Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T12:11:24.882Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Tilly Goes to Church: The Religious and Medieval Roots of European State Fragmentation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 April 2023

ANNA GRZYMALA-BUSSE*
Affiliation:
Stanford University, United States
*
Anna Grzymala-Busse, Professor, Department of Political Science, Stanford University, United States, [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The starting point for many analyses of European state development is the historical fragmentation of territorial authority. The dominant bellicist explanation for state formation argues that this fragmentation was an unintended consequence of imperial collapse, and that warfare in the early modern era overcame fragmentation by winnowing out small polities and consolidating strong states. Using new data on papal conflict and religious institutions, I show instead that political fragmentation was the outcome of deliberate choices, that it is closely associated with papal conflict, and that political fragmentation persisted for longer than the bellicist explanations would predict. The medieval Catholic Church deliberately and effectively splintered political power in Europe by forming temporal alliances, funding proxy wars, launching crusades, and advancing ideology to ensure its autonomy and power. The roots of European state formation are thus more religious, older, and intentional than often assumed.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

INTRODUCTION

The medieval church was a powerful, if neglected, force in European state formation. Canonical accounts of state building focus on war and violent conflict between secular rulers in the early modern era (1500–1800 CE). Taking the territorial fragmentation of Europe as a starting point, this “bellicist” literature agrees that early modern warfare consolidated the state system into fewer, larger states. The need to fund these wars also necessitated the rise of state institutions. Rulers who succeeded in waging war and extracting taxes went on to consolidate their territorial gains and ensure the survival and sovereignty of their states. Charles Tilly’s summary is as succinct as it is well known: “war made the state and the state made war” (Tilly Reference Tilly1975, 42).

Yet empirical incongruities challenge this account. First, the fragmentation of Europe was extraordinarily persistent. It lasted well through the mid-nineteenth century, contrary to the bellicist argument that early modern warfare winnowed out and consolidated states (Spruyt Reference Spruyt, Kaspersen and Strandsbjerg2017, 87). Second, many of the institutions that the bellicists claim were the inadvertent result of early modern warfare, such as taxation, courts, central administrations, or parliaments, arose long before the pressures of war supposedly made them necessary (Blaydes and Paik Reference Blaydes and Paik2016; Stasavage Reference Stasavage2010; Reference Stasavage2016). Third, conflict has not uniformly led states to consolidate. The early onset of military competition translated into a primitive and patrimonial administrations in Europe, rather than more effective and formalized ones (Ertman Reference Ertman1997). Wars produced crises: ancien regime France was exhausted by its military ventures, as was eighteenth-century Poland, so that “war unmade these states”(Teschke Reference Teschke, Kaspersen and Strandsbjerg2017, 45). More broadly, war can hinder state formation, ending intensive economic growth, spreading disease, and depleting the labor supply (Fouquet and Broadberry Reference Fouquet and Broadberry2015; Ober Reference Ober2015; Saylor and Wheeler Reference Saylor and Wheeler2017; Voigtländer and Voth Reference Voigtländer and Voth2013). State formation and warfare did not go hand in hand in other regions (Centeno Reference Centeno2002; Doner, Ritchie, and Slater Reference Doner, Ritchie and Slater2005; Herbst Reference Herbst2000; Mazzuca Reference Mazzuca2021; Thies Reference Thies2005; Hui Reference Hui2005).

To explain these anomalies, we need to look beyond early modern warfare. The foundational era of European state formationFootnote 1 goes back centuries earlier, to the medieval period (1000–1350 CE). The Roman Catholic Church (or “the Church”) was the dominant political actor in the Middle Ages, and it was most powerful from 1100 to 1300.Footnote 2 As a result, the strongest rival for an ambitious medieval ruler was not another monarch, but the Church. The Church wielded its enormous wealth, human capital, and moral authority to ensure its own autonomy and preclude the rise of a rival dominant power. It sought to fragment those rulers it saw as a direct threat to its autonomy by using temporal alliances, wars by proxy, and ideology. It challenged would-be hegemons and indirectly gave local notables and independent cities opportunities to grab authority.

As a result, the territorial fragmentation we observe is no accident: instead, it was deliberately instigated by the Church, in an attempt to protect its autonomy. Constant conflict with the papacy contributed to the fragmentation of authority in Europe. The Church’s chief target and rival was the Holy Roman Empire.Footnote 3 There, constant conflict with the papacy meant that central state power could not consolidate: while German emperors were frequently abroad fighting, local princes and cities assumed control over their local territories. In other areas of Europe, such as England or France, rulers could consolidate central authority more easily, either because the papacy left them alone or aided them. The material resources and institutional innovations of the Church also provided models for secular taxation, legal frameworks, and administrative division of labor (Grzymala-Busse Reference Grzymala-Busse2023a), but the Church could also hinder the adoption of these institutions by fragmenting the central authority of rulers.

In short, I argue that the Church fragmented the territorial authority of powers it saw as hostile (chiefly the Holy Roman Empire), and helped to consolidate and to strengthen states in other areas. By emphasizing the role of medieval religious authorities, this analysis also contributes to a more recent literature that has emphasized the deep (and secular) history of the European state: the influence of the Crusades (Blaydes and Paik Reference Blaydes and Paik2016), the development of legal systems (Cantoni and Yuchtman Reference Cantoni and Yuchtman2014; Møller Reference Møller2019), cities and communes (Abramson Reference Abramson2017; Møller Reference Møller2017), representative assemblies (Boucoyannis Reference Boucoyannis2021; Stasavage Reference Stasavage2010), and urban self-government and interdependence (Bosker, Eltjo, and van Zanden Reference Bosker, Eltjo and van Zanden2013; Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022). This study extends the framework first developed by Hintze ([1931] Reference Hintze and Gilbert1975) on the role of the Church in transmitting Roman precedents of the rule of law and the formalization of assemblies, as well as subsequent work exploring how the Church promoted the rule of law and diffused self-government (Bendix Reference Bendix1978; Doucette and Møller Reference Doucette and Møller2021; Ergang Reference Ergang1971; Fukuyama Reference Fukuyama2011; Kiernan Reference Kiernan1965; Møller Reference Møller2019; Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022; Poggi Reference Poggi1990).

Scholars have noted the importance of the conflict with the Church, but there has been far less focus on the Church’s direct role in fragmenting territorial authority. Thus, Møller (Reference Møller2019) focuses on the “crisis of church and state” as critical to subsequent “rise of Europe” (by which he means the multistate system, medieval parliaments, and early bureaucratic institutions) but devotes less attention to the mechanisms by which the papacy fragmented territorial rule. Møller and Doucette (Reference Møller and Doucette2022) focus on the spread of the Cluny reform program, as critical to fragmentation, urban self-government, and the rise of national assemblies. My argument here is that papal effort was the antecedent, leading to fragmentation, communes, and institutional adaptation.

Below, I argue that the Church was a critical force in medieval state formation in Europe. I first review the dominant “bellicist” account of state formation. I then take Charles Tilly to church, and examine the medieval papacy as a powerful player and adversary. The church wielded its wealth, spiritual weapons, and military alliances to deliberately fragment territorial authority and ensure its own autonomy. I examine two alternative explanations: the rise of communes and primogeniture. I conclude that the Church contributed to the lasting fragmentation of authority—and the rise of a European state system characterized by multiple competing states.

THE BELLICIST ACCOUNTS

The august bellicist accounts share several attributes. First, these analyses start with the fragmentation of territory and authority in post-Carolingian Europe, and view the decline of fragmentation as evidence for state consolidation. The starting point for state formation in Europe is the territorial fragmentation after the collapse of the Carolingian dynasty in 888 (Ertman Reference Ertman, Kaspersen and Strandbjerg2017, 63; Gorski and Sharma Reference Gorski, Sharma, Kaspersen and Strandbjerg2017, 99; Mitteraurer Reference Mitteraurer2010; Teschke Reference Teschke2003, chap. 3; Wickham Reference Wickham2016). Europe was a raft of principalities, ill-defined kingdoms, and territories controlled by local warlords. No empire arose in Europe that could compare to the Roman one: it was simply too difficult to sustain (Scheidel Reference Scheidel2019). The potential causes of this initial fragmentation vary. Scholars have pointed to the uneven emergence of urban life (Abramson Reference Abramson2017), the rise of local warlords and bands of knights (Bisson Reference Bisson1994), and the low levels of religious legitimation that made European rulers weak (Rubin Reference Rubin2017; see also Fischer Reference Fischer1992).

Second, this fragmentation declined thanks to constant interstate conflict, according to the bellicists. The relentless pressures of warfare eventually meant fewer and bigger states, a change from as many as 500 independent states in Europe in the year 1500 to 30 four centuries later (Bean Reference Bean1973, 204; Tilly Reference Tilly1992, 45–6). Repeated invasions and conflicts winnowed out weaker states and led to vigorous new efforts to tax and extract resources. Favorable geographic location meant that some states, such as Switzerland or England, could forego a military buildup. Those without such advantages, such as Poland, eventually disappeared (Downing Reference Downing1992).

More broadly, bellicists emphasize that secular conflict drove state formation. Kings, princes, and emperors fought to consolidate territory and control people and resources. Those who succeeded developed as states. War consolidated larger states and forced the building of state institutions. Following in the footsteps of Hintze, who argued that the threat of war led to the consolidation and centralization of European states, historians, sociologists, and political scientists such as Anderson ([1974] Reference Anderson2013), Bean (Reference Bean1973), Downing (Reference Downing1992), Mann (Reference Mann1986), McNeill (Reference McNeill1982), Parker (Reference Parker1992), and Tilly (Reference Tilly1992) emphasized the fierce pressures of military competition.Footnote 4

Third, the bellicist approach tends to view state institutions as the incidental “byproducts” of these preparations for war (Tilly Reference Tilly1992, 26, 75). With the Military Revolution of the sixteenth to seventeenth century, war became increasingly costly, and necessitated the formation of state administrations to extract resources (Downing Reference Downing1992; Mann Reference Mann1986, 486; Tilly Reference Tilly1992).Footnote 5 Taxes, tributes, and rents then allowed these states to wage war with greater force and success.Footnote 6 The collection of these taxes required surveillance, which in turn prompted the growth of state administrations (Tilly Reference Tilly1992) and the rise of national assemblies as sites of negotiation about taxes (North and Weingast Reference North and Weingast1989). In more fine-grained bellicist accounts, the timing and context of war shaped regime development: early military competition led to patrimonial administrations and relatively weak local governance facilitated absolutist regimes (Ertman Reference Ertman1997). Geopolitically exposed areas such as France or Russia required massive economic mobilization, and thus abolished medieval constitutionalism in favor of militarized absolutism (Downing Reference Downing1992).

Finally, the prevailing view is that the peak of state building took place in the early modern era, from roughly 1500 to 1800, also characterized by the rise of sovereignty and institutions such as parliaments. Thus, “the state” was invented as a corporate entity only in early modern Europe. That is when war became both costly and intense, increasing the pressures to consolidate and to extract resources. In the conventional periodization, state formation dates to the early modern era, from the mid-sixteenth to late eighteenth centuries, taking off only after 1600 (Ertman Reference Ertman, Kaspersen and Strandbjerg2017, 54; Tilly Reference Tilly1975, 170). Scholars of international relations often echo these claims, and argue that the modern state arose with the Treaties of Augsburg (1555) and Westphalia (1648), which established the principle of state sovereignty.Footnote 7 Thus, states grew and strengthened in Europe as a result of vicious early modern warfare, the competition for land and people that it entailed, and the mobilization of resources and people that war demanded.

