Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T05:01:00.889Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Critique of “Democratic Administration” and Its Supporting Ideation*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Robert T. Golembiewski*
Affiliation:
University of Georgia

Abstract

This paper analyzes Vincent Ostrom's major work, The Intellectual Crisis in American Public Administration, which he offers as providing paradigmatic direction for public administration and political science. The analysis urges caution as to that theory's status, especially from five analytic perspectives. Basically, attention is directed at the methodology or mode of inquiry associated with Ostrom's grounding of his argument in public choice theory, with special attention to the role of values. The adequacy of major assumptions of Ostrom's argument as descriptions of reality also is evaluated. Moreover, the critical lack of content in several key concepts is established. In addition, the analysis shows how opposite and simultaneous courses of action are implied by the argument. Finally, attention is directed at how Ostrom's argument can lead to unexpected consequences, even some that are opposite those effects Ostrom intends.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

This paper is one reflection of a substantial history of exchanges of ideas and papers that the author has had with a colleague, Dr. Keith Baker. Other reflections appear in Baker's works: “Public Choice Theory: Some Important Assumptions and Public Policy Implications,” in Public Administration, ed. Robert T. Golembiewski, Frank Gibson, and Geoffrey Y. Cornog, 3rd ed. (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1976), pp. 42–60; and “The Search for a New Paradigm in Public Administration,” paper delivered at the Annual Meeting, Southern Political Science Association, New Orleans, La., November 1974. The author warmly acknowledges that interchange.

References

1 Ostrom's, Vincent The Intellectual Crisis in American Public Administration (University, Ala.: University of Alabama Press, 1973) is the central sourceGoogle Scholar.

2 Ibid., esp. pp. 28–29.

3 Ibid., esp. pp. 111–12.

4. For exceptions to the lack of critical attention, system of thought see De Gregori, Thomas R., “Caveat Emptor: A Critique of the Emerging Paradigm of Public Choice,” Administration and Society, 6 (08 1974), 205–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Baker, Keith, “Public Choice Theory: Some Important Assumptions and Public Policy Implications,” in Public Administration, ed. Warren, Robert T., Golembiewski, , Gibson, Frank, and Cornog, Geoffrey Y., 3rd ed. (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1976), esp. pp. 4260 Google Scholar.

5 Ostrom, Vincent, Tiebout, Charles M., and Warren, Robert, “The Organization of Government in Metropolitan Areas,” American Political Science Review, 55 (12 1961), 835 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon, The Calculus of Consent (Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press, 1962),esp. pp. 4348 Google Scholar.

7 Ostrom, esp. pp. 50–51.

8 Buchanan and Tullock, p. vii.

9 Ibid., p. 3.

10 De Gregori, p. 208.

11 Niskanen, William A. Jr., Bureaucracy and Representative Government (Chicago: Aldine-Atherton, 1971), esp. p. 218 Google Scholar.

12 Ostrom, p. 52.

13 Long, Norton, Journal of Politics, 36 (08 1974), 804 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Shepsle, Kenneth A., “Theories of Collective Choice,” in Political Science Annual, Vol. 5, ed. Cotter, Cornelius P. (Indianapolis, Ind.: Bobbs-Merrill, 1974), p. 4 Google Scholar.

15 For example, Niskanen, esp. p. 8.

16 De Gregori, esp. pp. 207 and 217–19; and Baker, pp. 42–60.

17 Merewitz, Leonard and Sosnick, Steven H., The Budget's New Clothes (Chicago: Markham, 1971), pp. 79, 80 Google Scholar.

18 Ibid., p. 79n.

19 Ibid., p. 79n.

20 Ibid., p. 80n.

21 Illustratively, the Kaldor-Hicks and Little criteria have been developed to loosen the conceptual limits of the Pareto criterion. See Hicks, J. R., “The Rehabilitation of Consumer's Surplus,” Review of Economic Studies, 8 (19401941), 108–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Ostrom, esp. pp. 60–64.

23 De Gregori, p. 220.

24 Ostrom, pp. 50–51.

25 Ibid., p. 52.

26 Weinstein, Arnold A., “Individual Preference Intransitivity,” Southern Economic Journal, 34 (01 1968), 335 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

For an example of the empirical literature consult Tversky, Amos, “Intransitivity of Preferences,” Psychological Review, 76, No. 1 (1969), 3148 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Tversky begins to specify the empirical conditions under which consistent and predictable intransitivities occur. Those conditions seem to be quite prevalent, which provides but little support for the ideation and argument underlying democratic administration.

