Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T05:18:34.667Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Money, Reputation, and Incumbency in U.S. House Elections, or Why Marginals Have Become More Expensive

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 August 2013

HENRY A. KIM*
Affiliation:
University of Arizona
BRAD L. LEVECK*
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
*
Henry A. Kim is Assistant Professor, University of Arizona ([email protected]).
Brad L. LeVeck is Postdoctoral Research Fellow, University of California, San Diego ([email protected]).

Abstract

Since 1972, campaign spending by House incumbents has skyrocketed, particularly in those districts with marginal support for the incumbent's party. At the same time, parties in the House have become much more cohesive in the way they vote, producing more precise and informative party brands. We argue that these two phenomena are fundamentally linked. As parties have developed more precise reputations, incumbents in these districts must spend much more to attract voters in “marginal” districts, who would be willing to vote for a candidate with the particular incumbent's legislative record, but not the average member of his party. Increasingly precise party reputations provide voters with stronger priors that incumbents are just like the rest of their party, and incumbents in marginal districts must spend more to overcome these beliefs. We demonstrate this using a simple formal model and test it empirically using campaign-spending data from 1972 to 2008.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Aldrich, John. 1995. Why Parties? Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Angrist, Joshua D., and Pischke, Jorn-Steffen. 2009. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist's Companion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David. 1989. “Service-Induced Campaign Contributions and the Electoral Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (1): 4572.Google Scholar
Bartels, Larry. 2002. “Beyond Running Tally: Partisan Bias in Political Perceptions.” Political Behavior 24 (2): 117–50.Google Scholar
Bartels, Larry, and Achen, Christopher. 2006. “It Feels Like We're Thinking: The Rationalizing Voter and Electoral Democracy.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
Bertrand, Marianne, Duflo, Esther, and Mullainathan, Sendhil. 2004. “How Much Should We Trust Differences-in-Differences Estimates?Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (1): 249–75.Google Scholar
Brady, David W., D'Onofrio, Robert, and Fiorina, Morris P.. 2000. “The Nationalization of Electoral Forces Revisited.” In Continuity and Change in House Elections, eds. Brady, David, Cogan, John, and Fiorina, Morris. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Brady, David W., Han, Hahrie, and Pope, Jeremy. 2007. “Primary Elections and Candidate Ideology: Out of Step with the Primary Electorate?Legislative Studies Quarterly 32 (1): 79106.Google Scholar
Brady, Henry, and Sniderman, Paul. 1985. “Attitude Attribution: A Group Basis for Political Reasoning.” American Political Science Review 79 (4): 1061–78.Google Scholar
Braumoeller, Bear F. 2004. “Hypothesis Testing and Multiplicative Interaction Terms.” International Organization 58 (04): 807–20.Google Scholar
Campbell, Angus, Converse, Philip, Miller, Warren, and Stokes, Donald. 1960. The American Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Brady, David, and Cogan, John F.. 2002. “Out of Step, Out of Office: Electoral Accountability and House Members’ Voting.” American Political Science Review 96 (1): 127–40.Google Scholar
Carroll, Royce A., and Kim, Henry A., 2010, “Party Government and the ‘Cohesive Power of Public Plunder.’American Journal of Political Science 54 (1): 3444.Google Scholar
Carroll, Royce, Lewis, Jeffrey B., Lo, James, Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 2009. “Measuring Bias and Uncertainty in DW-NOMINATE Ideal Point Estimates via the Parametric Bootstrap.” Political Analysis 17 (3): 261–75.Google Scholar
Claggett, William, Flanigan, William, and Zingale, Nancy. 1984. “Nationalization of the American Electorate.” American Political Science Review 78 (1): 7791.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, John J., and Manna, Paul F.. 2000. “Congressional Campaign Spending and the Quality of Democracy.” Journal of Politics 62 (3): 757–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornelissen, Thomas. 2008. “The Stata Command Feldsvreg to Fit a Linear Model with Two High-Dimensional Fixed Effects.” Stata Journal 8 (2): 170–89.Google Scholar