THE MEDIEVAL CHURCH AS A FORCE IN STATE FORMATION

Shifting the focus to the medieval era reveals distinct aspects of state formation that the bellicist perspective may obscure: the fragmentation was persistent and not reduced by warfare, the relevant rivalry involved religious authorities, not just secular ones, and state institutions of taxation, parliaments, and justice arose long before the early modern era, often patterned on church models. As a result, many aspects of state formation date back to the medieval period, rather than the early modern era.

First, territorial fragmentation took off in the twelfth century, it was persistent, and it was unevenly distributed. Figure 1 shows the overwhelming and persistent fragmentation of the former Holy Roman Empire in comparison to the rest of Europe. The graph plots the number of states that existed over the twelfth to twentieth centuries in Europe. I take the 1900 borders of Europe, and calculate the number of states that existed within these borders over time. To construct this measure, I added historical European country borders to data on state size from Abramson (Reference Abramson2017).Footnote 8

Figure 1. The Fragmentation of Europe, 1100–1900

Contrary to the bellicists, this fragmentation did not end in the early modern era with the onset of intense warfare. The fragmentation of the Holy Roman Empire was exceptionally durable.Footnote 9 Tilly’s observation that the number of states decreased from 500 in 1500 to 20 in 1900 may need a broader context: two enormous territories, Germany and Italy, remained fractured until their political unification in the late nineteenth century (Spruyt Reference Spruyt, Kaspersen and Strandsbjerg2017, 87). This fragmentation persisted because cities and local princes gained power and precluded the assertion of central authority in these territories. As a result, there is no steady pattern of consolidation of ever-larger states through the warfare of the early modern era.

Second, religious rivalry, not interstate conflict, was critical in this earlier period of state formation. The Church, more than any secular monarch, was a powerful geopolitical force in the medieval Western Christendom, as we will see below. It assiduously sought to foment fragmentation. As a consequence, the fundamental rivalry of the medieval era was the struggle between popes and rulers over authority and supremacy (and its converse, sovereignty). The conflicts between the Church and various monarchs in the early medieval era were recurrent and unrelenting. Church efforts thus helped to prevent the rise of a hegemon in Europe, and instead maintained a more polycentric equilibrium. In maintaining this balance of power, the Church targeted what it saw as hostile rulers, allowing others, such as the Capetians in France or the Normans in England, to consolidate their power (see also Downing Reference Downing1989, 214). Both popes and monarchs were as ambitious as they were relatively weak: neither could fully enforce laws or agreements, nor claim full control of territory.Footnote 10 Moreover, spiritual and secular authorities were intermingled, as were morality and law. As a result, these conflicts were not interstate rivalries, but personalized struggles over authority.

Third, state institutions arose much earlier than required by early modern warfare. Figure 2 summarizes the pattern of institutional development across several European political entities. The bands summarize when several major state institutions arose: chanceries, cameras (accounting chambers), taxation, legal courts, and national councils and assemblies. Several patterns are evident. First, the Church was an institutional pioneer, developing these institutions as early as the eleventh century. Second, the Holy Roman Empire stands out as a late adopter. No central taxation, parliament, courts, or chancery emerged in the Empire until 1500 and they were weak and unstable once they arose. The Empire developed these institutions long after late-developing peripheral countries, such as Sweden and Poland, did. Italian institutions arose relatively early on—but these were not on the level of central government, but on the level of communes. Finally, where the pope needed rulers as allies, monarchs had more opportunity to develop state institutions in the late twelfth and thirteenth centuries. For example, successive popes relied on English kings to remain neutral in the papal conflicts on the continent, if not to aid the papacy outright. Accordingly, central state institutions in England, including a judiciary and court system, taxation, and local governance emerged in the twelfth century with little papal interference. Monarchs favored by the papacy could more easily adopt church templates for courts, chanceries, and tax collection and we see steady institutional gains in England, Spain, and France.

Figure 2. The Emergence of Central State Institutions in Europe

The church itself was the source of multiple institutional templates: legal advances, administrative precedents, and conceptual innovations. The extensive history of institutional borrowing from the Church is explored elsewhere,Footnote 11 but to give a few examples: canon scholars preserved and reinterpreted Roman law, and the idea of a state based on law. The papacy showed rulers how to collect taxes, answer the flood of petitions, and keep records and accounts. Concepts such as proctorial representation, supermajority rules, and binding consent all followed from church conciliar practice and theory. In short, the papacy and the Church provided valuable institutional prototypes. The church also provided the conduits: these templates were transmitted through church documents and legal innovations, by clerics serving in the courts and chanceries, and by bishops, who regularly sat in the royal councils and national assemblies, served as judges and chancellors, and who had both the training and the access to effectively transmit these templates.Footnote 12 Only some rulers could adopt and develop these institutional models: in areas targeted by the papacy, such as the Holy Roman Empire, these central state institutions did not develop.

This precocious institutional development also suggests that “contractarian” accounts of institutional formation also may need revision. In these accounts, institutions arise as a result of bargaining among elites in the early modern era. Specifically, these accounts argue that fiscal and representative institutions arose as commitment devices: when nobles could withdraw resources, monarchs and spending were constrained through institutions. Thus, early modern parliaments gained powers of consent and imposed constraints on the rulers in exchange for taxation and revenue (Barzel and Kiser Reference Barzel and Kiser1997; Blaydes and Chaney Reference Blaydes and Chaney2013; Hoffman and Rosenthal Reference Hoffman, Rosenthal, Drobak and Nye1997; Levi Reference Levi1988; North and Weingast Reference North and Weingast1989). Yet many of these institutions predate the early modern era: for example, medieval parliaments were powerful sites of consent, legitimation, and judgment (Boucoyannis Reference Boucoyannis2021 and Stasavage Reference Stasavage2016).Footnote 13

The Church Gains Autonomy

The Church gained autonomy and power in the late eleventh to early twelfth century. Until then, under the system of proprietary churches, lords and kings built churches, named clergy, and profited from church lands and revenues on their territory. The system made churches a lucrative source of income, and provided rulers with both revenue and military support (Joachimsen Reference Joachimsen and Morrison1978, 13). These relations were especially prevalent in the Holy Roman Empire. The Emperor also claimed the right to name the Pope: Henry III (r. 1045–56) had essentially appointed four loyalists as popes. After his death and the ensuing succession struggles, a power vacuum opened up at Rome, which the papal reformists used to ensure in 1059 that cardinals, not emperors, would now elect the pope in the newly founded College of Cardinals.

Starting in the 1050s, the papacy asserted its power within the Church (Morris Reference Morris1989, 33). The arrival of Pope Gregory VII (r. 1073–85) heralded a new era of reform, Church autonomy, and papal authority. Gregory quickly launched an ambitious reform program that freed the Church from secular interference and instilled greater discipline among the clergy. Papal power grew immensely during the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. As the papacy consolidated power within the Church, popes gained new confidence in demanding autonomy and even obedience from secular rulers.

A major episode was the Investiture Conflict (1075–1122), a conflict over papal and imperial authority that was nominally a dispute over the naming of bishops. (The “investitures” in question were the rights to name bishops.)Footnote 14 Bishops were important agents for both rulers and popes. They served as administrators for secular monarchs and the spiritual deputies of the pope. They held high spiritual and secular office, kept order and defended territory, collected taxes, issued local judgments and petitions, mediated disputes, and served as papal emissaries (Angelov and Herrin Reference Angelov, Herrin, Bang and Kołodziejczyk2012, 170; Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022; Robinson Reference Robinson1990, 423). The bishops’ loyalty was thus of paramount importance to both monarchs and popes and naming bishops was an exercise in ensuring both fealty and effective administration.

For the papacy, the Conflict served to assert papal power and to liberate the Church from secular interference (Schatz Reference Schatz1996, 81). Pope Gregory VII prohibited investiture by lay rulers as part of his reforms. Meanwhile, for the new German King Henry IV, controlling the bishoprics was critical to consolidating authority in Germany. The stakes were fundamental: “much of the emperor’s power depended on his investiture right, since it linked high church officials to the crown as a counterweight against German territorial nobles” (Clark Reference Clark1986, 668). When Henry IV began to name bishops, the Pope excommunicated him in 1075 and called on his lords to abandon Henry. Five decades of multiple excommunications, conflict, and negotiations over investiture and the delineation of temporal and ecclesiastical authority ensued.

The Concordat of Worms formally settled the controversy in 1122. The fundamental consequence of Worms was that it differentiated church from state, and helped the church to gain relative autonomy from temporal rulers. The Church selected the bishops and invested them with spiritual authority: the monarch could confer secular (but not spiritual) privileges (Robinson Reference Robinson1990, 437). The pope did not enforce the investiture agreements equally: outside of Germany, Italy, Burgundy, and France, Pope Gregory VII did not enforce lay investiture, since “he had no wish to alienate powerful rulers of the periphery” (Cowdrey Reference Cowdrey1998, 550).Footnote 15 Neither the papacy nor secular rulers could claim a decisive victory, but the Church now gained formal autonomy.

Having liberated the Church, the papacy now assumed a new “power of intervention and direction in both spiritual and secular affairs” (Southern Reference Southern1970, 34). A spectacular example is Pope Innocent III (r. 1198–1216). A proponent of papal supremacy and an ambitious leader, Innocent III threw himself into temporal politics, crowning and deposing kings, and settling disputes. His successors asserted even more authority: Innocent IV (r. 1243–54) argued that popes were above human law, and Boniface VIII (r. 1295–1303) proclaimed papal authority that extended over all beings. Popes used this power to assert the autonomy of the Church and prevent the rise of another imperial threat.Footnote 16 Papal power eventually peaked in the fourteenth century, starting with the conflict between Philip IV the Fair (r. 1285–1314) and Pope Boniface VIII (r. 1295–1303) and the Great Schism that followed (1378–1417).Footnote 17 It then waned both because the popes demanded ever more resources and jurisdiction from various monarchs, and because in the meantime, state capacity had increased thanks to the adoption of institutional models from the Church. For over two centuries, however, from roughly 1100 to 1300, the Church exercised unparalleled power in European politics.

Sources of Church Power

The medieval church was so powerful because it had considerable resources. First, there was its wealth. The medieval Church was the single biggest landowner in Europe (Spruyt Reference Spruyt1994, 44). A large portion of central Italy was a papal domain. By the time of the Reformation, over half the land in Germany was held by the Church and by the ecclesiastical princes (Goody Reference Goody1983, 131). Immediately before Henry VIII dissolved the monasteries in 1536–41, the English church held 25% of English land, whereas the crown had only 6%. These enormous land holdings were the result of earlier accumulation, in the seventh to tenth centuries, with voluntary offerings, property transfers, and bequests. Tithing entitled the Church to collect a 10% tax on all income, generating huge revenues (Morris Reference Morris1989, 388). Given this wealth, “one can hardly overestimate the importance of the Church as an economic entity in preindustrial Europe” (Cipolla Reference Cipolla1993, 45).

A second resource for the Church was its human capital: literate clerks, legal expertise, extensive documentation and archives, and administrative experience. Taxation required both authority and administrative capacity and the Church developed financial and accounting offices, as well as a network of enforcement officers. Popes sent legates across Christendom to monitor religious and fiscal discipline (Riley-Smith Reference Riley-Smith2005, 175). Clergy served at royal courts, writing letters and writs, and keeping accounts. They enforced local contracts, collected taxes, and recorded births, deaths, and wills in cathedral records. Cathedral chapters founded schools to study canon law, and kept records and relied on written documents, lowering transaction costs and allowing information to spread (Blum and Dudley Reference Blum and Dudley2001). Monasteries were a source of theological advances, a literate culture, and reformist zeal (Doucette and Møller Reference Doucette and Møller2021). The church further chartered universities and promoted the study of law starting in the late eleventh century.