27 Dahl, Robert A., A Preface to Democratic Theory (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956), esp. pp. 3450 Google Scholar.

28 Arrow, Kenneth J., Social Choice and Individual Values (New York: Wiley, 1951), pp. 51–59 and 7580 Google Scholar.

29 Dahl, p. 42n.

30 Shepsle, esp. pp. 31–42, provides ample doeumentation of this summary statement.

31 Buchanan and Tullock, p. 9.

32 This was the case, for example, in the famous 1930 studies of group atmospheres or climates. See especially Lippitt, Ronald, “Field Theory and Experiment in Social Psychology: Autocratic and Democratic Group Atmospheres,” American Journal of Sociology, 45 (07 1939), 2649 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33 Janis, Irving, Victims of Groupthink (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1972)Google Scholar, deals with a number of major political and military decisions which fit this characterization.

34 The classic experimental demonstration is that of Asch, Solomon E., “Effects of Group Pressure Upon the Modification and Distortion of Judgments,” in Groups, Leadership, and Men, ed. Guetzkow, Harold (Pittsburgh, Pa.: Carnegie Press, 1951), pp. 177–90Google Scholar.

35 De Gregori, p. 210.

36 Ibid., p. 209.

37 Buchanan and Tullock, pp. 3, 17.

38 Bish, Robert L. and Ostrom, Vincent, Understano ding Urban Government (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 1973), p. 18 Google Scholar.

39 De Gregori, p. 209.

40 Buchanan and Tullock, p. 18.

41 Sen, Amartya K., Collective Choice and Social Welfare (San Francisco: Holden Day, 1971), p. 6 Google Scholar.

42 Buchanan and Tullock, p. 9.

43 Ostrom, p. 62.

44 Ostrom, Tiebout, and Warren, pp. 835–37.

45 Ostrom, pp. 35, 48.

46 Briloff, Abraham J., Unaccountable Accounting (New York: Harper, 1972)Google Scholar.

47 Consult Burns, William J. Jr., and De Coster, Don T., eds., Accounting and Its Behavioral Implications (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1969)Google Scholar; and Burns, Thomas, ed., Behavioral Experiments in Accounting (Columbus, Ohio: College of Administrative Sciences, Ohio State University, 1972)Google Scholar.

48 Gross, Bertram M., The Managing of Organizations, Vol. 2 (London: Free Press of Glencoe, 1964), esp. pp. 467501 Google Scholar; and Dierkes, Meinoff and Bauer, Raymond A., eds., Corporate Social Accounting (New York: Praeger, 1973)Google Scholar.

49 Ostrom, esp. pp. 49–50.

50 Merewitz and Sosnick, p. 63; emphasis added.

51 Coker, Francis W., “Dogmas of Administrative Reform,” American Political Science Review, 16 (08 1922), 399411 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hyneman, Charles S., “Administrative Reorganization: An Adventure into Science and Theology,” Journal of Politics, 1 (02 1939), 6274 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Latham, Earl H., “Hierarchy and Hieratics,” Employment Forum, 2 (04 1947), 16 Google Scholar; and Simon, Herbert A., “Proverbs of Administration,” Public Administration Review, 6 (Winter 1946), 5367 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

52 Golembiewski, Robert T., Men, Management, and Morality (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1965)Google Scholar; Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., Strategy and Structure (Cambridge, Mass.: The M.I.T. Press, 1962)Google Scholar; and Corey, E. Raymond and Starr, Steven H., Organization Strategy: A Marketing Approach (Boston, Mass.: Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1971)Google Scholar.

53 Baker, pp. 51–52.

54 Ostrom, p. 112.

55 Friedrich, Carl J., Man and His Government (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1963), p. 667 Google Scholar.

56 Ostrom, esp. pp. 75–81.

57 Hart, David K., “Theories of Government Related to Decentralization and Citizen Participation,” Public Administration Review, 32 (10 1972), 606 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

58 Fesler, James W., “Approaches to the Understanding of Decentralization,” Journal of Politics, 27 (08 1965), 549 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a balanced view deriving from extensive empirical research by one of Fesler's students, see Yates, Douglas, Neighborhood Democracy (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1973)Google Scholar.

