Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T12:03:38.644Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Legislators and Interest Groups: How Unorganized Interests Get Represented

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Arthur T. Denzau
Affiliation:
Washington University, St. Louis
Michael C. Munger
Affiliation:
Dartmouth College

Abstract

This paper derives a supply price for public policy using a constrained maximization model. In the model, three sets of agents each have preferences over outcomes: organized interest groups offer campaign contributions to improve their own wealth, voters offer votes to obtain outcomes closer to their most preferred outcomes, and legislators seek both campaign contributions and votes to obtain reelection. A given legislator's supply price for policy is shown to depend on the productivity of his effort, as determined by committee assignments, priority and ability, and by the preferences of his unorganized constituency in the home district. Two extreme assumptions about the effectiveness of campaign spending in eliciting votes are used to illustrate the comparative statics properties of the model. The prediction of the model is that interest groups will, in general, seek out legislators whose voters are indifferent to the policy the interest group seeks. Thus, voters who do have preferences over policy are in effect represented, even though they are not organized.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bailey, Stephen K. 1950. Congress Makes a Law: The Story Behind the Employment Act of 1946. New York: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bauer, Raymond A., Pool, Ithiel de Sola, and Dexter, Anthony. 1972. American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade, 2nd ed. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Benham, Lee. 1973. The Effect of Advertising on the Price of Eyeglasses. Journal of Law and Economics, 16:337–52.Google Scholar
Bentley, Arthur F. 1907. The Process of Government. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1982. The Rational Preference for Biased Information. Working Paper No. 75. Center for the Study of American Business. St. Louis: Washington University.Google Scholar
Comanor, William S., and Wilson, Thomas A.. 1979. Advertising and Competition: A Survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 17:453–76.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W., McCubbins, Mathew D., and Sullivan, Terry. 1983. Policy and Constituency: Reelection Incentives and the Choice of Policy Intervention. Working Paper No. 02, Working Papers on Institutional Design and Public Policy. Department of Government, University of Texas at Austin.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1961. Who Governs? New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T., and Parks, Robert P.. 1979. Deriving Public Sector Preferences. Journal of Public Economics, 11: 335–52.Google Scholar
Dexter, Lewis Anthony. 1956. Candidates Make the Issues and Give Them Meaning. Public Opinion Quarterly, 19:1627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dexter, Anthony. 1963. The Representative and His District. In Peabody, Robert and Polsby, Nelson, eds., Perspectives on the House of Representatives. Chicago: Rand McNally.Google Scholar
Dougan, William and Kenyon, Daphne. 1984. Pressure Groups and Public Expenditures: The Flypaper Effect Reconsidered. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Fenno, Richard F. Jr., 1973. Congressmen in Committees. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company.Google Scholar
Fenno, Richard F. Jr., 1978. Home Style: House Members in Their Districts. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1974. Representatives, Roll Calls, and Constituencies. Lexington: D.C.Heath and Company.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P., and Noll, Roger G.. 1979 Majority Rule Models and Legislative Elections. The Journal of Politics, 41: 10811104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayes, Michael T. 1981. Lobbyists and Legislators. A Theory of Political Markets. New Brunswick. Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
Kau, James B., and Rubin, Paul H.. 1982. Congressmen, Constituents and Contributors. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Latham, Earl. 1952. The Group Basis of Politics: A Study of Basing-Point Legislation. Ithaca, N.Y.Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Loewenberg, Gerhard, and Patterson, Samuel C.. 1979. Comparing Legislatures. Boston: Little, Brown and Company.Google Scholar
Lowi, Theodore J. 1964. American Business, Public Policy, Case Studies, and Political Theory World Politics, 16:677715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKuen, Michael B. 1981. Social Communication and the Mass Policy Media. In MacKuen, Michael B. and Coombs, Steven L., eds., More Than News: Two Studies of Media Power. Beverly Hills: Sage.Google Scholar
MacKuen, Michael B. 1983. The Concept of Public Opinion. In Turner, Charles F. and Martin, Elizabeth, eds., Surveys of Subjective Phenomena. National Research Council Report. New York: Sage.Google Scholar
Matthews, Donald R. 1960. U.S. Senators and Their World. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McPherson, Charles P. 1972. Tariff Structures and Political Exchange. Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Miller, Gary, and Moe, Terry. 1983. Bureaucrats, Legislators, and the Size of Government. American Political Science Review, 77:297322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munger, Michael C. 1985. A Ranking of the Direct Benefits Provided by House Committees: An Indirect Approach. Department of Economics, Washington University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Niskanen, William A. Jr., 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and Theory of Groups, 2nd ed. New York: Schocken.Google Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1982. Constituent Interest and Congressional Voting. University of Chicago. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Pincus, Jonathan J. 1975. Pressure Groups and the Pattern of Tariffs. Journal of Political Economy, 83:757–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salamon, Lester M. and Seigfried, John J.. 1977. Economic Power and Political Influence: The Impact of Industry Structure on Public Policy. American Political Science Review, 71:1026–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schattschneider, Elmer E. 1935. Politics, Pressures, and the Tariff: A Study of Free Enterprise in Pressure Politics as Shown in the 1929–1930 Revision of the Tariff. New York: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Schotter, Andrew, and Schwodiauer, Gerhard. 1980. Economics and Game Theory: A Survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 18:479527.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1978. The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle: Democratic Committee Assignments in the Modern House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1971. The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics, 2:319.Google Scholar
Truman, David B. 1951. The Governmental Process. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Truman, David B. 1959. The Congressional Party. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Wagner, Richard E. 1966. Pressure Groups and Political Entrepreneurs: A Review Article. Papers on Non-Market Decision Making, 1: 161–70.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Marshall, William J.. 1984. The Industrial Organization of Congress. School of Business, Washington University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.