Bishops were especially important, as the Investiture Conflict suggests. They held both high secular and ecclesiastical office, “providing both sacral authority and literate clerics for his chancellery, backing his judicial authority with legitimacy and efficiency” (Mann Reference Mann1986, 382–3). As late as the fourteenth century, English bishops exercised discretionary justice in parliaments, councils, and chanceries (Dodd Reference Dodd2014, 216). There was no “clear area of separate governmental responsibilities that could be termed secular” (Morris Reference Morris1989, 18). The Church provided legal arbitration and judgments for both clerics and lay people (Gilchrist Reference Gilchrist1969, 9) In short, the “great achievement of medieval civilization of the eleventh to thirteenth centuries would not have been possible but for the learning, example, and progressive character of the clergy and monks of the time” (Gilchrist Reference Gilchrist1969, 69).

Finally, the Church’s power derived from its moral authority. The Church was deeply present in everyday life as both religious and secular authority (Mann Reference Mann1986, 380). It “governed birth, marriage, and death, sex, and eating, made the rules for law and medicine, gave philosophy and scholarship their subject matter. Membership in the Church was mandatory: expulsion was tantamount to a social death” (Tuchman Reference Tuchman1978, 32). Above all, the Church offered salvation: the promise of an eternal life and divine mercy that no secular ruler could possibly match. Conversely, the Church could also exclude the faithful from this ultimate benefit, through excommunication and interdicts.

In short, its wealth, administrative capacity, and its spiritual authority made the medieval church uniquely powerful. These advantages also meant that the Church would be an institutional pioneer—and that secular rulers would adopt ecclesiastical models. The Church became an ambitious and influential political actor and it fought to retain its autonomy, preclude the rise of rival superpowers, and consolidate its own administration over souls and territory. It formed alliances with secular rulers, financed military campaigns, and deployed spiritual weapons. The result was the peculiar pattern of the fragmentation of territorial authority in some areas of Europe, and the early consolidation of central states in others.

THE IMPACT OF PAPAL RIVALRY: THE FRAGMENTATION OF EUROPE

The broad scholarly consensus is that the fragmentation of territorial authority is the foundation for subsequent political and economic modernity in Europe, a point of departure for state formation and economic development.Footnote 18

Yet this fragmentation was no accident and it was deliberately sustained. As the papacy sought first to free the Church from secular influence, and then to prevent imperial resurgence, a special target of the popes was the Holy Roman Empire, and its ruling dynasty, the Hohenstaufens, who greatly expanded its territory from 1138 to 1254. These emperors repeatedly sought to rebuild the Carolingian empire by controlling both northern Italy and Sicily. Had they succeeded in this pincer movement, they would leave the papal states surrounded by a powerful rival, and the Church again under imperial control. The papacy sought to ensure that Germany would remain fragmented and Italy under papal control.

The Church marshaled its material, human, and spiritual resources to gain an advantage against its rivals. It deliberately played rulers against each other, and used both spiritual weapons and wars by proxy to ensure that no powerful rival could arise that might threaten its political or territorial interests. Popes tried to take successive states out of Emperor’s sphere and into their own. These efforts drained the resources and attention of imperial rulers, hindering their ability to consolidate central power. These papal campaigns were so successful that Innocent IV (r. 1243–54) destroyed the imperial authority in Italy that had been already atomized in Germany, and the Hohenstaufen dynasty collapsed in 1268. Both Italy and Germany remained politically fragmented until the nineteenth century (Oakley Reference Oakley2012; Ozment Reference Ozment1980, 144; Stollberg-Rilinger Reference Stollberg-Rilinger2018).

This fragmentation persisted because newly ascendant cities and princes precluded the consolidation of central authority long after the Church’s power declined. Distracted by their attempts to annex territory in Italy, successive emperors failed to consolidate their central power. Instead, cities and princes gained regional authority relative to the emperor. First, the power vacuum after Henry III’s death in 1056 meant 20 years without a ruler in Italy, giving the initial impetus to the “communal revolution” and the rise of increasingly autonomous cities in Italy, such as Pisa, Milan, or Lucca (Hyde Reference Hyde1973, 49). These cities then began to control neighboring territory and in effect became regional powers. Second, local lords grew in power, gaining greater control over serfs and taxation at the expense of the emperor (Clark Reference Clark1986, 668; Mitteraurer Reference Mitteraurer2010, chap. 5). Bishops and abbots used the political and financial authority bestowed upon them by church to strengthen their lordship rights (Stollberg-Rilinger Reference Stollberg-Rilinger2018, 22). While the German emperors focused on the conflict with Rome, they had neither the time nor the resources to stem this leakage of authority. Communes and powerful regional princes who “grew in strength as a result of the conflict between kings and popes...could defeat any imperial plans to centralize administration or tax collection” (Hay Reference Hay1995, 317). The emperor lost power to princes, towns, and bishops, who had a vested interest in maintaining fragmentation and preventing the imposition of central state authority or institutions.

In contrast, where popes sought the cooperation of rulers, monarchs could consolidate territorial authority more easily. The papacy supported the Spanish unification and Reconquista. It sought English neutrality in its conflicts on the continent, and largely left English politics alone. Medieval England was able to centralize the state and develop its own endogenous institutions, such as common law. France until the late thirteenth century cooperated with, and benefited from, the papacy. In France, popes supported the unification and consolidation efforts of Louis VI (1108–37), Louis VII, (1137–80), and Philip Augustus (1179–1223) (Baldwin Reference Baldwin, Luscombe and Riley-Smith2004, 510). Since French monarchs tended to be allied with the Pope, the nobles could not challenge the monarch as successfully in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries and a more centralized French administrative state could develop. The French monarchs proved recalcitrant in the late thirteenth to early fourteenth century, when the papacy had grown weaker (and had moved to Avignon, from where it supported the French monarchy). In areas where the rulers posed little threat to the papacy, such as the Spanish territories, France until the end of the thirteenth century, Scandinavia, or East Central Europe, the Church was more influential in transmitting institutional templates—but also had less interest in fragmentation.

The general pattern is of fragmentation and hindering of central state development in Germany, Burgundy, and Italy, endogenous state development in England, and lower fragmentation and higher transmission of church templates elsewhere. Fischer (Reference Fischer1992) argues that the Church failed to maintain European unity (Fischer Reference Fischer1992, 438). Rubin (Reference Rubin2017) agrees that Europe was fragmented because relatively feeble religious “propagating agents” failed to legitimate secular rulers and strengthen them. Yet it is not that the Church failed to legitimate monarchs. Instead, the Church deliberately sought to balance them against each other and precluded any from gaining too much authority. Its main target and enemy was the Holy Roman Empire, which kept Italy and Germany fragmented, even as it allowed other states, such as England or Spain, to consolidate.

Weapons of the Meek? Papal Strategies of Confrontation

To protect the Church’s autonomy from secular powers and ensure its status within Europe, popes relied on both spiritual weapons and armed conflict to target individual rulers and to undermine their authority over territory and people. They excommunicated and deposed monarchs, princes, and nobles, cutting off hostile or disloyal rulers from the community of the faithful and releasing them from loyalty to the monarch (Helmholz Reference Helmholz1994; Reference Helmholz2015). They placed entire communities under interdict, cutting them off from sacraments in the hopes of fomenting disloyalty to the kings and monarchs that provoked papal displeasure. Yet these were surprisingly weak weapons. They did not consistently weaken rulers or remove them from office: excommunications destabilized monarchical rule and made it less predictable—but threatened only newer, more vulnerable rulers, and only weakly (Grzymala-Busse Reference Grzymala-Busse2023, chap. 2). This is partly because to impose excommunications successfully, popes still had to rely on secular support compliance: the “consent and cooperation of [other] secular rulers” (Southern Reference Southern1970, 20). And, these supporters could be fickle: for example, when German emperor Henry IV was excommunicated for the first time in 1076, his nobles began to abandon him and his enemies elected an anti-king. He had to beg forgiveness of the pope. However, when he was excommunicated a second time in 1080, his princes stayed loyal—and he began to again encroach on papal territories in earnest. As Møller (Reference Møller2019) points out, excommunication is “only effective if it creates opposition against the targeted ruler” (217).

As a result, popes used temporal weapons to protect their secular interests. They allied with secular rulers, using favors, financial subsidies, exemptions, and dispensations to cement these coalitions. They funded wars by proxy, armies, and joint ventures, including the Crusades, to attack their enemies. They launched ideological salvos against imperial hierarchy and hereditary monarchy. In short, the papacy used a full range of privileges and prerogatives to punish imperial holdouts and reward papal loyalists (Whalen Reference Whalen2019, 180). These strategies destabilized some rulers, maintained the fragmentation of Europe, and affected the development of central state institutions.

Papal Conflict: Alliances and Wars by Proxy

To protect their interests, popes entered into strategic coalitions with secular rulers. These alliances shifted as the balance of power changed. The papacy was opportunistic: the Lombard League of city-states was traditionally an enemy, but Pope Alexander III allied with the League to prevent Frederick I from taking over Italy, and again to battle Frederick II under Pope Gregory IX. Urban II (r. 1088–99) and Pascal II (r. 1099–1118) found it expedient to favor the Normans: when Roger I conquered Sicily, Urban recognized him and named him the papal deputy on the island (Fried Reference Fried2015, 195). Despite its overall hostility to the Hohenstaufens, the papacy could even ally with the German emperors: after the Concordat of Worms, hostilities ceased and the pope broke their costly alliance with the Normans and instead allied with the Empire (Brooke Reference Brooke1938, 264). Similarly, popes sought German help subsequently to contain Angevin ambitions in Sicily.

Popes offered protection and legitimation to allied rulers. Monarchs entered into a “feudal” relationshipFootnote 19 by surrendering land to pope, and receiving it back as a fief. The benefit was that a vassal kingdom could not be legitimately offered to another ruler and any injury to king or country was an injury to the Church (Ullmann [1955] Reference Ullmann1965, 336). In return, kings then had to pay annual tribute or perform military duties. At different points in time, Scandinavia, Hungary, Poland, Bohemia, and the British Isles were under papal lordship (Mundy Reference Mundy2000, 200). Popes also recognized the territorial grabs of their allies, but not the conquests of their foes (Hoffman Reference Hoffman2015, 132).

Popes invested heavily in their defense, and subsidized their allies. Pope Gregory IX (r. 1227–41) excommunicated Frederick II on multiple occasions, but for good measure, both he and Innocent IV (r. 1243–51) raised armies to fight the emperor and to prevent the union of Sicily with the Empire that would have consolidated imperial power on the Italian peninsula. Innocent IV sold the rights to invade Sicily to the English King Henry III for the ungodly sum of 90,000 pounds. When Henry III failed to come up with the money, the papacy negated the sale and let Charles of Anjou take Sicily instead. The papacy then supported Charles in his fight against the Empire and the Hohenstaufen line ended in defeat in 1268. The result was continued violent hostilities in Italy and the eventual retreat of imperial ambition beyond the Alps, leaving behind a fractured Italy and an atomized Holy Roman Empire (Watts Reference Watts2009, 65).

