Article contents
Wars and State-Making Reconsidered - The Rise of the Developmental State*
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 August 2017
Abstract
This article argues that the term “fiscal-military state” is a misnomer, particularly when applied to one of the paradigmatic cases of early modern state formation, Britain. Britain devoted a significantly smaller proportion of government revenues to military expenses than any other European state. Moreover, its overall expenditure included important non-military elements and massive investment in colonial development, a fact that standard accounts fail to take into consideration. The existing fiscal historiography also ignores large swaths of other types of state activity. Finally, the article argues that the British state—and quite probably other early modern states—was not forged in warfare. If war did not make the British state, this would explain why the British state was less narrowly focused on making war.
- Type
- War and the State in the Eighteenth Century
- Information
- Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales - English Edition , Volume 71 , Issue 1 , March 2016 , pp. 9 - 34
- Copyright
- Copyright © Les Éditions de l'EHESS 2017
Footnotes
The research on which this article is based was conducted with the aid of the Institute for New Economic Thinking. The authors would like to thank Catherine Arnold, Natalie Basinska, Margaret Coons, and Alex Fisher.
References
1. For two very different examples, see Gilbert, Bentley B., The Evolution of National Insurance in Great Britain: The Origins of the Welfare State (London: Michael Joseph, 1966)Google Scholar, and Pedersen, Susan, Family, Dependence, and the Origins of the Welfare State: Britain and France, 1914–1945 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993)Google Scholar.
2. Roberts, David, Victorian Origins of the British Welfare State (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1960), vii Google Scholar.
3. Tilly, Charles, “Reflections on the History of European State Making,” in The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed. Tilly, Charles (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975), 42 Google Scholar. This view has been widely endorsed: Hall, John A. and Ikenberry, G. John, The State (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1989), 40–41 Google ScholarPubMed; Conway, Stephen, War, State, and Society in Mid-Eighteenth-Century Britain and Ireland (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006), 275 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
4. Tilly, Charles, Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 900–1992 (Oxford: Blackwell, 1990), 76 Google Scholar.
5. Bonney, Richard and Ormrod, W. Mark, “Crises, Revolutions and Self-Sustained Growth: Towards a Conceptual Model of Change in Fiscal History,” in Crises, Revolutions and Self-Sustained Growth: Essays in European Fiscal History, 1130–1830, ed. Ormrod, W. Mark, Bonney, Margaret, and Bonney, Richard (Stamford: Shaun Tyas, 1999), 1–21, here p. 2Google Scholar; Hoffman, Philip T. and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent, “The Political Economy of Warfare and Taxation in Early Modern Europe: Historical Lessons for Economic Development,” in The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, ed. Drobak, John N. and Nye, John V. C. (San Diego: Academic Press, 1997), 31–55, here p. 35Google Scholar; Glete, Jan, War and the State in Early Modern Europe: Spain, the Dutch Republic and Sweden as Fiscal-Military States, 1500–1660 (London: Routledge, 2002), 216 Google Scholar; Giddens, Anthony, A Contemporary Critique of Historical Materialism, vol. 2, The Nation-State and Violence (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985), 112 Google Scholar; Spruyt, Hendrik, “War, Trade, and State Formation,” in The Oxford Handbook of Comparative Politics, ed. Boix, Carles and Stokes, Susan C. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007), 211–36, here pp. 214–15Google Scholar; Besley, Timothy and Persson, Torsten, “The Origins of State Capacity: Property Rights, Taxation, and Politics,” American Economic Review 99, no. 4 (2009): 1218–44, here p. 1218CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gennaioli, Nicola and Voth, Hans-Joachim, “State Capacity and Military Conflict,” Review of Economic Studies 82, no. 4 (2015): 1409–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Historians of the Renaissance and the Middle Ages have demonstrated that this literature is wrong to assume that the transformation began in the early modern period, and that fiscal-military states began to emerge in the thirteenth century: Béguin, Katia and Genet, Jean-Philippe, “Fiscalité et genèse de l’État : remarques introductives,” in Ressources publiques et construction