Article contents
Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964*
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 01 August 2014
Extract
This paper develops several simple multivariate statistical models and applies them to explain fluctuations in the aggregate vote for the United States House of Representatives, over the period 1896-1964. The basic hypothesis underlying these models is that voters are rational in at least the limited sense that their decisions as to whether to vote for an incumbent administration depend on whether its performance has been “satisfactory” according to some simple standard. Because of data limitations, the analysis focuses on measures of economic performance, treating other aspects of an incumbent's performance, such as its handling of foreign affairs, as stochastic perturbations of the underlying relationship to be estimated. (Examination of residuals suggests this assumption is not unreasonable, at least during peacetime.) Possible effects of coattails from presidential races, of incumbency, and of secular trends in the underlying partisanship of the electorate are also taken into account. The models, estimated by maximum-likelihood methods, are found to be successful. Close to two-thirds of the variance in the vote series is accounted for, and the structural coefficients of the models are of the correct signs and of quite reasonable magnitudes. Economic growth, as measured by the changes in real per capita income, is the major economic variable; unemployment or inflation have little independent effect. Presidential coattails are also found to be of some importance.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © American Political Science Association 1971
Footnotes
The research described in this article was performed at the Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University, under grants from the National Science Foundation and the Ford Foundation.
References
1 Downs, Anthony, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper, 1957)Google Scholar.
2 Though see Key, V. O. Jr., The Responsible Electorate (Cambridge: Belknap Harvard, 1966)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
3 Kerr, W. A., “A Quantitative Study of Political Behavior, 1840–1940,” Journal of Social Psychology, 19 (1944), 273–281 Google Scholar.
4 Pearson, F. A. and Myers, W. I., “Prices and Presidents,” Farm Economics (Ithaca, N.Y.: New York State College of Agriculture, Cornell University), 163 (September 1948), 4210–4218, at p. 4210Google Scholar.
5 Bean, Louis H., Ballot Behavior (Washington, D.C.: American Council on Public Affairs, 1940), p. 63n Google Scholar.
6 Wilkinson, T. and Hart, H., “Prosperity and Political Victory,” Public Opinion Quarterly, 14 (1950), 331–335, at pp. 332, 334CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
7 Ibid., p. 334.
8 Tibbits, Clark, “Majority Votes and the Business Cycle,” American Journal of Sociology, 36 (1931), 596–606 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
9 Gosnell, H. F. and Coleman, W. G., “Political Trends in Industrial America: Pennsylvania as an Example,” Public Opinion Quarterly, 4 (1940), 473–484, at p. 475CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
10 Ogburn, W. F. and Coombs, L. C., “The Economic Factor in the Roosevelt Elections,” this Review, 34 (1940), 719–736, at pp. 719–720Google Scholar.
11 Ibid., p. 724.
12 Rees, Albert, Kaufman, H., Eldersveld, S. J., and Freidel, F., “The Effect of Economic Conditions on Congressional Elections, 1946–58,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 44 (1962), 458–465 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
13 Clark, Wesley C., Economic Aspects of a President's Popularity (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Pennsylvania, 1943)Google Scholar.
14 Durant, Henry, “Indirect Influences on Voting Behavior,” Polls, 1 (1965), 3–11 Google Scholar.
15 Campbell, Angus, Converse, Philip E., Miller, Warren E., and Stokes, Donald E., The American Voter (New York: Wiley, 1960), pp. 381–440 Google Scholar.
16 For discussion of the identification problem in a somewhat different context, see Koopmans, Tjalling C., “Identification Problems in Economic Model Construction,” in Hood, W. C. and Koopmans, T. C. (eds.), Studies in Econometric Method (New York: Wiley, 1953)Google Scholar.
17 Stokes, Donald E. and Miller, Warren E., “Party Government and the Saliency of Congress,” Public Opinion Quarterly, 26 (1962)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
18 Ibid..
19 Stokes, Donald E., “A Variance Components Model of Political Effects,” in Bernd, J. L. (ed.), Mathematical Applications in Political Science (Dallas, Tex.: Southern Methodist University Press, 1965)Google Scholar.
20 It would also be natural to add a third disturbance, say z t , to represent the net effect of the personal characteristics of individual congressional candidates. However, as we have already noted, congressional candidates are relatively anonymous to most of their constituents, and congressional campaign efforts are typically much less extensive than those of either state-wide or local races; furthermore, this “personal” effect would be averaged over some 400-odd individual races, so the final net effect would be small indeed. Hence we shall ignore it.
21 Rees et al, op. cit.
22 Durant, op. cit.
23 Cummings, Milton C. Jr., Congressmen and the Electorate (New York: The Free Press, 1966), pp. 135ffGoogle Scholar.
24 The other parameter estimates are close to those reported in Table 1, though the goodness of fit is some-what poorer.
25 Key, op. cit.
26 See Freeman, Harold, Introduction to Statistical Inference (Reading, Pa.: Addison-Wesley, 1963), pp. 69ffGoogle Scholar; and Mood, A. M. and Graybill, F. A., Introduction to the Theory of Statistics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1963), pp. 220ffGoogle Scholar.
27 See Freeman, op. cit., pp. 253c; and Mood and Graybill, op. cit. pp. 178ff.
28 See Freeman, op. cit., pp. 300ff; and Mood and Graybill, op. cit., pp. 297ff.
- 982
- Cited by
Comments
No Comments have been published for this article.