The Crusades were also an exercise in political power—and fragmenting of authority. Blaydes and Paik (Reference Blaydes and Paik2016) argue that these expeditions contributed to state formation by promoting the emergence of taxation, sales of feudal land to finance the expeditions, the reintegration of Europe into global trade networks, and the elimination of rivals to ruling monarchs (Blaydes and Paik Reference Blaydes and Paik2016). Yet these joint ventures between popes and monarchs also had explicitly temporal and local aims. Popes summoned the Crusades to defeat their rivals, rather than to defend the faith.Footnote 20 The Baltic Crusades, designed to convert Northern Europe to Christianity and to gain the pope political influence, began in 1147 and lasted through the sixteenth century. The papacy subsequently blessed the Stedinger crusade against peasants who refused to pay the tithe (1233–34), and the political crusade against the Colonna, their enemies in Rome, in 1298. In 1241, shortly before his death, Gregory IX (r. 1227–41) commissioned a crusade against German Emperor Frederick II. Pope Innocent IV (r. 1243–54) also launched a crusade against Frederick II and then against Frederick’s son, Conrad IV, excommunicating and deposing both. He summoned Germany, Lombardy, and Sicily, and offered indulgences to the crusaders as if they had been going on a crusade to the Holy Land, “creating an equivalency between the two theatres of holy war” (Whalen Reference Whalen2019, 186). Subsequently, Pope Alexander VI and then Urban IV called for a crusade against Manfred, the last Hohenstaufen king of Sicily and son of Frederick II, who invaded papal territories in 1258. This crusade was launched in 1255 and lasted until 1266, with enormous privileges granted to Charles of Anjou, an ally of the pope (Jedin Reference Jedin1993, 166). It became increasingly obvious that the aim of these military ventures, especially after the thirteenth century, became “less religious than hierarchical; it implied the domination of Church over State, and of clergy over laity, the demonstration of the civil power’s derivation from ecclesiastical” (Smith Reference Smith1964, 54).

Finally, popes used their authority to launch ideological salvos. First, they used law as a political weapon. Using new interpretations of Roman law, Pope Gregory VII fought with legal arguments, using the papal archives to buttress his arguments. When the law faculty at Bologna was founded at 1088, both popes and emperors then invested heavily in furthering legal expertise (Zacour Reference Zacour1976, 224). Second, popes articulated early concepts of state sovereignty,Footnote 21 or a ruler’s right alone to control his territory and defend it from external demands, even if no ruler at the time could actually exercise this sovereignty. Drawing on precedents from Roman law, papal decrees and canonical reinterpretations underlined the principle that a ruler need not recognize any superior, including emperors. Pope Innocent III declared in his 1202 decretal Per Venerabile that “every king [is] an emperor in his kingdom.” This doctrine was a move against imperial ambition, effectively replacing imperial hierarchy and deference with the equal standing of states. By the thirteenth century, drawing on Roman precedents and canon law, jurists recognized the sovereignty of the French, English, and Spanish kingdoms and the practical sovereignty of many city states (Canning Reference Canning1983, 4; Rigaudiere Reference Rigaudiere and Reuter1995, 21). These concepts, thus, arose long before their sixteenth-century articulation by early modern theorists such as Jean Bodin or their supposed statement at Westphalia in 1648.

All of these weapons were deployed to defend a fundamental papal aim: hindering the rise of a hegemony that could once again subordinate the Church. The outcome of these balancing tactics was the fragmentation of territorial authority in Europe.

EMPIRICAL TESTS

To test the proposition that papal conflict undermined and fragmented territorial authority in Europe, I collected data on European state boundaries over time and the conflicts that took place over the years 1000–1800 within the boundaries of Western Christendom.Footnote 22 I also include existing data on cities (Bairoch Reference Bairoch1988), sites of conflict (Dincecco and Onorato Reference Dincecco and Onorato2016), primogeniture (Kokkonen and Sundell Reference Kokkonen and Sundell2014), and parliaments (Van Zanden, Buringh, and Bosker Reference Van Zanden, Buringh and Bosker2012). The data consist of over 105,000 grid cell-year observations (see the Supplementary Material for a full description of the dataset and sources).

The measure of papal conflict, the critical explanatory variable, consists of the number of clearly identifiable wars by proxy funded or directed by popes against papal enemies, papal depositions of secular rulers, political crusades, and attacks either led or financed by the popes directly, over a rolling 5-year period. Each of these is a distinct category: wars by proxy involve rulers and clergy acting on behalf of the papacy, with tacit papal approval, but no special privileges conferred by the pope. Political crusades target specific rulers, but like other crusades, still needed to be authorized publicly by the pope, involved preaching to arms, and conferred privileges on the combatants (see Riley-Smith Reference Riley-Smith2005). Papal depositions involved the pope, usually acting in alliance with domestic barons or other secular rivals for power, to remove a ruling king of prince. Finally, there are a few cases of popes themselves leading battles.Footnote 23 Conflicts involving the Papal States, the territories directly governed by the papacy, are also coded as papal conflicts: for example, Pope Julius II (r. 1503–13) led armies to successfully defend the papal territories.

I count and add the number of such incidents involving the papacy per grid cell, without weighing the different conflict types: there is little theoretical reason to think that a war by proxy would be costlier or more effective than a political crusade, for example. An incident could also involve more than one type of conflict: as a result, if there is a war by proxy and a deposition effort against a ruler invading the Papal States, that incident would be given a value of 3. The main sources are the New Cambridge Medieval History, Brecke (Reference Brecke2012), and Dupuy and Dupuy (Reference Dupuy and Dupuy1993).

The measures of secular conflict come from Dincecco and Onorato (Reference Dincecco and Onorato2016), who code whether armed conflict occurred in a given site in the preceding 150 years among secular parties. In pre-modern Europe, religious and secular authority could overlap or blur (see the ecclesiastical princes in the Holy Roman Empire, or the consistories in early modern Protestant Europe). Therefore, by “secular conflict,” I mean only the actors involved: monarchs and princes, acting in their secular capacity as rulers against other secular forces.Footnote 24

Figure 3 plots the incidence of papal conflict with temporal rulers and secular conflict among temporal rulers. The rise in papal conflict in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries coincides with the takeoff of fragmentation of territorial authority, as the papacy reached the acme of its ambitions. Papal conflict drops in the fourteenth century: during the Avignon papacy and then the Great Schism that lasted until 1417, the weakened papacy did not launch conflicts at anywhere near the same rates. The conflicts spike again in the sixteenth century, thanks to the proxy wars of the Reformation. Secular conflict takes off later, consistent with the bellicist account of more intense early modern warfare.

Figure 3. Papal and Secular Conflict by Century

The main dependent variable is fragmentation, or the number of political authorities within a given territory. I proxy territorial fragmentation with the number of state boundaries in a given area. I divide Western Christian Europe into 100 × 100 km grid cells, and calculate the number of states within each grid cell. The number of state borders that cross the grid cell is the measure of fragmentation. Grid cells that fall entirely in one state have a value of 0 (there are no borders within the cell).Footnote 25 The results are robust to other specifications of fragmentation, such as the number of states within a given radius of a centroid of a state.Footnote 26

The literature identifies the presence of parliaments and economic development as two important forces in medieval state development. First, parliaments may help to consolidate authority: parliaments constrain monarchs and lead to power sharing, thus stabilizing rule (Blaydes and Chaney Reference Blaydes and Chaney2013; Ertman Reference Ertman1997; Stasavage Reference Stasavage2010). I use the indicators of parliamentary presence from Van Zanden, Buringh, and Bosker (Reference Van Zanden, Buringh and Bosker2012), which measure the number of years per century that parliaments met in a given state. Second, urbanization serves as a standard proxy used in the literature for economic development. Cities themselves may also contribute to fragmentation, since the rise of cities drove the survival of smaller units in Europe (Abramson Reference Abramson2017), and dense urban populations drove both economic growth and institutional development (Acharya and Lee Reference Acharya and Lee2019). I therefore use the number of cities with population over 5,000, using data from Bosker, Eltjo, and van Zanden (Reference Bosker, Eltjo and van Zanden2013). I include whether or not a given cell belonged to the Holy Roman Empire, to ensure that the results are not simply driven by papal hostility to the emperor. Moreover, the shape of the Holy Roman Empire changed over time: Burgundy became part after 1032, the empire withdrew from Northern Italy after 1250, and the Empire itself was dissolved in 1806. I also include a coding for Protestant in the early modern period, in case the results are driven by the struggles of the Reformation.Footnote 27 The measure for Protestant consists of the number of cities coded as Protestant by Cantoni (Reference Cantoni2012) within the grid cell.

In all analyses, I use ordinary least squares regressions with two-way grid cell and year fixed effects, which approximate a difference-in-difference design with observational data and control for time- and space-invariant factors such as climate, elevation, agricultural suitability, and proximity to ports and coasts. Robust standard errors are clustered around grid cells. To capture the theorized difference between the medieval and early modern periods in papal strength, I split the sample into medieval (1000–1350) and early modern (1450–1750) periods to reflect the distinct periods of papal power. This periodization is substantiated by structural break tests (see Section 3 of the Supplementary Material). I report the results for both the entire time period, and the two specific eras.

If the Church deepened the fragmentation of territorial authority in Europe, we would expect conflict with the popes to be strongly and positively associated with the fragmentation of authority. As Figure 4 reports, that is indeed the case for the entire period examined, even when we include several potential other factors that might have led to fragmentation. The horizontal lines represent 95% confidence intervals for a given variable.

Figure 4. Explanations for the Fragmentation of Europe, 1000–1800

Note: Bands indicate 95% confidence intervals around coefficient estimates.

Table 1 reports the results from Figure 4 (model 1), and from the medieval and early modern periods. Over the entire time period examined, from 1000 to 1800, papal conflict is consistently and positively associated with the fragmentation of territorial authority (model 1). In the medieval period, papal conflict is strongly, positively, and consistently associated with fragmentation. These results are robust to the inclusion of both parliaments and urbanization. Parliaments are negatively associated with fragmentation and cities are positively associated, in keeping with the existing literature. Parliaments indicate some measure of state institutional consolidation. Medieval cities, on the other hand, arose where central powers were weak. The coefficient on medieval papal conflict is even higher when these two variables are included, and retains its significance (compare models 2 and 3).Footnote 28 Status as part of the Holy Roman Empire is not independently associated with fragmentation in the Middle Ages. These results are robust both to other measures of fragmentation, and to placebo tests (see Tables A.2–A.5 in the Supplementary Material).

Table 1. Papal Conflict Increases Territorial Fragmentation

Note: * $ p<0.05 $ , ** $ p<0.01 $ , *** $ p<0.001 $ .

In the early modern period, papal conflict initially appears to be positively and even more strongly associated with fragmentation (models 4 and 5). However, once we include status as Protestant for a given cell of territory, this relationship disappears (model 6). The enormous upheaval of Protestant Reformation, the papal efforts to fight it, and the wars that followed meant that there was a great deal of papal conflict, and nearly all of it was tied to the religious status of a territory. Contrary to bellicist predictions, secular conflict appears to be positively associated with territorial fragmentation during this period. These patterns are not simply an artefact of the Holy Roman Empire, where the Reformation took off and where several massive wars took place.Footnote 29 That said, membership in the Holy Roman Empire, unsurprisingly, is also associated with increased fragmentation.

Contrary to the bellicists, then, temporal warfare does not seem to consolidate states. This may be because many states either consolidated before the early modern period (England, Spain, and Portugal) or long after (Germany, Italy, and Poland). Further, devastating early modern wars, such as the Thirty Years’ War (1618–1848), were fought mostly on the already fragmented territory of the Holy Roman Empire, and did little to consolidate it. Instead, religious conflict instigated by the popes is closely associated with the fragmentation of territorial authority in Europe.

