Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T23:57:35.388Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Whistleblowing

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 May 2008

MICHAEL M. TING*
Affiliation:
Columbia University
*
Michael M. Ting is Associate Professor of Political Science and Public Affairs, Political Science Department, Columbia University, 420 W 118th St., New York, NY 10027 ([email protected]).

Abstract

By skipping managers and appealing directly to politicians, whistleblowers can play a critical role in revealing organizational information. However, the protection of whistleblowers can affect managers' abilities to provide employees with incentives to exert effort. This paper explores this tradeoff with a model of agency decision-making under incomplete information. In the game, an employee's effort determines a project's quality, and a manager chooses whether to approve the project and discipline the employee. The employee and politician wish for only “good” projects to be approved. By whistleblowing, an employee reveals the quality to a politician outside of the organization, who may override the manager's decision. A key finding is that from the politician's perspective, the benefits of whistleblower protections depend on the preferences of the manager. If the manager is inclined toward approving projects, then the costs of lower employee effort may outweigh the informational benefits of whistleblowing. The optimal policy may then be to ban whistleblowing. By contrast, when the manager is inclined toward rejecting projects, whistleblower protections prevent him or her from suppressing effort and are unambiguously beneficial.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Alford, C. Fred. 2001. Whistleblowers: Broken Lives and Organizational Power. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Apesteguia, Jose, Dufwenberg, Martin, and Selten, Reinhard. 2007. “Blowing the Whistle.” Economic Theory 31: 143–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aubert, Cécile, Rey, Patrick, and Kovacic, William E.. 2006. “The Impact of Leniency and Whistle-blowing Programs on Cartels.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 24: 1241–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey S. 1989. “Agency Budgets, Cost Information, and Auditing.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (3): 670–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan B. 1985. Parallel Systems: Redundancy in Government. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, Patrick, and Dewatripont, Mathias. 1994. “The Firm as a Communication Network.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (4): 809–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowman, James S. 1983. “Whistle Blowing: Literature and Resource Materials.” Public Administration Review 43 (3): 271–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, Daniel P. 2004. “The Political Economy of FDA Drug Approval: Processing, Politics and Lessons for Policy.” Health Affairs 23 (1): 5263.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Carpenter, Daniel P., and Ting, Michael M.. 2007. “Regulatory Errors with Endogenous Agendas.” American Journal of Political Science 51 (4): 835–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeMaria, William Maria, William. 1999. Whistleblowing and the Ethical Meltdown of Australia. Kent Town, Australia: Wakefield Press.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash K. 1998. The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction Cost Politics Perspective. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash K. 2002. “Incentives and Organizations in the Public Sector: An Interpretative Review.” Journal of Human Resources 37 (4): 696727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, David, and O'Halloran, Sharyn. 1994. “Administrative Procedures, Information, and Agency Discretion.” American Journal of Political Science 39 (3): 697722.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fayol, Henri. 1949. General and Industrial Management. London: Pitman.Google Scholar
Friebel, Guido, and Raith, Michael. 2004. “Abuse of Authority and Hierarchical Communication.” Rand Journal of Economics 35 (2): 224–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gailmard, Sean. 2007. “Multiple Principals and Oversight of Bureaucratic Policy-Making.” Unpublished manuscript, University of California at Berkeley.Google Scholar
Gailmard, Sean, and Patty, John W.. 2007. “Slackers and Zealots: Civil Service, Policy Discretion and Bureaucratic Expertise.” American Journal of Political Science 51 (4): 873–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 1998. “Incentives in Organizations.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (4): 115–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heclo, Hugh. 1977. A Government of Strangers: Executive Politics in Washington. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Heimann, C. F. Larry. 1993. “Understanding the Challenger Disaster: Organizational Structure and the Design of Reliable Systems.” American Political Science Review 87 (2): 421–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heimann, C. F. Larry. 1997. Acceptable Risks: Politics, Policy, and Risky Technologies. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul. 1991. “Multitask Principal Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership and Job Design.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7 (Special Issue): 2452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopenhayn, Hugo, and Lohmann, Susanne. 1996. “Fire-Alarm Signals and the Political Oversight of Regulatory Agencies.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 12 (1): 196213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knott, Jack H., and Miller, Gary J.. 1987. Reforming Bureaucracy: The Politics of Institutional Choice. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Kovacic, William E. 1998. “The Civil False Claims Act as a Deterrent to Participation in Government Procurement Markets.” Supreme Court Economic Review 6: 201–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krause, George A., Lewis, David E., and Douglas, James W.. 2006. “Political Appointments, Civil Service Systems, and Bureaucratic Competence: Organizational Balancing and Executive Branch Revenue Forecasts in the American States.” American Journal of Political Science 50 (3): 770–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques. 1990. “Analysis of Hidden Gaming in a Three-Level Hierarchy.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 6 (2): 301–24.Google Scholar
Lewis, David. 2001. “Whistleblowing at Work: On What Principles Should Legislation Be Based?Industrial Law Journal 30 (2): 169–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, David E. 2003. Presidents and the Politics of Agency Design. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, David E. 2008. The Politics of Presidential Appointments: Political Control and Bureaucratic Performance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lorentzen, Peter L. 2007. “Regularized Rioting: The Strategic Toleration of Popular Protest in China.” Unpublished manuscript, University of California at Berkeley.Google Scholar
McAfee, R. Preston, and McMillan, John. 1995. “Organizational Di-seconomies of Scale.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 4: 399426.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D., Noll, Roger G., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1987. “Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 3 (2): 243–77.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D., and Schwartz, Thomas. 1984. “Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols Versus Fire Alarms.” American Journal of Political Science 28 (1): 165–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melumad, Nahum D., Mookherjee, Dilip, and Stefan, Reichelstein. 1995. “Hierarchical Decentralization of Incentive Contracts.” Rand Journal of Economics 26 (4): 654–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1989. “The Politics of Bureaucratic Structure.” In ed. Chubb, John E. and Peterson, Paul E., Can the Government Govern? Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Near, Janet, and Miceli, Marcia. 1996. “Whistle-Blowing: Myth and Reality.” Journal of Management 22 (3): 507–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, Valerie R. 1991. “The False Claims Act, Qui Tam Relators, and the Government: Which Is the Real Party to the Action?Stanford Law Review 43 (5): 1061–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, Canice. 2003. “The Limits of Bureaucratic Efficiency.” Journal of Political Economy 111 (5): 929–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Public Service Commission of Canada, Research Directorate. 2001. “Three Whistleblower Protection Models: A Comparative Analysis of Whistleblower Legislation in Australia, the United States, and the United Kingdom.”Google Scholar
Shafritz, Jay M., and Russell, E. W.. 2000 Introducing Public Administration. 2nd ed. New York: Addison Wesley Longman.Google Scholar
Ting, Michael M. 2002. “A Theory of Jurisdictional Assignments in Bureaucracies.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (2): 364–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean. 1986. “Hierarchies and Bureaucracies: On the Role of Collusion in Organizations.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 2 (2): 181214.Google Scholar
United States Office of Special Counsel. 1999. “A Report to Congress from the U.S. Office of Special Counsel for Fiscal Year 1999.”Google Scholar
United States Congressional Research Service. 2005. “National Security Whistleblowers.” CRS Report RL33215.Google Scholar
United States Congressional Research Service. 2007. “The Whistleblower Protection Act: An Overview.” CRS Report RL33918.Google Scholar
Wilson, James Q. 2000. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It. 2nd ed. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.