Cover, Thomas. 1977. “One Good Term Deserves Another: The Advantage of Incumbency in Congressional Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 21 (3): 523–41.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 1993. Legislative Leviathan. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 2007. Setting the Agenda: Party Government in the House. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert, and Wright, Gerald. 1993. “Voters, Candidates and Issues in Congressional Elections.” In Congress Reconsidered. 4th ed., eds. Dodd, Lawrence and Oppenheimer, Bruce. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert, and Wright, Gerald. 2008. “Voters, Candidates, and Issues in Congress.” In Congress Reconsidered. 9th ed., eds. Dodd, Lawrence and Oppenheimer, Bruce. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert, and Palfrey, Thomas. 2000. “Equilibria in Campaign Spending Games: Theory and Data.” American Political Science Review 94 (3): 595609.Google Scholar
Green, Donald P., and Gerber, Alan. 1999. “Misperceptions about Perceptual Bias.” Annual Review of Political Science 2: 189210.Google Scholar
Grynavski, Jeffrey D. 2006. “A Bayesian Learning Model with Applications to Party Identification.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 18 (3): 323–46.Google Scholar
Harden, Jeffrey J., and Carsey, Thomas M.. 2010. “Balancing Constituency Representation and Party Responsiveness in the US Senate: The Conditioning Effect of State Ideological Heterogeneity.” Public Choice 150 (1–2): 137–54.Google Scholar
Hetherington, Marc J. 2001. “Resurgent Mass Partisanship: The Role of Elite Polarization.” American Political Science Review 95 (3): 619–31.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 1978. “The Effects of Campaign Spending in Congressional ElectionsAmerican Political Science Review 72 (2): 469–91.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 1998. “The Declining Salience of U.S. House Candidates: 1958–1994,” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 2009. The Politics of Congressional Elections. 7th ed. New York: Pearson Longman.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C., and Kernell, Samuel. 1983. Strategy and Choice in Congressional Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, David R. 2003. “Position Taking and Position Avoidance in the U.S. Senate.” The Journal of Politics 65 (03): 851–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, David. 2010. “Partisan Polarization and Congressional Accountability in House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 54 (2): 323–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kawato, Sadafumi. 1987. “Nationalization and Partisan Realignment in Congressional Elections.” American Political Science Review 81 (4): 1235–50.Google Scholar
Liang, Kung-Yee, and Zeger, Scott L.. 1986. “Longitudinal Data Analysis Using Generalized Linear Models. Biometrika 73 (1): 1322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1974a. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1974b. “Congressional Elections: The Case of the Vanishing Marginals.” Polity 6 (3): 296317.Google Scholar
Munger, Michael C. 1988. “Allocation of Desirable Committee Assignments: Extended Queues Versus Committee Expansion.” American Journal of Political Science 32 (2): 317–44.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 2000. Congress: Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting in Congress. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Popkin, Samuel L. 1995. The Reasoning Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Rohde, David. 1991. Parties and Leaders in the Postreform House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1972, “The Strategy of Ambiguity: Uncertainty and Electoral Competition,” American Political Science Review 66 (2): 555–68.Google Scholar
Snyder, James M., and Ting, Michael M.. 2002. “An Informational Rationale for Political Parties.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (1): 90110.Google Scholar
Stokes, Donald, and Miller, Warren E.. 1962. “Party Government and the Saliency of Congress.” Public Opinion Quarterly 26 (4): 531–46.Google Scholar
Woon, Jonathan, and Pope, Jeremy C.. 2008. “Made in Congress: Testing the Electoral Implications of Party Ideological Brand Names.” Journal of Politics 70 (3): 823–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

KIM and LEVECK supplementary material

Appendix

Download KIM and LEVECK supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 108.4 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.