Alternative Religious Explanations

Two other potential sources of fragmentation (and consolidation) are both related to the Church itself, and could serve as religious confounders.

First, inheritance regimes may explain fragmentation. Specifically, primogeniture (the inheritance of all land and office by the oldest son) acts to prevent territorial fragmentation, whereas partible inheritance divides the land under a ruler’s control among several heirs. Primogeniture and female inheritance can be traced back to earlier changes in the Church family and marriage laws designed to funnel wealth into the Church (Goody Reference Goody1983; see also Møller Reference Møller2019, 217). The Church introduced changes in marriage law, beginning in earnest in the tenth century, including monogamy, stricter definitions of legitimate children, constraints on marriage among distant relatives, and prohibitions on adoption and divorce (Acharya and Lee Reference Acharya and Lee2019; Goody Reference Goody1983; Gorski and Sharma Reference Gorski, Sharma, Kaspersen and Strandbjerg2017, 204). Many of these allowed the Church to benefit financially, since they limited the number of potential heirs—and increased the probability the assets would revert to the Church. These changes in family law, in turn, prompted the rise of primogeniture (Kokkonen and Sundell Reference Kokkonen and Sundell2014; Møller Reference Møller2019).

Primogeniture emerged around 1000, and was adopted by the Capetians in twelfth-century France and within many families within the Holy Roman Empire by the thirteenth to fourteenth century (Goody Reference Goody1983, 118; Wilson Reference Wilson2016, 425). Along with other changes in family law, primogeniture stabilized monarchical rule in Western Christendom and beyond (Acharya and Lee Reference Acharya and Lee2019; Brundage Reference Brundage2009; Goody Reference Goody1983; Sharma Reference Sharma2015). Kokkonen and Sundell (Reference Kokkonen and Sundell2014) find that primogeniture extended and stabilized ruler tenure. Since primogeniture is also the basis for dynastic unions of territory, we might expect it to lower fragmentation (Sharma Reference Sharma2015, 169; Teschke Reference Teschke2003, 225). In contrast, other scholars emphasize that such unions, and therefore primogeniture, did not consolidate territorial gains (Bonner Reference Bonner2003; Fichtner Reference Fichtner1976; Joseph Reference Joseph2015; Sharp Reference Sharp, Higham and Hill2001; Wilson Reference Wilson2016, 436).Footnote 30

Second, the rise of communes from the late eleventh century to the twelfth century would prevent rulers from establishing and centralizing territorial authority (Abramson Reference Abramson2017; Rokkan Reference Rokkan and Tilly1975; Tilly Reference Tilly1992; Tilly and Blockmans Reference Tilly and Blockmans1994; Wickham Reference Wickham2015; Reference Wickham2016). In the “city belt” that stretched from central Italy to North Germany, self-governing towns arose where the central government was too weak to assert control (Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022; see also Stasavage Reference Stasavage2010; Reference Stasavage2020, chap. 5). They arose where rulers were preoccupied with papal conflict: communes filled in the vacuum left behind by the withdrawal of imperial authority in Italy. They are thus an indirect result of papal conflict with the emperors (Hyde Reference Hyde1973; Wickham Reference Wickham2015). Further, as Doucette and Møller show, the Church itself diffused norms of local self-governance through bishops and monastic reform (Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022). Thus, cities expanded greatly in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries, after the fragmentation of the eleventh to twelfth century.Footnote 31 I therefore include both communes (data from Van Zanden, Buringh, and Bosker Reference Van Zanden, Buringh and Bosker2012) and primogeniture (data from Kokkonen and Sundell Reference Kokkonen and Sundell2014) in the analyses.

Table 2 reports the results from Figure 5 (model 1), and from the medieval and early modern periods. Papal conflict has a very strong and positive association with fragmentation over the entire time period examined, from 1000 to 1800 (model 1). Secular conflict is not associated with territorial consolidation or fragmentation. The coefficients on parliaments are negative and on cities positive, as expected. Primogeniture and communes also have a positive relationship with fragmentation. As in Table 1 and throughout, I use two-way cell and year fixed effects and robust standard errors clustered around the cells.

Table 2. Papal Conflict Increases Territorial Fragmentation: Religious Confounders

Note: * $ p<0.05 $ , ** $ p<0.01 $ , *** $ p<0.001 $ .

Figure 5. Average Marginal Impact of Papal Conflict in the Holy Roman Empire

Note: Brackets indicate 95% confidence intervals.

In the medieval period, papal conflict is strongly associated with territorial fragmentation, even as parliaments, urbanization, primogeniture, and communes continue to play a role (model 2). Primogeniture does not lower fragmentation, consistent with the argument that medieval dynastic unions did not permanently unite territory, and did not lead to the expansion of authority (Joseph Reference Joseph2015). Communes also have a strong and positive relationship, consistent with their arising in territory where central authority was weak.

Subsequently, in the early modern period, we initially see papal conflict has a strong and positive relationship with fragmentation (model 3), which drops out once we include a cell’s status as Protestant (model 4). Papal conflict, then, disappears as a factor in early modern fragmentation. Neither primogeniture nor communes are associated with early modern fragmentation: the single most important factor becomes membership in the Holy Roman Empire, which in the early modern era is powerfully associated with fragmentation.

In short, medieval conflict with the papacy is strongly associated with territorial fragmentation, independently of parliaments, urbanization, primogeniture, and communes. In the early modern period, papal conflict is so strongly associated with the wars of the Reformation that its independent association with fragmentation drops out. Secular conflict is not associated with the consolidation of territorial authority.

Reverse Causation?

Conflict with the popes is thus closely associated with medieval fragmentation, consistent with the proposition that medieval popes actively fragmented territorial authority. An alternative interpretation may be that popes were more likely to enter into conflict with rulers in already fragmented areas, opportunistically targeting rulers who were weak, rather than going after powerful rivals.

Yet the historical evidence suggests that this reversed causation is implausible. First, there are the papacy’s stated intentions. Medieval popes deliberately and consistently targeted what they considered to be their biggest threat: the Holy Roman Empire. Among their first targets in the twelfth century were the Hohenstaufen emperors (1079–1254), whom they denounced as a “brood of vipers” for their designs on Italian territories (Abulafia Reference Abulafia and Abulafia1999, 506; Toch Reference Toch and Abulafia1999). Second, there is sequencing: the Empire fragmented after papal efforts began in earnest in the late twelfth century, but not before (see Figure 1 and Doucette and Møller Reference Doucette and Møller2021). Popes did not target already fragmented territories.

Third, there are the geographic patterns of papal conflict: in the peripheral areas, popes tended either to stay out of domestic politics (as in England), or offered assistance to their allies. Since smaller and weaker rulers did not pose a threat to church autonomy, they were not the main target of papal efforts. Indeed, the papacy served a very different role in the periphery of Europe. For example, Polish kings allied with the papacy and joined in the fight against the empire, and the papacy actively helped state builders to consolidate rule (Ertman Reference Ertman1997, 279–80; Wyrozumski Reference Wyrozumski, Luscombe and Riley-Smith2004, 281). Instead of meddling, the papacy even allowed these rulers to name their bishops and exert secular control over the Church, in the name of preserving their alliances (Kotecki Reference Kotecki, Kotecki, Maciejewski and Ott2018, 308; Obertyński and Kumor Reference Obertyński and Kumor1974, 60, 360).

Empirical Implications: The Holy Roman Empire

Since the Holy Roman Empire posed the greatest threat to the papacy and the autonomy of the Church, it became a principal target of papal efforts. As a result, we should see greater fragmentation in the areas of the Holy Roman Empire as a result of papal conflict. To test this empirical implication, I interact papal conflict with a given grid cell belonging to the Holy Roman Empire. Figure 5 shows that consistent with the explanation advanced here, papal conflict has a strong and positive marginal association with fragmentation in the Holy Roman Empire, while it has a much lower (if still positive) association with fragmentation in non-imperial lands. This is consistent with the proposition that papal conflict fragmented authority everywhere: but where the papacy targeted specific rulers (here, the Emperors), the result was particularly intense fragmentation.

Empirical Implications: The Rise of Communes

This literature further suggests that papal conflict led to both the fragmentation of territorial authority and the rise of communes. As Max Weber and Otto Hintze have already noted, towns seized autonomy and control during the conflict between popes and emperors in the late eleventh century, and in the subsequent imperial power vacuum (Ertman Reference Ertman, Kaspersen and Strandbjerg2017, 61; Ringer Reference Ringer2004, 206; Rokkan Reference Rokkan1999; Weber Reference Weber1958). Cities could carve out a sphere of independent activity, of relative autonomy and burgher rights. Local self-governance started to take off after 1000, and then grew further in the shadow of imperial–papal conflict: self-governing towns arose where the central government was too weak to assert control (Doucette and Møller Reference Doucette and Møller2021; Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022, 55ff; Wickham Reference Wickham2015, 9; Reference Wickham2016, 148ff; Watts Reference Watts2009, 99). To curry local support, both popes and emperors granted new charters with substantial privileges to lay officials and new political rights, which “only strengthened the sense of agency that the urban population felt,” giving new agency, urgency, and responsibilities to communal self-government (Witt Reference Witt2012, 206).

For their part, bishops often cooperated with the creation of communes, and medieval communal institutions then mirrored religious ones (Coleman Reference Coleman1999, 394–5; Schwartzberg Reference Schwartzberg2014, 51; see especially Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022). But bishops could also have highly antagonistic relationship with urban self-government, one that could even erupt in violence and murder: the Roman commune arose in the 1140s to rebel against papal authority, also eventually resorting to violence, while the good burghers of Laon in France murdered their overweening bishop in 1112. Communes often served as “an instrument of liberation from the captivity of worldly and abusive bishops” (Malegam Reference Malegam2013, 231).

Figure 6 shows that in the entire sample, papal conflict, secular conflict, and fragmentation all show a positive relationship to the rise of communes. Parliaments and the presence of cities are also positively and strongly associated, in keeping with the existing literature.

Figure 6. Papal Conflict and Fragmentation Are Associated with the Rise of Communes

Note: Bands indicate 95% confidence intervals around coefficient estimates.

Table 3 shows the results from Figure 6 (model 1), and from the medieval and early modern periods. Once we disaggregate the data into medieval and early modern eras, two distinct patterns emerge. In the medieval era, papal conflict is consistently and positively associated with communes. Fragmentation and the presence of bishops are also positively and independently associated with communes. Secular conflict is not. This is consistent with the argument that the power vacuum associated with papal conflict and territorial fragmentation allowed medieval communes to flourish. In the early modern period, in contrast, these variables no longer predict the rise of communes. This is because communes themselves changed: Italian communes became regional powers, expanding their authority over surrounding territory and ceding governance to prominent families and cartels. Elsewhere, communes fell under the renewed control of local nobles and princes. Borders stabilized and power vacuums disappeared, so that conflict and fragmentation were no longer a factor. Many local parliaments simply disappeared.

Table 3. Communes

Note: * $ p<0.05 $ , ** $ p<0.01 $ , *** $ p<0.001 $ .

These empirical regularities are consistent with the core argument of this paper: that medieval papal conflict with emperors, monarchs, and princes fragmented territorial authority, allowing other forms of autonomous governance to arise and escape imperial control in the Middle Ages.

CONCLUSION: MISSA FINITA EST?

Bellicist accounts argue that the medieval fragmentation of Europe gave way to state consolidation through warfare. In these accounts, secular conflict winnowed out small states and institutions arose in response to the pressures of war. Early modern warfare ended the territorial fragmentation of Europe and incidentally established state institutions.