étatique en Europe, xiii e– xviii e siècle, ed. Béguin, Katia (Paris: Igpde/Comité pour l'histoire économique et financière de la France, 2015), 3–26 Google Scholar; Genet, Jean-Philippe, “Ambiguïtés d'un modèle, enjeux d'un programme,” in The Heritage of the Pre-Industrial European State: The Origins of The Modern State in Europe, 13th to 18th Century, ed. Blockmans, Wim, de Macedo, Jorge Borges, and Genet, Jean-Philippe (Lisbon: Arquivos Nacionais/Torre do Tombo, Divisaõ de Publicaçoẽs, 1996), 261–78Google Scholar; Ormrod, W. Mark, “Parliament, Political Economy and State Formation in Later Medieval England,” in Power and Persuasion: Essays on the Art of State Building in Honour of W. P. Blockmans, ed. Hoppenbrouwers, Peter, Janse, Antheun, and Stein, Robert (Turnhout: Brepols, 2010), 123–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Genet, Jean-Philippe, La genèse de l’État moderne (Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 2003), especially pp. 11–32 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Blockmans, Wim, A History of Power in Europe: Peoples, Markets, States (Antwerp: Fonds Mercator Paribas, 1997), 163–201 Google Scholar; Blockmans, , “Les origines des États modernes en Europe, xiii e–xviii e siècles : état de la question et perspectives,” Archives et bibliothèques de Belgique 61 (1990): 331–47Google Scholar; Zorzi, Andrea, “Lo Stato terrioriale fiorentino (secolo xiv–xv). Aspetti giurisdizionali,” Società e storia 50 (1990): 799–825 Google Scholar; Kirshner, Julius, “The State is ‘Back In,’” and Giorgio Chittolini, “The ‘Private,’ the ‘Public,’ the State,” both in The Origins of the State in Italy, 1300–1600, ed. Kirshner, Julius (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996), respectively 1–10 and 34–61Google Scholar.
6. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990), 10 Google Scholar.
7. For the necessary intellectual connection between concepts of mercantilism and the bellicist approach to state formation, see Sánchez, Rafael Torres, “The Triumph of the Fiscal-Military State in the Eighteenth Century: War and Mercantilism,” in War, State and Development: Fiscal-Military States in the Eighteenth Century, ed. Sánchez, Rafael Torres (Pamplona: Ediciones Universidad de Navarra, 2007), 13–34 Google Scholar.
8. Maier, Charles S., Among Empires: American Ascendancy and Its Predecessors (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2006), 273 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
9. Findlay, Ronald and O'Rourke, Kevin H., Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2007), 227 Google Scholar.
10. Ferguson, Niall, Empire: The Rise and Demise of the British World Order and the Lessons for Global Power (New York: Basic Books, 2003), 17 Google Scholar.
11. Bayly, Christopher A., The Birth of the Modern World 1780–1914: Global Connections and Comparisons (Oxford: Blackwell, 2004), 136 Google Scholar.
12. Mokyr, Joel, The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain, 1700–1850 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2009), 64 Google Scholar.
13. Storrs, Christopher, “The Fiscal-Military State in the ‘Long’ Eighteenth Century,” in The Fiscal-Military State in Eighteenth-Century Europe: Essays in Honour of P. G. M. Dickson, ed. Storrs, Christopher (Farnham: Ashgate, 2009), 1–22, here p. 19Google Scholar. Interestingly, the increasingly fashionable bottom-up school of state formation also posits an epistemic shift at the beginning of the nineteenth century, though without offering any new periodization: Glete, War and the State, 1–2.
14. Pincus, Steve, “Rethinking Mercantilism: Political Economy, the British Empire, and the Atlantic World in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries,” William and Mary Quarterly, 3rd ser., 69, no. 1 (2012): 3–34 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
15. Ganter, Herbert Lawrence, “Jefferson's ‘Pursuit of Happiness’ and Some Forgotten Men,” William and Mary Quarterly, 2nd ser., 16, no. 4 (1936): 558–85Google Scholar; Wills, Garry, Inventing America: Jefferson's Declaration of Independence (Garden City: Doubleday, 1978), 150–64Google Scholar.
16. Trenchard, John and Gordon, Thomas, Cato's Letters; or, Essays on Liberty, Civil and Religious, and Other Important Subjects [1720–1723], ed. Hamowy, Ronald (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1995), vol. 1, no. 12, p. 67 Google Scholar.
17. Priestley, Joseph, An Essay on the First Principles of Government and on the Nature of Political, Civil, and Religious Liberty (Dublin: James Williams, 1768), 64 Google Scholar.
18. Raynal, Guillaume-Thomas, A Philosophical and Political History of the Settlements and Trade of the Europeans in the East and West Indies, trans. Justamond, John Obadiah (London: T. Cadell, 1776), 4:432 Google Scholar.
