Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-16T15:03:10.117Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Union Organization in Advanced Industrial Democracies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Michael Wallerstein
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles

Abstract

I suggest a new explanation of cross-national differences in unionization rates: the size of the labor force. Size matters because the gains unions are able to achieve in collective bargaining depend on the proportion of substitutable workers who are organized, while the costs of organizing depend in part on the absolute number to be recruited. The comparison of the costs and benefits of organizing new workers yields the conclusion that unions in larger labor markets will accept lower levels of unionization. Statistical analysis of cross-national differences in unionization rates among advanced industrial societies in the late 1970s indicates that the size of the labor force and the cumulative participation of leftist parties in government explain most of the variance.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adam, Gerard. 1983. Le pouvoir syndical. Paris: Dunod.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, Orley, and Pencavel, John H.. 1969. “American Trade Union Growth: 1900–1960.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 83:434–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bain, George S., and Elsheikh, Farouk. 1976. Union Growth and the Business Cycle. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Bain, George S., and Price, Robert. 1980. Profiles of Union Growth: A Comparative Statistical Portrait of Eight Countries. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Barnett, George E. 1916. “Growth of Labor Organization in the United States, 1897–1914.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 30:780–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Irving. 1954. “The Growth of American Unions.” American Economic Review 44:301–18.Google Scholar
Block, Richard N. 1980. “Union Organizing and the Allocation of Union Resources.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 34:101–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, David R. 1978. “The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis.” American Political Science Review 72:1243–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, David R. 1984. “Social Democracy, Corporatism, and Labor Quiescence: The Representation of Economic Interest in Advanced Capitalist Society.” In Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism, ed. Goldthorpe, John H.. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, Kim B. 1984. “Unionization and Firm Performance: The Impact on Profits, Growth, and Productivity.” American Economic Review 74: 893919.Google Scholar
Coldrick, Arthur P., and Jones, Philip. 1979. The International Directory of the Trade Union Movement. New York: Facts on File.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. et al. , 1918. History of Labour in the United States. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Dunlop, John T. 1949. “The Development of Labor Organization: A Theoretical Framework.” In Insights into Labor Issues, ed. Lester, Richard A. and Shister, Joseph. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ellwood, David T., and Fine, Glen. 1987. “Effects of Right-to-work Laws on Union Organizing.” Journal of Political Economy 95:250–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorito, Jack. 1982. “American Trade Union Growth: An Alternative Model.” Industrial Relations 21:123–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Richard B., and Medoff, James L.. 1981. “The Impact of the Percentage Organized on Union and Nonunion Wages.” Review of Economics and Statistics 63:561–72.Google Scholar
Freeman, Richard B., and Medoff, James L.. 1984. What Do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Goldfield, Michael. 1987. The Decline of Organized Labor in the United States. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Headey, Bruce. 1970. “Trade Unions and National Wages Policies.” Journal of Politics 32:407–39.Google Scholar
Hicks, Alexander. 1988. “Capitalism, Social Democratic Corporatism, and Economic Growth.” Journal of Politics 50:677704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, Alexander, and Swank, Duane. 1984a. “On the Political Economy of Welfare Expansion: A Comparative Analysis of Eighteen Advanced Capitalist Democracies, 1960–1971.” Comparative Political Studies 17:81119.Google Scholar
Hicks, Alexander, and Swank, Duane. 1984b. “Governmental Redistribution in Rich Capitalist Democracies.” Policy Studies Journal 13:265–86.Google Scholar
Hines, A. G. 1964. “Trade Unions and Wage Inflation in the United Kingdom 1893–1961.” Review of Economic Studies 31:221–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hines, A. G. 1969. “Wage Inflation in the United Kingdom 1948–1962: A Disaggregated Study.” Economic Journal 79:6689.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, Barry T. 1980. “The Determinants of Unionization: An Analysis of Interarea Differences.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 33: 147–61.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Barry T., and Addison, John T.. 1986. The Economic Analysis of Unions: New Approaches and Evidence. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Ingham, Geoffrey K. 1974. Strikes and Industrial Conflict. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
International Labour Office. 19791983. Yearbook of Labour Statistics. Geneva: ILO.Google Scholar
Israel. Central Bureau of Statistics. 1980. Statistical Abstract of Israel 1980. Jerusalem: Hamakor.Google Scholar
Kalai, Ehud. 1985. “Solutions to the Bargaining Problem.” In Social Goals and Social Organization: Essays in Memory of Elisha Pazner, ed. Hurwicz, Leonid, Schmeidler, David, and Sonnenschein, Hugo. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kassalow, Everett M. 1980. “The Closed and Union Shop in Western Europe: An American Perspective.” Journal of Labor Research 1:323–39.Google Scholar