This article argues instead that the roots of the European state reach back further, to the medieval era, and to a different set of actors. Fragmentation was deliberate, persistent, and popes helped to sustain it. States did not consolidate uniformly: the Church contributed to the fragmentation of territorial authority of powers it saw as hostile (chiefly the Holy Roman Empire), and helped to consolidate the development of the central state in other areas. War was neither necessary nor sufficient to build states, in both the medieval and early modern eras: some highly fragmented states survived until the nineteenth century, whereas others consolidated without the pressures of war. Indeed, papal conflict increased fragmentation in the medieval period, and secular conflict in the early modern. By the same token, state institutions arose centuries before early modern warfare would have necessitated them; in those lands medieval rulers could consolidate power and adopt ecclesiastical innovations.

By shifting attention to the greatest geopolitical rival of the medieval era, the Catholic Church, we gain a new perspective on state formation in Europe. State formation began earlier, and this medieval state development differed from early modern in the key protagonists, motivations, and mechanisms. Medieval state formation was shaped by religious authority. Popes and bishops, rather than kings alone, were critical. That said, the motivation for the popes was not religious ideology or doctrine, but the institutional autonomy of the Church. The medieval papacy was consumed with preventing the resurrection of a rival superpower, the German Empire, and used everything from legal arguments, to proxy wars and crusades to achieve its aims. The mechanisms of this earlier episode of state formation thus consisted of both rivalry and emulation, of both temporal alliances and ideological weapons, rather than interstate conflict that somehow necessitated state institutions.

This argument builds on both an older tradition that notes how the Church helped to diffuse the rule of law and administrative norms throughout Europe, and more recent work that emphasizes the importance of the Church to medieval state building and its legacies (Hintze [1931] Reference Hintze and Gilbert1975; Bendix Reference Bendix1978; Doucette and Møller Reference Doucette and Møller2021; Ergang Reference Ergang1971; Fukuyama Reference Fukuyama2011; Grzymala-Busse Reference Grzymala-Busse2020; Kiernan Reference Kiernan1965; Møller and Doucette Reference Møller and Doucette2022; Poggi Reference Poggi1990). The contribution of this analysis is to compare the impact of the Church to other sources of fragmentation, specify the secular and temporal tactics used by the Church, and draw our attention to the direct mechanisms that helped to fragment territorial authority (papal conflict) and the indirect ones (empowering nobles and communes).

The irony is that with these successes, the Church ordained its own fall from grace. The very political fragmentation that it fomented meant that subsequently, when the Protestant Reformation took off, individual princes and lords could protect the new rival religion from a reassertion of Catholic monopoly. It is no accident that the Reformation took off in fragmented Germany, or that Frederick III, the Elector of Saxony, could successfully protect Luther against the vengeance of both the Pope and the German Emperor. In battling monarchs with both laws and arms, the Church led these rulers to sharpen their own legal arguments and buttress their own administrative and legal infrastructure. Secular nobles replaced bishops and clerics in the administration. Within kingdoms, rulers increasingly decided who would serve and who could govern the Church.

In winning battles, the Church lost the war. Yet this eventual supremacy of the state would not be possible without the medieval church, the clashing ambitions of medieval popes and rulers, and the early state formation they engendered.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055423000278.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Research documentation and data that support the findings of this study are openly available in the American Political Science Review Dataverse at https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/DWQLIB.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I am grateful to Advait Arun and especially Hans Lueders for their expert research assistance. My thanks go to Avi Acharya, Scott Abramson, Lisa Blaydes, Gary Cox, Lauren Davenport, Rowan Dorin, Pauline Jones, Jørgen Møller, David Stasavage, Daniel Ziblatt, the three anonymous reviewers, and the participants of seminars at Duke University, Harvard University, the University of Southern California, Johns Hopkins University, The Ohio State University, Princeton University, Stanford University, Texas A&M University, and the University of Wisconsin–Madison for their valuable comments.

FUNDING STATEMENT

Some of this research was funded by the Guggenheim Foundation Fellowship.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The author declares no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

ETHICAL STANDARDS

The author affirms this research did not involve human subjects.

Footnotes

1 State formation is the process by which rulers amass authority over territory and populations. The “state” is an anachronism in the Middle Ages, when “lordship” would have been more intelligible (Davies Reference Davies2003). Nonetheless, we can still meaningfully discuss the stated goals of these rulers: (a) a more effective set of mechanisms through which they could exercise authority, such as the nomination of officials, a legal apparatus, and taxation and resource extraction (state building) and (b) the assertion of that authority over people and territory, free from internal rivals or external interference (sovereignty).

2 This was also the critical period for the rise of cities, the growth of commerce and trade networks (including the founding of the Hanseatic League and the expansion of trade to Asia), the development of law and reinterpretation of Roman law, the rise of universities, and new scientific and technological advances.

3 In Voltaire’s famous dictum, the Holy Roman Empire was none of those things. The empire became “Holy” under Barbarossa, and “Roman” in 1254 (Sulovsky Reference Sulovsky2019). “Of the German Nation” was added in the fifteenth century.

4 Thomas Ertman differentiates Hintze’s earlier work, with its emphasis on the geopolitical context and war, from his later scholarship, which emphasized uneven state development: rulers in the core of the former Carolingian empire, such as France, built bureaucratic administrative institutions with which they could challenge local lords. The periphery developed strong local governments and lords that could either accompany a powerful monarch (as in England) or dominate weak ones (as in Poland, Hungary, or Bohemia) (Ertman Reference Ertman, Kaspersen and Strandbjerg2017, 63–5). This balance of power and local assemblies leading to the emergence of representative institutions are important themes in Downing (Reference Downing1992), Ergang (Reference Ergang1971), Ertman (Reference Ertman1997), and Kiernan (Reference Kiernan1965).

5 Tilly and Mann both also examine the interplay of capital and war, acknowledging that bargaining processes with social classes, most notably capitalists, were critical in generating revenue and thus variation in state building. See also Anderson ([1974] Reference Anderson2013).

6 Historians working in this multidisciplinary tradition focused on the intentional development of specific institutions of the fiscal state, analyzing the early modern regimes of taxation, extraction, and war-making, rather than viewing them as incidental (Bonney Reference Bonney1999; Brewer Reference Brewer1989; Glete Reference Glete2002; Stone Reference Stone1994).

7 See Held (Reference Held1995), Morgenthau (Reference Morgenthau1985), Philpott (Reference Philpott2001), and Watson (Reference Watson1992). Others dispute the idea that Westphalia marked the rise of state sovereignty (see Krasner Reference Krasner, Goldstein and Keohane1993; Osiander Reference Osiander2001; Teschke Reference Teschke2003). Yet, as de Carvalho, Leira, and Hobson (Reference de Carvalho, Leira and Hobson2011) note, the textbook consensus on the importance of 1648 remains.

8 Data from the Mosaic historical maps project: https://censusmosaic.demog.berkeley.edu/data/historical-gis-files (accessed August 2021).

9 The one dip is in the aftermath of the Thirty Years’ War, when Sweden temporarily conquered large swathes of German territory.

10 As Gorski and Sharma (Reference Gorski, Sharma, Kaspersen and Strandbjerg2017) and Sharma (Reference Sharma2015) point out, rulers struggled over authority and control of people more than over territory per se.

11 In a series of works, Møller (Reference Møller2015; Reference Møller2017; Reference Møller2018; Reference Møller2019) emphasizes that modern legal institutions and parliamentary practices are rooted in the Middle Ages. Grzymala-Busse (Reference Grzymala-Busse2023) traces at the emulation and adoption of state institutions, such as courts, parliaments, and administrations.

12 These templates did not comprise a wholesale importation, as earlier work might have suggested (Strayer Reference Strayer1970; Ullmann [1955] Reference Ullmann1965). As Hintze notes, “procedures and ideas of these chancelleries passed from country to country, from court to court, and that in this way a certain uniformity of thinking about politics and administration was established which gave way only much later to the advancing differentiation of national characters” (Hintze [1931] Reference Hintze and Gilbert1975, 318).

13 That said, the rise of administrative institutions is not equivalent to the rise of the state (Sharma Reference Sharma, Kaspersen and Strandsbjerg2017, 217) and state capacity is distinct from the territorial state (Spruyt Reference Spruyt, Kaspersen and Strandsbjerg2017, 84).

14 Popes endowed bishops with their spiritual powers, whereas secular rulers endowed the clergy, bishops, and abbots as vassals to monarchs. As part of the ceremony, the king would present a bishop with the symbols of religious office: the staff and the ring, and with rights and privileges (regalia). The clergy would then swear fealty to the ruler who named them.

15 Bueno de Mesquita (Reference Bueno de Mesquita2000; Reference Bueno de Mesquita2022) argues that Worms and lay investiture drove a permanent wedge between kings and popes, by incentivizing the former to promote economic development and the latter to hamper growth. Yet the struggle between popes and kings continued and lay investiture itself applied inconsistently and unevenly. For example, some kings, such as the French Louis VII in 1149 or Philip in 1203, voluntarily withdrew their rights to name bishops (Baldwin Reference Baldwin, Luscombe and Riley-Smith2004, 518, 524).

16 That said, the Church was not a monolithic institution. Clergy initially opposed the elimination of clerical marriage and concubinage introduced by Gregory VII in the late eleventh century (though they came around by the II Lateran Council of 1139). Several schisms racked the Church, as competing popes emerged in 1130 and 1159 and famously during the Great Schism of 1378–1417. Bishops often “interpreted” papal requests or declarations in their favor (Dorin Reference Dorin2021).

17 The eventual consequence of this conflict was the exile of the papacy to Avignon, an area firmly under Philip’s control, where it remained from 1309 to 1376. The Great Schism then ensued from 1378 to 1417, 40 years that saw competing papacies, highly politicized claims, and the eventual resolution of the crisis by secular rulers, rather than councils or clergy (Kaminsky Reference Kaminsky and Jones2000, 680).

19 Since the mid-1990s, most medievalists have followed Susan Reynolds in questioning the concepts of fief, vassalage, and feudalism as misleading. See Reynolds (Reference Reynolds1996).

20 Popes also launched crusades against domestic religious dissent. Thus, Innocent III (1198–1216) launched Crusades against Muslim Spain and the Albigensian Crusade against the Cathars in 1209.

21 Concepts of medieval political authority, statehood, and sovereignty (autonomy from outside interference and control over internal affairs) are debated extensively (Costa Lopez Reference Costa Lopez2020; Friedrichs Reference Friedrichs2001; Hall and Kratochwil Reference Hall and Kratochwil1993; Little and Buzan Reference Little, Buzan, Hobdon and Hobson2002; Ruggie Reference Ruggie1983).

22 The Great Schism of 1054 split the Church into a Western and Eastern rite. The Church in the Eastern rite never gained its autonomy, did not function independently of the state, and instead continued to be controlled by the Byzantine emperor. The territories of modern Bulgaria, Greece, Romania, Russia, and Serbia all followed the Eastern rite, and are not part of the analysis.

23 The military ventures of medieval popes tended to end in disaster. When Pope Leo IX (r. 1049–54) fought the Normans in Southern Italy in 1053, the Normans easily defeated his army and took him prisoner (Jordan Reference Jordan2001, 87). When Innocent II took the field himself against Roger of Sicily in 1139, he, too, was taken prisoner and had to accede to Roger’s demand for control of Sicily and Apulia (Brooke Reference Brooke1938, 276). History repeated in 1156 (Robinson Reference Robinson1990, 367).

