Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T20:16:19.852Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Universalism in Experimental Committees

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 September 1982

Gary J. Miller
Affiliation:
Michigan State University
Joe A. Oppenheimer
Affiliation:
University of Maryland

Abstract

Most rational choice theories of committee decision making predict a process of competitive coalition formation leading to a minimum winning coalition. Committee experiments reported to date tend to support these theories. However, both theories and committee experiments are contradicted by the evidence of real-world legislatures making distributive decisions; these decisions are characterized by coalitions of the whole providing virtually all members with a share of distributive benefits. The results in this article help to resolve this contradiction by showing that if the committee experimental design includes a universalistic alternative which provides a high level of expected benefits for committee members, it will be selected. Competitive coalition formation occurs in experimental settings which do not include such an alternative. The results call into question the generality of ordinalist theories of competitive coalition formation.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Able, R. and Oppenheimer, J. A. In press. Liberating the industrious tailor, Political Methodology.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth. 1963. Social choice and individual values. 2nd ed. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Aumann, R. J. and Maschler, M. 1964. The bargaining set for cooperative games. In Aumann, Dresher, Shapley, , and Tucker, , eds. Advances in game theory. Published as Annals of Mathematical Studies, No. 52, of the American Mathematical Society, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Berle, J. E., McKelvey, R. D., Ordeshook, P. C., and Winer, M. D. 1976. An experimental test of the core in a simple N-person cooperative nonsidepayment game. Journal of Conflict Resolution 20:454–79.Google Scholar
Black, D. 1958. The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary and Tutt, Tim. 1979. The rule of five. Caltech Social Science Working Paper #295. Pasadena, California: mimeographed.Google Scholar
Fenno, Richard F. 1966. Power of the purse. Boston: Little Brown.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John F. 1974. Pork barrel politics. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1978. Legislative facilitation of government growth: universalism and reciprocity practices in majority rule institutions. Caltech Social Science Working Paper #228. Pasadena, California: Mimeographed.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. and Plott, Charles R. 1978. Committee decisions under majority rule: an experimental study. The American Political Science Review 72: 575–98.10.2307/1954111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1953. The methodology of positive economics, In Essays in positive economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 343.Google Scholar
Froman, Lewis A. 1967. The congressional process. Boston: Little Brown.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1971. Collective action as an agreeable N-prisoners' dilemma. Behavioral Science 16: 472–81.10.1002/bs.3830160507CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. In press. Collective action. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.10.4324/9781315044330CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, and Plott, Charles R. Pre-meeting discussions and the possibility of coalition breaking procedures in majority rule committees. Caltech Social Science Working Paper #281. Pasadena, California: Mimeographed.Google Scholar
Isaac, Mark and Plott, Charles R. 1978. Cooperative game models of the influence of the closed rule in three person, majority rule committees. In Game theory and political science, Ordeshook, P. C., ed. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. 1977. A dynamical model of political equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory 16: 310–34.10.1016/0022-0531(77)90011-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, Duncan and Raiffa, Howard. 1957. Games and decisions. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Manley, John F. 1969. Wilbur D. Mills: a study in congressional influence. American Political Science Review 62:442–64.10.1017/S0003055400262321CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwell, Gerald and Ames, Ruth E. 1981. Economists free ride: does anyone else? Journal of Public Economics 15:295310.10.1016/0047-2727(81)90013-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwell, Gerald and Ames, Ruth E. 1979. Experiments on the provision of public goods: resources, interest, group size and the free-rider problem. American Journal of Sociology 84: 1335–60.10.1086/226937CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1976. Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–82.10.1016/0022-0531(76)90040-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. and Ordeshook, Peter C. 1978a. Vote trading: an experimental study. Pittsburgh: Carnegie-Mellon University, mimeographed.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. and Ordeshook, Peter C. 1978b. An experimental test of several theories of committee decision making under majority rule. Pittsburgh: Carnegie-Mellon University, mimeographed.10.1007/978-3-662-41501-6_9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., Ordeshook, Peter C., and Winer, Mark D. 1978. The competitive solution for N-person games without transferable utility. American Political Science Review 72:559–615.10.2307/1954112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgram, Stanley. 1974. Obedience to authority. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Oppenheimer, J. A. 1979. Outcomes of logrolling in the bargaining set and democratic theory: some conjectures. Public Choice 34:419–34.10.1007/BF00225678CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, Charles R. 1967. A notion of equilibrium and its possibilities under majority rule. American Economic Review 57:787806.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. and Levine, Michael E. 1976. On using the agenda to influence group decisions. Caltech Social Science Working Paper #66. Pasadena, Calif., mimeographed.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1971. A theory of justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674042605CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Runge, Carlisle Ford. 1981. Common property externalities: isolation, assurance, and resource depletion in a traditional grazing context. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63:595606.10.2307/1241202CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1960. Strategy of Conflict. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1977. Transitivity of preferences on a smooth manifold of alternatives. Journal of Economic Theory 14:149–71.10.1016/0022-0531(77)90089-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1978. The instability of simple dynamic games. Review of Economic Studies 45:575–94.10.2307/2297259CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sweeney, John W. Jr. 1973. An experimental investigation of the free rider problem. Social Science Research 2:277–92.10.1016/0049-089X(73)90004-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sweeney, John W. Jr. 1974. Altruism, the free rider problem and group size. Theory and decision 4:259–75.10.1007/BF00136649CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ward, Benjamin. 1961. Majority rule and allocation. Journal of Conflict Resolution 5:379–89.10.1177/002200276100500405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry. 1979. A rational choice perspective on congressional norms. American Journal of Political Science 23:245–62.10.2307/2111001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.