19. United States Declaration of Independence, 1776.
20. Levi, Margaret, Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988), 143 Google Scholar.
21. Patrick K. O'Brien, “The History, Nature and Economic Significance of an Exceptional Fiscal State for the Growth of the British Economy, 1453–1815,” London School of Economics: Economic History Working Papers, no 109/08, 2008, http://www.lse.ac.uk/economicHistory/pdf/wp109.pdf.
22. Mokyr, The Enlightened Economy, 392.
23. Brewer, John, The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State, 1688–1783 (London: Unwin Hyman, 1989), 30, 66–68, and 114–26Google Scholar.
24. Bonney, Richard, introduction to The Rise of the Fiscal State in Europe, c. 1200–1815, ed. Bonney, Richard (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999), 1–15, here p. 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
25. The most complete analysis of the French fiscal-military state in the seventeenth century is now Béguin, Katia, Financer la guerre au xvii e siècle. La dette publique et les rentiers de l'absolutisme (Paris: Champ Vallon, 2012)Google Scholar.
26. Körner, Martin, “Expenditure,” in Economic Systems and State Finance, ed. Bonney, Richard (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995), 393–422, here p. 411Google Scholar.
27. Ibid.
28. Ibid., 416. Joël Félix and Frank Tallett give a slightly lower figure for France but state that it is underestimated: Félix and Tallett, “The French Experience, 1661–1815,” in Storrs, The Fiscal-Military State, 147–66, here p. 155. See also Riley, James C., “French Finances, 1727–1768,” Journal of Modern History 59, no. 2 (1987): 209–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar. We have used Körner's figures for our comparison since he used the same calculation method for all of his cases.
29. Janet Hartley, “Russia as a Fiscal-Military State, 1689–1825,” in Storrs, The Fiscal-Military State, 125–46, here pp. 126–29; Hellie, Richard, The Economy and Material Culture of Russia, 1600–1725 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999), 536 Google Scholar; Dunning, Chester and Smith, Norman S., “Moving Beyond Absolutism: Was Early Modern Russia a ‘Fiscal-Military’ State?” Russian History 33, no. 1 (2006): 19–44, here p. 43CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
30. Esteban, Javier Cuenca, “Was Spain a Viable Fiscal-Military State on the Eve of the French Wars?” in The Spending of States: Military Expenditure during the Long Eighteenth Century; Patterns, Organisation, and Consequences, 1650–1715, ed. Conway, Stephen and Sánchez, Rafael Torres (Sarrebruck: Verlag Dr. Muller, 2011), 247–56, here p. 247 Google Scholar.
31. Ibid., 249.
32. Childs, John, Armies and Warfare in Europe, 1648–1789 (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1982), 180 Google Scholar. Scholars have recently emphasized that Prussian state-building was less of a top-down affair than previously thought, though that observation does not necessarily contradict the enormous amount of resources devoted to warfare: Friedrich, Karin, Brandenburg-Prussia, 1466–1806: The Rise of a Composite State (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2012), 30–36 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Clark, Christopher, Iron Kingdom: The Rise and Downfall of Prussia, 1600–1947 (Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 2006), 243–46Google Scholar.
33. Michael Hochedlinger, “The Habsburg Monarchy: From ‘Military-Fiscal State’ to ‘Militarization,’” in Storrs, The Fiscal-Military State, 55–94, here p. 63.
34. Dickson, Peter G. M., Finance and Government under Maria Theresa, 1740–1780 (Oxford/New York: Clarendon Press/Oxford University Press, 1987), 1:15 and 2:114Google Scholar.
35. Christopher Storrs, “The Savoyard Fiscal-Military State in the Long Eighteenth Century,” in Storrs, The Fiscal-Military State, 201–35, here p. 214.
36. Collins, James B., The State in Early Modern France (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), 184–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The heart of French Colbertism was not substantial state financial support for commercial initiatives—though there was some—but “inspection of manufactures”: Minard, Philippe, La fortune du colbertisme. État et industrie dans la France des Lumières (Paris: Fayard, 1998), 10 Google Scholar. Colbert, it is true, aimed to create and finance state industries like the Gobelins, and to subsidize others. But the Franco-Dutch War of 1672–1678 “shut down the flow of subsidies to industry and commerce and shipbuilding”: Cole, Charles Woolsey, Colbert and a Century of French Mercantilism (New York: Columbia University Press, 1939), 2:551 Google Scholar.
37. Duncan-Jones, Richard, Money and Government in the Roman Empire (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 45 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
38. Fischer-Bovet, Christelle, Army and Society in Ptolemaic Egypt (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2013), 74–75 Google Scholar.