24 Papal conflict and secular conflict, as measured here, do not overlap significantly: the pairwise correlation is 0.025, at $ p=0.05 $ .

25 The data come from MPIDR (Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research) and CGG (Chair for Geodesy and Geoinformatics, University of Rostock) 2013: MPIDR Population History GIS Collection, Mosaic Census Collection.

26 See Tables A.2 and A.3 in the Supplementary Material for two specifications using the number of state borders within the 100-km and 250-km radii of state centroids as a measure of fragmentation.

27 The spread of Protestantism itself in the early modern era may have been endogenous to medieval fragmentation: it took off in the fragmented territories of the Holy Roman Empire, the Low Countries, and East Central Europe. Various princes protected the nascent religious reforms within their territories, whereas others maintained a commitment to Catholicism.

28 Oster sensitivity tests report the delta, or the estimate of proportional bias due to unobservables. Oster (Reference Oster2019) proposes 1 as a conventional threshold. Negative signs suggest that the effect of the unobservables would have to run in the opposite reaction for the beta to be 0.

29 The collinearity between Protestant and Papal Conflict disappears when I reran the same models on state-level data. All the other variables retained their previous relationship (see Tables A.2 and A.3 in the Supplementary Material). This is because the data on Protestantism are measured on the city level. The state-level dataset aggregates these into state-level averages, but the raster dataset does not.

30 Despite prominent examples such as the union of Aragon and Castile through the marriage of Ferdinand and Isabella, or the uxorious expansion of early modern Austria, the main reasons for contracting such marriages were alliances rather than uniting territory. Territorial acquisition through dynastic unions only emerged after the fifteenth century, and could not be responsible for medieval territorial fragmentation or consolidation. Even in Habsburg Austria, the rapid accumulation of dynastic possessions in 1477–1536 did not expand the empire. Dynastic gains in the other most likely case, England, were only temporary.

31 For example, Germany went from 250 cities in 1200 to over a thousand a century later (Jedin Reference Jedin1993, 322ff).

