Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-29T10:22:52.887Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses of Political Choice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 September 2013

George A. Quattrone
Affiliation:
Stanford University
Amos Tversky
Affiliation:
Stanford University

Abstract

We contrast the rational theory of choice in the form of expected utility theory with descriptive psychological analysis in the form of prospect theory, using problems involving the choice between political candidates and public referendum issues. The results showed that the assumptions underlying the classical theory of risky choice are systematically violated in the manner predicted by prospect theory. In particular, our respondents exhibited risk aversion in the domain of gains, risk seeking in the domain of losses, and a greater sensitivity to losses than to gains. This is consistent with the advantage of the incumbent under normal conditions and the potential advantage of the challenger in bad times. The results further show how a shift in the reference point could lead to reversals of preferences in the evaluation of political and economic options, contrary to the assumption of invariance. Finally, we contrast the normative and descriptive analyses of uncertainty in choice and address the rationality of voting.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1988 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abelson, Robert, and Levi, Ariel. 1985. Decision Making and Decision Theory. In The Handbook of Social Psychology, 3d ed., ed. Lindzey, Gardner and Aronson, Elliot. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.Google Scholar
Adorno, Theodor, Frenkel-Brunswik, Else, Levinson, Daniel, and Sanford, R. Nevitt. 1950. The Authoritarian Personality. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Allais, Maurice. 1953. Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulates et axiomes de l'école americaine. Econometrica 21:503–46.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1982. Risk Perception in Psychology and Economics. Economic Inquiry 20: 19.Google Scholar
Bazerman, Max H. 1983. Negotiator Judgment. American Behavioral Scientist 27:211–28.Google Scholar
Bernoulli, Daniel. 1954. Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk. Econometrica 22: 2336.Google Scholar
Converse, Philip. 1975. Public Opinion and Voting Behavior. In Handbook of Political Science, vol. 4, ed. Greenstein, Fred and Polsby, Nelson. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Dawes, Robyn. 1988. Rational Choice in an Uncertain World. New York: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Slovic, Paul, and Tversky, Amos. 1982. Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1979. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica 47:263–91.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1984. Choices, Values, and Frames. American Psychologist 39:341–50.Google Scholar
Kiewiet, D. Roderick. 1982. The Rationality of Candidates Who Challenge Incumbents in Congressional Elections. Social Science Working Paper no. 436, California Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. 1971. Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964. American Political Science Review 65:131–43.Google Scholar
Lebow, Richard N., and Stein, Janice G.. 1987. Beyond Deterrence. Journal of Social Issues 43: 571.Google Scholar
Meehl, Paul. 1977. The Selfish Voter Paradox and the Thrown-away Vote Argument. American Political Science Review 71:1130.Google Scholar
Quattrone, George A., and Tversky, Amos. 1984. Causal versus Diagnostic Contingencies: On Self-Deception and on the Voter's Illusion. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 46: 237–48.Google Scholar
Quattrone, George A., and Warren, Diann. 1985. The Ratio-Difference Principle and the Perception of Group Differences. Stanford University. Typescript.Google Scholar
Raiffa, Howard. 1968. Decision Analysis: Introductory Lectures on Choices under Uncertainty. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Riker, William, and Ordeshook, Peter. 1968. A Theory of the Calculus of Voting. American Political Science Review 10:2542.Google Scholar
Ross, Lee. 1986. Conflict Notes. Stanford University. Typescript.Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard. 1954. The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth. 1972. The Strategy of Ambiguity: Uncertainty and Electoral Competition. American Political Science Review 66:555–68.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert. 1955. A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69:99118.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert. 1978. Rationality As Process and As Product of Thought. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 68:116.Google Scholar
Tursky, Bernard, Lodge, Milton, Foley, Mary Ann, Reeder, Richard, and Foley, Hugh. 1976. Evaluation of the Cognitive Component of Political Issues by Use of Classical Conditioning. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 34:865–73.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos, and Kahneman, Daniel. 1986. Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions. The Journal of Business 59:251–78.Google Scholar
Von Neumann, John, and Morgenstern, Oskar. 1947. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, 2d ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.