39. It could be argued that the fiscal-military state synergized civil expenditures through its role in creating a deep market for public debt, which could then be used to fund civil as well as military expenditures. The evidence against this view, however, is that during periods of war, when debt was issued most intensively, civil expenditures were squeezed, while in peacetime, when debt was being repaid, civil expenditures increased (see figure 1). In short, this does not suggest that the ability to issue large amounts of debt was critical in enabling civil expenditures.
40. Sinclair, John, The History of the Public Revenue of the British Empire (London: W. and A. Strahan, 1785–1790), 1:4–5 Google Scholar.
41. Public Income and Expenditure of Great Britain (hereafter the “Chisholm Report”) (London: s.n., 1869).
42. Some scholars have highlighted the important role of non-state actors, such as the East India or Hudson's Bay Companies, in the British polity: Thomson, Janice E., Mercenaries, Pirates, and Sovereigns: State-Building and Extraterritorial Violence in Early Modern Europe (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994), 97–105 Google Scholar; Stern, Philip J., The Company-State: Corporate Sovereignty and the Early Modern Foundations of the British Empire in India (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Even if one accepts that these companies were completely separate from the state, their military expenditures were relatively minor prior to the assumption of the diwani (the right to collect taxes) in 1765. Soon thereafter the costs of the military in India were included in the overall accounting of the state's military expenditure.
43. Brewer, The Sinews of Power, 40.
44. Innes, Joanna, Inferior Politics: Social Problems and Social Policies in Eighteenth-Century Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009), 74 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Our statistical findings appear to echo the data produced by Brewer, The Sinews of Power, 40.
45. Chisholm Report, 1:73 and 79.
46. Webster, Thomas, Reports and Notes of Cases on Letters Patent for Inventions (London: Thomas Blenkarn, 1844), 38 Google Scholar.
47. Chisholm Report, 1:167 and 171.
48. Ibid., 1:111.
49. Ibid., 1:15 and 17.
50. Ibid., 1:117.
51. On the North American colonies, see McCusker, John J. and Menard, Russell R., The Economy of British America, 1607–1789 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1985), 341–42Google Scholar. John Brewer and Eckhart Hellmuth's claim that while political groups in Britain “were prepared to accept a formidable fiscal-military apparatus if supervised by Parliament, any attempt by central government to implement a systematic domestic policy remained anathema” can only be sustained by focusing on England to the exclusion of the colonies, Scotland, and Ireland. See their introduction to Rethinking Leviathan: The Eighteenth-Century State in Britain and Germany, ed. Brewer, John and Hellmuth, Eckhart (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999), 1–21, here p. 16Google Scholar.
52. Chisholm Report, 1:121.
53. Sinclair, History of the Public Revenue, 3:64.
54. Chisholm Report, 1:135.
55. Ibid., 1:163 and 173.
56. Sinclair, History of the Public Revenue, 3:88; Schwartz, Stuart B., Sea of Storms: A History of Hurricanes in the Greater Caribbean from Columbus to Katrina (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2015), 98–99 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
57. Borsay, Peter, The English Urban Renaissance: Culture and Society in the Provincial Town, 1660–1770 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1989), 46 and 90–97 Google Scholar.
58. This theme is developed at length for the period circa 1730–1778 by Whatley, Christopher A., Scottish Society, 1707–1830: Beyond Jacobitism, towards Industrialisation (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2000), 99–113 Google Scholar.
59. Sinclair, History of the Public Revenue, 3:62.
60. The National Archives, London (hereafter “TNA”), T1/297, “The Report of the Commissioners and Trustees for Improving Fisheries and Manufactures in Scotland,” January 20, 1738, fols. 51–52r.
61. Hoppit, Julian, “The Nation, the State and the First Industrial Revolution,” Journal of British Studies 50, no. 2 (2011): 307–31, here p. 327CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Harris, Bob, “Scotland's Herring Fisheries and the Prosperity of the Nation, c. 1660–1760,” Scottish Historical Review 79, no. 1 (2000): 39–60 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
62. Styles, John, “Spinners and the Law: Regulating Yarn Standards in the English Worsted Industries, 1550–1800,” Textile History 44, no. 2 (2013): 145–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
63. Chisholm Report, 1:125, 127, 129, 131, 133, and 137.
64. TNA, CO 5/640/2, fol. 233r, James Oglethorpe (Frederica, Georgia) to Harman Verelst, November 22, 1738.
65. TNA, CO 5/654/1, fol. 109r, Georgia Trustees (Westminster) to Sir Robert Walpole, June 22, 1737.
66. TNA, CO 5/654/1, fol. 109r–v.
67. Sinclair, History of the Public Revenue, 3:61.
68. Desbarats, Catherine, “France in North America: The Net Burden of Empire during the First Half of the Eighteenth Century,” French History 11, no. 1 (1997): 1–28, here p. 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
69. Stein, Stanley J. and Stein, Barbara H., Silver, Trade, and War: Spain and America in the Making of Early Modern Europe (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2000), 260 Google Scholar.