References

Abramson, Scott. 2017. “The Economic Origins of the Territorial State.” International Organization 71 (1): 97140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abulafia, David. 1999. “The Kingdom of Sicily under the Hohenstaufen and Angevins.” In The New Cambridge Medieval History, vol. 5, ed. Abulafia, David, 497–521. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acharya, Avidit, and Lee, Alexander. 2019. “Path Dependence in European Development: Medieval Politics, Conflict, and State Building.” Comparative Political Studies 52 (13–14): 2171–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Perry. [1974] 2013. Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: Verso Books.Google Scholar
Angelov, Dimiter, and Herrin, Judith. 2012. “The Christian Imperial Tradition—Greek and Latin.” In Universal Empire: A Comparative Approach to Imperial Culture and Representation in Eurasian History, eds. Bang, Peter F. and Kołodziejczyk, Dariusz, 149–74. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bairoch, Paul. 1988. Cities and Economic Development: From the Dawn of History to the Present. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, John. 2004. “The Western Franks: Crown and Government.” In The New Cambridge Medieval History, vol. 4, eds. Luscombe, David and Riley-Smith, Jonathan, 510–29. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Yoram, and Kiser, Edgar. 1997. “The Development and Decline of Medieval Voting Institutions: A Comparison of England and France.” Economic Inquiry 35 (2): 244–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bean, Richard. 1973. “War and the Birth of the Nation State.” Journal of Economic History 33 (1): 203–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendix, Reinhard. 1978. Kings or People: Power and the Mandate to Rule. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bisson, Thomas N. 1994. “The ‘Feudal revolution’.” Past & Present 142: 642.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa, and Chaney, Eric. 2013. “The Feudal Revolution and Europe’s Rise: Political Divergence of the Christian West and the Muslim World before 1500 CE.” American Political Science Review 107 (1): 1634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa, and Paik, Christopher. 2016. “The Impact of Holy Land Crusades on State Formation: War Mobilization, Trade Integration, and Political Development in Medieval Europe.” International Organization 70 (3): 136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blum, Ulrich, and Dudley, Leonard. 2001. “Religion and Economic Growth: Was Weber Right?Journal of Evolutionary Economics 11: 207–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonner, Elizabeth. 2003. “Charles VII’s Dynastic Policy and the ‘Auld Alliance’: The Marriage of James II and Marie de Guelders.” Innes Review 54 (2): 143–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonney, Richard, ed. 1999. The Rise of the Fiscal State in Europe, c. 1200–1815. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bosker, Maarten, Eltjo, Buringh, and van Zanden, Jan Luiten. 2013. “From Baghdad to London: Unraveling Urban Development in Europe, the Middle East, and North Africa, 800–1800.” Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (4): 1418–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucoyannis, Deborah. 2021. Kings as Judges: Power, Justice, and the Origins of Parliaments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brecke, Peter. 2012. The Conflict Catalog Data Set. https://brecke.inta.gatech.edu/research/conflict/.Google Scholar
Brewer, John. 1989. The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State, 1688–1783. New York: Alfred A Knopf.Google Scholar
Brooke, Zachary Nugent 1938. A History of Europe from 911 to 1198. London: Methuen & Co.Google Scholar
Brundage, James A. 2009. Law, Sex, and Christianity in Medieval Europe. Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce. 2000. “Popes, Kings, and Endogenous Institutions: The Concordat of Worms and the Origins of Sovereignty.” International Studies Review 2 (2): 93118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce. 2022. The Invention of Power. New York: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Canning, Joseph. 1983. “Ideas of the State in Thirteenth and Fourteenth-Century Commentators on the Roman Law.” Transactions of the Royal Historical Society 33: 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cantoni, Davide. 2012. “Adopting a New Religion: The Case of Protestantism in 16th Century Germany.” Economic Journal 122 (50): 502–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cantoni, Davide, and Yuchtman, Noam. 2014. “Medieval Universities, Legal Institutions, and the Commercial Revolution.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (2): 823–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Centeno, Miguel Angel. 2002. Blood and Debt: War and the Nation-State in Latin America. University Park, PA: Penn State Press.Google Scholar
Cipolla, Carlo. 1993. Before the Industrial Revolution: European Society and Economy 1000–1700. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Clark, David. 1986. “The Medieval Origins of Modern Legal Education: Between Church and State.” American Journal of Comparative Law 35: 653719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, Edward. 1999. “The Italian Communes. Recent Work and Current Trends.” Journal of Medieval History 25 (4): 373–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa Lopez, Julia. 2020. “Political Authority in International Relations: Revisiting the Medieval Debate.” International Organization 74 (2): 222–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowdrey, Herbert. 1998. Pope Gregory VII: 1073-1085. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, Rees. 2003. “The Medieval State: The Tyranny of a Concept?Journal of Historical Sociology 16 (2): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Carvalho, Benjamin, Leira, Halvard, and Hobson, John M.. 2011. “The Big Bangs of IR: The Myths That Your Teachers Still Tell You about 1648 and 1919.” Millennium 39 (3): 735–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, Mark, and Onorato, Massimo. 2016. “Military Conflict and the Rise of Urban Europe.” Journal of Economic Growth 21 (3): 259–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, Mark, and Wang, Yuhua. 2018. “Violent Conflict and Political Development over the Long Run: China versus Europe.” Annual Review of Political Science 21: 341–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dodd, Gwilym. 2014. “Reason, Conscience, and Equity: Bishops as the King’s Judges in Later Medieval England.” History 99 (335): 213–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doner, Richard F., Ritchie, Bryan K., and Slater, Dan. 2005. “Systemic Vulnerability and the Origins of Developmental States: Northeast and Southeast Asia in Comparative Perspective.” International Organization 59 (2): 327–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorin, Rowan. 2021. “The Bishop as Lawmaker in Late Medieval Europe.” Past & Present 253: 4582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doucette, Jonathan Stavnskaer, and Møller, Jørgen. 2021. “The Collapse of State Power, the Cluniac Reform Movement, and the Origins of Urban Self-Government in Medieval Europe.” International Organization 75 (1): 204–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downing, Brian. 1989. “Medieval Origins of Constitutional Government in the West.” Theory and Society 18(2): 213–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downing, Brian. 1992. The Military Revolution and Political Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dupuy, R. Ernest, and Dupuy, Trevor N.. 1993. The Harper Encyclopedia of Military History. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Ergang, Robert 1971. Emergence of the National State. New York: Van Nostrand Reinhold.Google Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 2017. “Otto Hintze, Stein Rokkan, and Charles Tilly’s Theory of European State-Building.” In Does War Make States?: Investigations of Charles Tilly’s Historical Sociology, eds. Kaspersen, Lars Bo and Strandbjerg, Jeppe, 5269. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fichtner, Paula. 1976. “Dynastic Marriage in Sixteenth-Century Habsburg Diplomacy and Statecraft: An Interdisciplinary Approach.” American Historical Review 81 (2): 243–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, Markus. 1992. “Feudal Europe, 800–1300: Communal Discourse and Conflictual Practices.” International Organization 46 (2): 427–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fouquet, Roger, and Broadberry, Stephen. 2015. “Seven Centuries of European Economic Growth and Decline.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 29 (4): 227–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fried, Johannes. 2015. The Middle Ages. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Friedrichs, Joerg. 2001. “The Meaning of New Medievalism.” European Journal of International Relations 7 (4): 475501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis. 2011. The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Gilchrist, John. 1969. The Church and Economic Activity in the Middle Ages. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Glete, Jan. 2002. War and the State in Early Modern Europe: Spain, the Dutch Republic and Sweden as Fiscal-Military States, 1500–1660. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goody, Jack. 1983. The Development of Family and Marriage in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorski, Philip, and Sharma, Vivek. 2017. “Beyond the Tilly Thesis: ‘Family Values’ and State Formation in Latin Christendom.” In Does War Make States?: Investigations of Charles Tilly’s Historical Sociology, eds. Kaspersen, Lars Bo and Strandbjerg, Jeppe, 98124. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2020. “The Religious and Medieval Origins of the European State.” Annual Review of Political Science 23: 1936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2023a. Sacred Foundations: The Religious and Medieval Roots of the European State. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2023b. “Replication Data for: Tilly Goes to Church: The Religious and Medieval Roots of European State Fragmentation.” Harvard Dataverse. Dataset. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/DWQLIB.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Rodney, and Kratochwil, Friedrich V.. 1993. “Medieval Tales: Neorealist ‘Science’ and the Abuse of History.” International Organization 47 (3): 479–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hay, Denys. 1995. Europe in the Fourteenth and Fifteenth Centuries. New York: Longman Publishing.Google Scholar
Held, David. 1995. Democracy and the Global Order: From the Modern State to Cosmopolitan Governance. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Helmholz, Richard. 1994. “Excommunication in Twelfth Century England.” Journal of Law and Religion 11 (1): 235–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helmholz, Richard. 2015. “Canon Law and Roman Law.” In Cambridge Companion to Roman Law, 396422. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herbst, Jeffrey. 2000. States and Power in Africa. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hintze, Otto. [1931] 1975. “The Preconditions of Representative Government in the Context of World History.” In The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, ed. Gilbert, Felix, 305–53. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hintze, Otto. [1906] 1975. “Military Organization and the Organization of the State.” In The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, ed. Gilbert, Felix, 180215. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Philip. 2015. Why Did Europe Conquer the World? Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Philip T., and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1997. “The Political Economy of Warfare and Taxation in Early Modern Europe: Historical Lessons for Economic Development.” In The Frontiers of Institutional Economics, eds. Drobak, John and Nye, Jon, 3155. St. Louis, MO: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Hui, Victoria Tin-bor. 2005. War and State Formation in Ancient China and Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyde, John Kenneth. 1973. Society and Politics in Medieval Italy: The Evolution of the Civil Life, 1000–1350. New York: St. Martin’s Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jedin, Hubert. 1993. The Medieval and Reformation Church. New York: Crossroad.Google Scholar
Joachimsen, Paul. 1978. “The Issue of Government: Conflict of Church and Empire.” In The Investiture Controversy, ed. Morrison, Karl, 1223. Huntington, NY: Krieger Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Jones, Eric. 1981. The European Miracle: Environments, Economies and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jordan, William C. 2001. Europe in the High Middle Ages. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Joseph, Lisa. 2015. “Dynastic Marriage in England, Castile and Aragon, 11th–16th Centuries.” PhD diss. University of Adelaide, Australia.Google Scholar
Kaminsky, Howard. 2000. “The Great Schism.” In The New Cambridge Medieval History, vol. 6. ed. Jones, Michael, 674–96. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiernan, Victor G. 1965. “State and Nations in Western Europe.” Past & Present 31: 2038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kokkonen, Andrej, and Sundell, Anders. 2014. “Delivering Stability—Primogeniture and Autocratic Survival in European Monarchies 1000–1800.” American Political Science Review 108 (2): 438–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kotecki, Radosław. 2018. “Lions and Lambs, Wolves and Pastors of the Flock: Portraying Military Activity of Bishops in Twelfth-Century Poland.” In Between Sword and Prayer: Warfare and Medieval Clergy in Cultural Perspective, eds. Kotecki, Radosław, Maciejewski, Jacek, and Ott, John, 303–40. Leiden, NL: Brill.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krasner, Stephen. 1993. “Westphalia and All That.” In Ideas and Foreign Policy, eds. Goldstein, Judith and Keohane, Robert O., 235–64. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Landes, David. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1988. Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Little, Richard, and Buzan, Barry. 2002. “International Systems in World History: Remaking the Study of International Relations.” In Historical Sociology of International Relations, eds. Hobdon, Stephen and Hobson, John, 200–22. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Malegam, Jehangir Yezdi. 2013. The Sleep of Behemoth: Disputing Peace and Violence in Medieval Europe, 1000/1200. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Mann, Michael. 1986. The Sources of Social Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mazzuca, Sebastian. 2021. Latecomer State Formation: Political Geography and Capacity Failure in Latin America. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McNeill, William. 1982. The Pursuit of Power. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitteraurer, Michael. 2010. Why Europe? The Medieval Origins of Its Special Path. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Møller, Jørgen 2015. “The Medieval Roots of Democracy.” Journal of Democracy 26 (3): 110–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Møller, Jørgen. 2017. “Medieval Origins of the Rule of Law: The Gregorian Reforms as Critical Juncture?Hague Journal on the Rule of Law 9 (2): 265–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Møller, Jørgen. 2018. “Medieval Roots of the Modern State: The Conditional Effects of Geopolitical Pressure on Early Modern State Building.” Social Science History 42 (2): 295316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Møller, Jørgen. 2019. “Bringing the Church Back In: Ecclesiastical Influences on the Rise of Europe.” Politics and Religion 12 (2): 213–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Møller, Jørgen, and Doucette, Jonathan Stavnskær. 2022. The Catholic Church and European State Formation, AD 1000–1500. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgenthau, Hans. 1985. Politics among Nations. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Morris, Colin. 1989. The Papal Monarchy: The Western Church from 1050 to 1250. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mundy, John. 2000. Europe in the High Middle Ages 1150–1300. Edinburgh, UK: Longman.Google Scholar
North, Douglass, and Weingast, Barry. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oakley, Francis. 2012. The Mortgage of the Past: Reshaping the Ancient Political Inheritance (1050–1300). New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ober, Josiah. 2015. The Rise and Fall of Classical Greece. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obertyński, Zdzisław, and Kumor, Bolesław. 1974. Historia Kościoła W Polsce. Poznań, PL: Pallottinum.Google Scholar
Osiander, Andreas. 2001. “Sovereignty, International Relations, and the Westphalian Myth.” International Organization 55 (2): 251–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oster, Emily. 2019. “Unobservable Selection and Coefficient Stability: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 37 (2): 187204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ozment, Steven. 1980. The Age of Reform. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Parker, Geoffrey. 1992. The Military Revolution; Military Innovation and the Rise of the West. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Philpott, Daniel. 2001. Revolutions in Sovereignty: How Ideas Shaped Modern International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Poggi, Gianfranco. 1990. The State: Its Nature, Development, and Prospects. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Reynolds, Susan. 1996. Fiefs and Vassals: The Medieval Evidence Reinterpreted. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rigaudiere, Albert. 1995. “The Theory and Practice of Government in the Western Europe in the Fourteenth Century.” In The New Cambridge Medieval History, vol. 6, ed. Reuter, Timothy, 1741. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Riley-Smith, Jonathan. 2005. Crusades: A History. New York: Continuum Books.Google Scholar
Ringer, Fritz. 2004. Max Weber: An Intellectual Biography. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Ian Stuart 1990. The Papacy 1073–1198. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rokkan, Stein. 1975. “Dimensions of State Formation and Nation Building: A Possible Paradigm for Research on Variations within Europe.” In The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed. Tilly, Charles, 562600. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rokkan, Stein. 1999. State Formation, Nation-Building, and Mass Politics in Europe: The Theory of Stein Rokkan. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent, and Wong, Roy Bin. 2011. Before and beyond Divergence. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Jared. 2017. Rulers, Religion, and Values: Why the West Got Rich and the Middle East Did Not. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1983. “Continuity and Transformation in the World Polity: Toward a Neorealist Synthesis.” International Organization 47 (1): 139–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saylor, Ryan, and Wheeler, Nicholas. 2017. “Paying for War and Building State: The Coalitional Politics of Debt Servicing and Tax institutions.” World Politics 69 (2): 366408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schatz, Klaus. 1996. Papal Primacy from Its Origins to the Present. Collegeville, MN: The Liturgical Press.Google Scholar
Scheidel, Walter. 2019. Escape from Rome. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schwartzberg, Melissa. 2014. Counting the Many: The Origins of Supermajority Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sharma, Vivek. 2015. “Kinship, Property, and Authority.” Politics & Society 43 (2): 151–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sharma, Vivek. 2017. “War, Conflict, and State Reconsidered.” In Does War Make States?: Investigations of Charles Tilly’s Historical Sociology, eds. Kaspersen, Lars Bo and Strandsbjerg, Jeppe, 181217. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sharp, Sheila. 2001. “The West Saxon Tradition of Dynastic Marriage with Special Reference to the Family of Edward the Elder.” In Edward the Elder, 899–824, eds. Higham, Nick and Hill, David, 8385. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Smith, Alistair L. 1964. Church and State in the Middle Ages. New York: Frank Cass.Google Scholar
Southern, Richard. 1970. Western Society and the Church in the Middle Ages. London: Harmondsworth.Google Scholar
Spruyt, Hendrik 1994. The Sovereign State and Its Competitors. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spruyt, Hendrik. 2017. “War and State Formation: Amending the Bellicist Theory of State Making.” In Does War Make States?: Investigations of Charles Tilly’s Historical Sociology, eds. Kaspersen, Lars Bo and Strandsbjerg, Jeppe, 7397. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2010. “When Distance Mattered: Geographic Scale and the Development of European Representative Assemblies.” American Political Science Review 104 (4): 625–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2016.“Representation and Consent: Why They Arose in Europe and Not Elsewhere.” Annual Review of Political Science 19: 145–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2020. The Decline and Rise of Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Stollberg-Rilinger, Barbara. 2018. The Holy Roman Empire. Translated by Yair Mintzker. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stone, Lawrence. 1994. An Imperial State at War: Britain from 1689 to 1815. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Strayer, Joseph. 1970. On the Medieval Origins of the Modern State. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sulovsky, Vedran. 2019. “The Concept of Sacrum Imperium in Historical Scholarship.” History Compass 252 (4): 119–31.Google Scholar
Teschke, Benno. 2003. The Myth of 1648: Class, Geopolitics, and the Making of Modern International Relations. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Teschke, Benno. 2017. “After the Tilly Thesis.” In Does War Make States? Investigations of Charles Tilly’s Historical Sociology, eds. Kaspersen, Lars Bo and Strandsbjerg, Jeppe, 2551. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thies, Cameron. 2005. “War, Rivalry and State Building in Latin America.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 451–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1975. The Formation of National States in Western Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1992. Coercion, Capital, and European States: Ad 990–1992. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles, and Blockmans, Willem P., eds. 1994. Cities and the Rise of States in Europe, AD 1000 to 1800. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Toch, Michael. 1999. “Welfs, Hohenstaufen, and Habsburgs.” In The New Cambridge Medieval History, vol. 5, ed. Abulafia, David, 375404. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuchman, Barbara. 1978. A Distant Mirror: The Calamitous 14th Century. New York: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Ullmann, Walter. [1955] 1965. The Growth of Papal Government in the Middle Ages. London: Methuen & Co.Google Scholar
Van Zanden, Jan Luiten. 2009. The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution: The European Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000–1800. Leiden, NL: Brill.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Zanden, Jan Luiten, Buringh, Eltjo, and Bosker, Maarten. 2012. “The Rise and Decline of European Parliaments, 1188–1789.” Economic History Review 65 (3): 835–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voigtländer, Nico, and Voth, Hans Joachim. 2013. “Gifts of Mars: Warfare and Europe’s Early Rise to Riches.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 (4): 165–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vries, Peer. 2013. Escaping Poverty. Vienna: V&R Unipress.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watson, Adam. 1992. The Evolution of International Society. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Watts, John. 2009. The Making of Polities: Europe, 1300–1500. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Max. 1958. The City. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Whalen, Brett. 2019. The Two Powers. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wickham, Christopher. 2015. Sleepwalking into a New World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wickham, Christopher. 2016. Medieval Europe. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Wilson, Peter H. 2016. Heart of Europe: A History of the Holy Roman Empire. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ronald. 2012. The Two Latin Cultures and the Foundation of Renaissance Humanism in Medieval Italy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wyrozumski, Jerzy. 2004. “Poland in the Eleventh and Twelfth Centuries.” In The New Cambridge Medieval History, vol. 4, eds. Luscombe, David and Riley-Smith, Jonathan, 277–89. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zacour, Norman. 1976. An Introduction to Medieval Institutions. New York: St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The Fragmentation of Europe, 1100–1900

Figure 1

Figure 2. The Emergence of Central State Institutions in Europe

Figure 2

Figure 3. Papal and Secular Conflict by Century

Figure 3

Figure 4. Explanations for the Fragmentation of Europe, 1000–1800Note: Bands indicate 95% confidence intervals around coefficient estimates.

Figure 4

Table 1. Papal Conflict Increases Territorial Fragmentation

Figure 5

Table 2. Papal Conflict Increases Territorial Fragmentation: Religious Confounders

Figure 6

Figure 5. Average Marginal Impact of Papal Conflict in the Holy Roman EmpireNote: Brackets indicate 95% confidence intervals.

Figure 7

Figure 6. Papal Conflict and Fragmentation Are Associated with the Rise of CommunesNote: Bands indicate 95% confidence intervals around coefficient estimates.

Figure 8

Table 3. Communes

Supplementary material: Link

Grzymala-Busse Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Grzymala-Busse supplementary material

Appendix
Download Grzymala-Busse supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 246.5 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.