59 Ibid., p. 549.

60 Kaufman, Herbert, The Limits of Organizational Change (University, Ala.: University of Alabama Press, 1971), pp. 101 ffGoogle Scholar.

61 Fesier, esp. pp. 539–46.

62 Graham, George, Morality in American Politics (New York: Random House, 1952), esp. pp. 4253 Google Scholar.

63 Tannenbaum, Arnold S. et al., Hierarchy in Organizations (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1974)Google Scholar.

64 Ostrom, p. 118; emphasis in original.

65 For example, Pachon, Harry P. and Lovrich, Nicholas P., “The Consolidation of Urban Public Services,” Public Administration Review, 37 (01 1977), 3847 CrossRefGoogle Scholar, provide evidence which contradicts Ostrom's position with respect to large vs. small police systems. Such studies reinforce the notion that any relevant comparisons between large vs. small public agencies are likely to be very complicated, contingent on intervening variables, and so on. This certainly has been the case with industrial and commercial organizations. For example, substantial evidence implies that total organization size is likely to be less salient than the size of component “managerial units,” a managerial unit being defined as that portion of an agency monitored by some authoritative agent who can make reasonable decisions about some total “flow of work.” For the conceptual argument and a review of substantial evidence, see Golembiewski, , Men, Management, and Morality, pp. 113–15, 133–38, 144–47, 234–43, 268–71, and 279–83Google Scholar.

Size of managerial unit is not dependent on size of organization, but will vary with the degree of decentralized delegation in an organization. A decentralized organization, however, could be huge in total size.

66 Bish and Ostrom, p. 38. See also pp. 36–37.

67 Reidel, James A., “Citizen Participation: Myths and Reality,” Public Administration Review, 32 (05 1972), 211–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

68 Coleman, James S. et al., Equality of Educational Opportunity (Washington, D.C.: National Center for Educational Statistics, 1966)Google Scholar.

69 Bish and Ostrom, p. 38.

70 Ibid., pp. 41–46.

71 Ostrom, Elinor et al., Community Organization and the Provision of Police Services (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1973)Google Scholar; and Ostrom, Elinor and Whitaker, Gordon, “Black Citizens and the Police” (paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, 1971)Google Scholar.

72 IsHak, S. T., “Consumers' Perceptions of Police Performance: Consolidation vs. Deconcentration” (Ph.D. Dissertation, Indiana University, 1972)Google Scholar.

73 Ahlbrandt, Roger S. Jr., Municipal Fire Protection Services (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1973)Google Scholar.

74 Bish and Ostrom, p. 47.

75 Ibid., pp. 40–41.

76 Ibid., p. 36.

77 It is also correct that larger urban schools do pose more challenging targets for change, in part because of the organizing concepts prevalent in them, as Ostrom argues. See Schmuck, Richard A. and Miles, Matthew B., eds., Organization Development in Schools (Palo Alto, Calif.: National Press Books, 1971), esp. pp. 236–37Google Scholar.

78 Ostrom, p. 59.

79 Ibid., p. 119; emphasis added.

80 Ibid., p. 121.

81 Ibid., p. 56.

82 Shepsle, p. 30.

83 van Dalen, Hendrik, “Some Theoretical Perspectives on Government's Role in Consumer Protection” (paper prepared for the Southwestern Public Administration Meeting, Phoenix, Arizona, 11 12, 1975), p. 12 Google Scholar.

84 Gawthrop, Louis C., The Administration Process and Democratic Theory (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1970), pp. 439, 439–40Google Scholar.

85 Ostrom, pp. 56–58.

86 Baker, p. 59.

87 De Gregori, p. 210.

88 Baker, p. 54.

89 McKean, Roland, “Product Liability,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84 (11 1970), 623 Google Scholar. Most public choice theorists incline to somewhat more government intervention, as in providing information about product safety. See Oi, W. Y., “The Economics of Product Safety,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5 (Spring 1973), 26 Google Scholar.

90 Baker, p. 55.

91 Kaufman, Herbert, “Administrative Decentralization and Political Power,” Public Administration Review, 29 (01 1969), 3 and 4 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

92 Waldo, Dwight, ed., Public Administration in a Time of Turbulence (Scranton, Pa.: Chandler, 1971), pp. 259–60Google Scholar.

93 Ostrom, p. 125.

Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.