70. Kuethe, Allan J. and Andrien, Kenneth J., The Spanish Atlantic World in the Eighteenth Century: War and the Bourbon Reforms, 1713–1796 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014), 68–130 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
71. Grafe, Regina and Irigoin, Alejandra, “A Stakeholder Empire: The Political Economy of Spanish Imperial Rule in America,” Economic History Review 65, no. 2 (2012): 609–51, here p. 623CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The comparisons that Grafe and Irigoin make with British expenditure focus on the very late eighteenth century, and do not include the corrections for drawbacks and bounties.
72. Slack, Paul, The Invention of Improvement: Information and Material Progress in Seventeenth-Century England (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2015), 186 Google Scholar.
73. TNA, CUST 37/62, “An Account of the Money paid out of the Customs for all bounties, except Corn, Christmas 1739 to Christmas 1752.”
74. William Clements Library, Ann Arbor (hereafter “WCL”), Shelburne Papers, vol. 111, p. 357, “An Account of the Total Amount of Bounties and Drawbacks paid out of the Revenue of Customs 1754–1766, February 10, 1767”; WCL, Shelburne Papers, vol. 111, p. 361, “An Account of the Total Amount of all Bounties and Drawbacks paid out of the Revenue of the Excise, 1754–1766.”
75. Hoppit, Julian, “Bounties, the Economy and the State in Britain, 1689–1800,” in Regulating the British Economy, 1660–1850, ed. Gauci, Perry (Farnham: Ashgate, 2011), 139–60, here p. 140Google Scholar.
76. Yonge, Francis, A View of the Trade of South Carolina (London: s.n., 1722), 7 Google Scholar; British Library, London (hereafter “BL”), Hardwicke Papers, Add. MS 35910, fol. 5r, “Memorial on Linen,” circa 1750; BL, Hardwicke Papers, Add. MS 35910, fols. 119–22, “State of the Case Relating to the Importation of American Iron,” circa 1760; New York Mercury no. 714, July 1, 1765, p. [2]; BL, Add. MS 33030, fols. 91–92, Trecothick, Barlow, “Committee on the American Papers,” February 11, 1766; “Estimate of the Civil Establishment of West Florida, 24 June 1764–24 June 1765,” in Proceedings and Debates of the British Parliaments Respecting North America 1754–1783, ed. Simmons, Richard C. and Thomas, Peter D. G. (Millwood: Kraus International, 1982–1986), 2:36 Google Scholar; “George Grenville, 14 January 1766,” in Simmons and Thomas, Proceedings and Debates, 2:87; Whately, Thomas, Considerations on the Trade and Finances of this Kingdom, 2nd ed. (London: J. Wilkie, 1766), 111 Google Scholar.
77. Gentleman's Magazine 36, March 1766, 107.
78. Innes, Inferior Politics, 30.
79. Slack, Paul, The English Poor Law, 1531–1782 (London: Macmillan, 1990), 32 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
80. This is based on ongoing research we are conducting in the Bank of England Archives in London, especially relating to the collection ADM 7.
81. Bogart, Dan, “Did the Glorious Revolution Contribute to the Transport Revolution? Evidence from Investment in Roads and Rivers,” Economic History Review 64, no. 4 (2011): 1073–1112, here p. 1075CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
82. Braddick, Michael J., State Formation in Early Modern England, c. 1550–1700 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000), 101–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
83. Gorski, Philip S., The Disciplinary Revolution: Calvinism and the Rise of the State in Early Modern Europe (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2003), 39–77 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The essays collected in Blockmans, Wim, Holenstein, André, and Mathieu, Jon, eds., Empowering Interactions: Political Cultures and the Emergence of the State in Europe, 1300–1900 (Farnham: Ashgate, 2009 Google Scholar), show that the “bottom-up” aspects of British state formation were not unique but common to many parts of Western and Northern Europe.