Katzenstein, Peter. 1985. Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Korpi, Walter. 1983. The Democratic Class Struggle. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Korpi, Walter, and Shalev, Michael. 1979. “Strikes, Industrial Relations, and Class Conflict in Capitalist Societies.” British Journal of Sociology 30:164–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korpi, Walter, and Shalev, Michael. 1980. “Strikes, Power, and Politics in Western Nations, 1900–1976.” Political Power and Social Theory 1: 301–34.Google Scholar
Lazear, Edward P. 1983. “A Microeconomic Theory of Labor Unions.” In New Approaches to Labor Unions, ed. Reid, Joseph D.. Greenwich, CT: JAI.Google Scholar
Lorwin, Lewis L. 1933. The American Federation of Labor: History, Policies, and Prospects. Washington: Brookings.Google Scholar
Mackie, Thomas T., and Rose, Richard. 1982. The International Almanac of Electoral History. 2d ed. New York: Free Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, Ian M., and Solow, Robert W.. 1981. “Wage Bargaining and Employment.” American Economic Review 71:896908.Google Scholar
Menil, George de. 1971. Bargaining: Monopoly Power versus Union Power. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Moore, William J., and Pearce, Douglas K.. 1976. “Union Growth: A Test of the Ashenfelter-Pencavel Model.” Industrial Relations 15:244–47.Google Scholar
Nash, John F. 1950. “The Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 18:155–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1984. Labor Force Statistics 1962–1982. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 1984. “Union Growth: A Review of the Literature.” University of Chicago. Typescript.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, and Sprague, John. 1986. Paper Stones: A History of Electoral Socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Rogers, Joel. 1985. “Divide and Conquer: The Legal Foundations of Postwar U.S. Labor Policy.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New Orleans.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel. 1982. “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model.” Econometrica 50:97109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shalev, Michael, and Korpi, Walter. 1980. “Working Class Mobilization and American Exceptionalism.” Economic and Industrial Democracy 1: 3161.Google Scholar
Sharpe, Ian G. 1971. “The Growth of Australian Trade Unions: 1907–1969.” Journal of Industrial Relations 13:138–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheflin, Neil, Troy, Leo, and Koeller, C. T.. 1981. “Structural Stability in Models of American Trade Union Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 85:7788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shister, Joseph. 1953. “The Logic of Union Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 61: 413–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephens, John D. 1980. The Transition from Capitalism to Socialism. Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities.Google Scholar
Sutton, John. 1986. “Non-Cooperative Bargaining Theory: An Introduction.” Review of Economic Studies 53:708–24.Google Scholar
Swindinsky, R. 1974. “Trade Union Growth in Canada, 1911–1970.” Relations Industrielles 29: 435–51.Google Scholar
Troy, Leo, and Sheflin, Neil. 1985. U.S. Union Sourcebook. West Orange, NJ: Industrial Relations Data and Information Services.Google Scholar
Tu, Pierre N. V. 1984. Introductory Optimization Dynamics. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
United Nations. 1985. World Statistics in Brief. New York: UN.Google Scholar
United Nations. Food and Agricultural Organization. 1985. FAO Trade Yearbook, 1984. Rome: FAO.Google Scholar
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1956. Labor in Iceland. Washington: Bureau of Labor Statistics.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor. 1980. International Labor Profiles. Detroit: Grand River Books.Google Scholar
Voos, Paula B. 1983. “Union Organizing: Costs and Benefits.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 36:576–91.Google Scholar
Voos, Paula B. 1984a. “Does It Pay To Organize? Estimating the Cost to Unions.” Monthly Labor Review 107 (June): 4344.Google Scholar
Voos, Paula B. 1984b. “Trends in Union Organizing Expenditures, 1953–1977.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 38:5263.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, Michael. 1987. “Unemployment, Collective Bargaining, and the Demand for Protection.” American Journal of Political Science 31: 729–52.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, Michael. 1988a. “Parties in Government.” University of California, Los Angeles. Typescript.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, Michael. 1988b. “Union Growth from the Unions' Perspective.” Institute of Industrial Relations Working Paper no. 149. University of California, Los Angeles.Google Scholar
Weinstein, James. 1975. Ambiguous Legacy: The Left in American Politics. New York: New View-points.Google Scholar
Weyworth, William O. 1917. The Organizability of Labor. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Wilensky, Harold L. 1981. “Leftism, Catholicism, and Democratic Corporatism: The Role of Political Parties in Recent Welfare State Development.” In The Development of Welfare States in Europe and America, ed. Flora, Peter and Heidenheimer, Arnold J.. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books.Google Scholar
Wilkinson, R. K., and Burkitt, B.. 1973. “Wage Determination and Trade Unions.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 20:107–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Erik O. 1985. Classes. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.