As it was argued earlier, Mele's second hypothesis is unacceptable. It seems to me quite likely that in some cases it was the elite themselves who did the trading and in other cases, agents working for them. It need not be an either-or proposition.

89 Finley, M. I., ‘Servitude pour dettes’, Revue historique de droit francais et éranger, 43 (1965) 159–84Google Scholar; Forrest, op. cit. 147–56; Hopper, R. J., ‘The Solonian Crisis’, in Badian, E. (ed.), Ancient Society and Institutions (Oxford 1965) 139–46Google Scholar; Andrewes, op. cit. 114–29; Cassola, F., ‘La proprietà del suolo in Attica fine a Pisistrato’, PdP 28 (1973) 75–87Google Scholar; Ehrenberg, op. cit. 56–76; Austin, M. M. and Vidal-Naquet, P., Economic and Social History of Ancient Greece (London 1977) 58–60, 70–2Google Scholar; Mossé, C., ‘Les dépendants paysans dans le monde grecque à l’époque archaïque et classique‘, in Terre et paysans dependants dans les sociétés antiquites (Lyon 1979) 85–97Google Scholar; M. Sakellariou, ‘Hektemoroi’, ibid. 98–108; Murray, op. cit. 181–6; Snodgrass, op. cit. 121–59.

90 Chisholm, M., Rural Settlement and Land Use (London 1968 2) 65.Google Scholar

91 Aristotle Ath. Pol. 2. 2.

92 The main part of the argument will focus on the essays of Finley, Andrewes, Forrest, and Mossé.

93 Shanin, T., Peasants and Peasant Societies (Harmondsworth 1971) 15.Google Scholar These are peasants who are dependant on production from outside their own farm for their subsistence.

94 Andrewes, op. cit. 116.

95 Andrewes (op. cit. 117) tries to get around this problem by arguing that there was a redistribution of land in some manner: ‘There is no good reason for thinking that this did not happen.’ We are told, however, that Solon did not redistribute the land: Ath. Pol. 11. 2.

96 Finley, op. cit. (n.89), 169; Andrewes, op. cit. 119; Forrest, op. cit. 147; Jeffery, L. H., Archaic Greece. The City-Slates c. 700–500 B.C. (London 1976) 182Google Scholar; Murray, op. cit. 184.

97 Woodhouse, op. cit. 43 n. 2; Thomson, op. cit. i. 591.

98 von Fritz, K., ‘The Meaning of HektemorosAJP 61 (1940) 54–62Google Scholar; ‘Once More the Hektemoroi’, AJP 64 (1943) 24–44; Lewis, N., ‘Solon's Agrarian Legislation’, AJP 62 (1941) 144–57.Google Scholar

99 Plutarch, (Solon 13. 2)Google Scholar clearly states that the Hektemoroi paid one-sixth to the rich. He was writing many years after the fact, and, even if he was using a fourth-century B.C. source, it is possible that he did not understand what some of the terms meant and related them to what he felt to be similar social positions in his own day. French, (‘Land Tenure and the Solon Problem’, Historia 12 (1963) 245–7)Google Scholar makes some sensible comments on the limitations of Plutarch as a source. Arrayed against Plutarch is the equally late tradition preserved in Pollux (7. 151) that the Hektemoroi received one-sixth. I have felt it prudent then to centre the examination on the account of Aristotle alone.

100 Sahlins, Tribesmen 87.

101 Sahlins, Stone Age Economics 204–15; Finley, op. cit. (n.89) 161.

102 This point has been made a number of times: Finley, ibid. 168; Mossé, op. cit. 89, are two examples.

103 West, op. cit. F 4.

104 Aristotle, Ath. Pol. 2. 3.

105 There is some debate over whether this was ‘demos’ land or not. It does not strike me as being that crucial a point; it is sufficient to accept that previously everyone had access to this land.