84. Pincus, Steven C. A. and Robinson, James A., “What Really Happened during the Glorious Revolution?” in Institutions, Property Rights, and Economic Growth: The Legacy of Douglass North, ed. Galiani, Sebastian and Sened, Itai (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2014), 192–222 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A., Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (New York: Crown, 2012), 182–212 Google Scholar; Pincus, Steve, 1688: The First Modern Revolution (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2009)Google Scholar.
85. On the rise of cabinet government, see Cox, Gary W., “War, Moral Hazard, and Ministerial Responsibility: England after the Glorious Revolution,” Journal of Economic History 71, no. 1 (2011): 133–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The institutions that made cabinet government possible also created the conditions for party rule.
86. Locke, John, Second Treatise of Government [1689], ed. Macpherson, C. B. (Indianapolis: Hackett, 1980), 24–25 Google Scholar.
87. Mandeville, Bernard, The Fable of the Bees; or, Private Vices, Publick Benefits (London: J. Roberts, 1714), 178–79Google Scholar.
88. Reynell, Carew, A Necessary Companion; or, The English Interest Discovered and Promoted (London: William Budden, 1685), sigs. A5v–A7r, (a1)v–(a2)r, 5, 17–18, 48Google Scholar. Locke was impressed by Reynell's work: Oxford, Bodleian Library, MS Locke c. 30, fols. 18–19.
89. Reynell, A Necessary Companion, sigs. A5v–A7r, (a1)v–(a2)r, 5, 17–18, 48.
90. Ibid.
91. For a more extended critique of the notion of mercantilism and the interpretative pitfalls created by the ubiquitous deployment of the term, see Pincus, “Rethinking Mercantilism.”
92. Povey, Charles, An Enquiry into the Miscarriages of the Four Last Years Reign (London: s.n., 1714), 18 Google Scholar.
93. Addison, Joseph, The Present State of the War, and the Necessity of an Augmentation Consider'd (London: J. Morphew, 1708), 16–19 Google Scholar.
94. Oxford, Bodleian Library, MS Eng. Misc. e. 180, fols. 4–5, Henry St. John (Bucklebury) to Orrery, July 9, 1709.
95. For further elaboration on the competing political, economic, and state-building agendas of the Whigs and Tories during the War of the Spanish Succession, see Pincus, Steve, “Addison's Empire: Whig Conceptions of Empire in the Early 18th Century,” Parliamentary History 31, no. 1 (2012): 99–117 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
96. Brenner, Robert, Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change, Political Conflict, and London's Overseas Traders, 1550–1653 (London: Verso, 1993), 661 Google Scholar; Cogswell, Thomas, The Blessed Revolution: English Politics and the Coming of War, 1621–1624 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989)Google Scholar; Adams, Simon, “Spain or the Netherlands? The Dilemmas of Early Stuart Foreign Policy,” in Before the English Civil War: Essays on Early Stuart Politics and Government, ed. Tomlinson, Howard (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1984), 79–101 Google Scholar.
97. Rose, Craig, England in the 1690s: Revolution, Religion, and War (Oxford: Blackwell, 1999), 94 Google Scholar; Hoppit, Julian, A Land of Liberty? England 1689–1727 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), 156 Google Scholar.
98. Ashworth, William J., Customs and Excise: Trade, Production, and Consumption in England, 1640–1845 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003), 318ffCrossRefGoogle Scholar; Justin du Rivage, “Taxing the Empire: Political Economy and the Ideological Origins of the American Revolution, 1747–1776” (PhD diss., Yale University, 2013), 143.
99. Glete, War and the State, 127 and 137.
100. Agustín González Enciso, “A Moderate and Rational Absolutism: Spanish Fiscal Policy in the First Half of the Eighteenth Century,” in Torres Sánchez, War, State and Development, 109–32.
101. Storrs, “The Fiscal-Military State,” 11.
102. Gorski, The Disciplinary Revolution, 165–66. For the English case, see Hindle, Steve, The State and Social Change in Early Modern England, c. 1550–1640 (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 2000)Google Scholar; Braddick, State Formation.
103. Gorski, The Disciplinary Revolution, 166. It should be noted that in his State Formation, Braddick is essentially telling a story of transition from local state formation to national state formation. In War and the State, Glete has perceptively pointed out that this account also adopts a chronology in which the modern state emerged in the nineteenth century.
104. Our comparative intuitions accord with those of Innes, Inferior Politics, 76–77.
- 5
- Cited by
Linked content
This is a translation of: Faire la guerre et faire l ’État