Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-06T11:02:58.015Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternative Theories

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Donald Wittman*
Affiliation:
University of California, Santa Cruz

Abstract

A formal model of electoral behavior is developed under the assumption that candidates have policy preferences as well as an interest in winning per se. This model is shown to have an equilibrium in a k-issue space when there are two candidates. The implications of this model are compared to the implications of the Downsian-type model where candidates are interested only in winning. Testable propositions are derived via the use of comparative statics. The results of recent studies are shown to coincide with the synthesis model but not the pure Downsian model.

The theoretical model bridges the gap between formal theory and empirical research and unifies a variety of seemingly unrelated studies.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1983

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramowitz, A. 1980. A comparison of voting for U.S. senator and representatives in 1978. American Political Science Review 74:633–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Achen, C. 1978. Measuring representation. American Journal of Political Science 72:3.Google Scholar
Aldrich, J. 1980. A dynamic model of presidential nomination campaign. American Political Science Review 74:651–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aldrich, J. and McKelvey, R. 1977. A method of scaling with applications to the 1968 and 1972 presidential elections. American Political Science Review 71: 111–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amacher, R., and Boyes, W. 1978. Cycles in senatorial voting behavior: implications for the optimal frequency of elections. Public Choice 33:178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aranson, P., and Ordeshook, P. 1972. Spatial strategies for sequential election. In Probability models of collective decision making, eds. Niemi, R. and Weisberg, H.. Columbus, Ohio: Merrill.Google Scholar
Beck, N. 1982. Parties, administrations, and American macroeconomic outcomes. American Political Science Review 76:8393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bental, B., and Ben Zion, U. 1975. Political contributions and policy—some extensions. Public Choice 30:113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brams, S. 1978. The presidential elections game. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1971a. Internal processes governing party positions in elections. Public Choice 11:3560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1972b. The positions of political parties in elections. In Probability models of collective decision making, eds. Niemi, R. and Weisberg, H.. Columbus, Ohio: Merrill.Google Scholar
Debreu, G. 1952. Existence of a social equilibrium. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.Google Scholar
Diewert, W. E.; Avriel, M.; and Zang, I. 1981. Nine kinds of quasiconcavity and concavity. Journal of Economic Theory 25:397420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, A. 1957. An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Elling, R. 1976. Patterned temporal ideological instability in the United States senate: of time and electoral responsiveness. Unpublished.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. 1977. On the decline of competition in congressional elections. American Political Science Review 71:166–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, M. 1977. The case of the vanishing marginals: the bureaucracy did it. American Political Science Review 71:177–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, M. 1974. Representatives, roll calls, and constituencies. Lexington, Mass.: D.C. Heath.Google Scholar
Fiorina, M. 1973. Electoral margins, constituency influence and policy moderation: a critical assessment. American Politics 4:479–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. S., and Schneider, F. 1978. An empirical study of politico-economic interaction in the U.S. Review of Economics and Statistics 60:174–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginsburg, B. 1976. Elections and public policy. American Political Science Review 70:4149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, S. 1975. Participation, political structure and consequence. American Political Science Review 69: 1181–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, D. 1979. Inflation, unemployment and left-wing political parties: a reanalysis. American Political Science Review 73:185–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, D. 1977. Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review 71: 1767–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. J. 1977. Equilibrium in spatial voting. Journal of Economic Theory 16:208–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. J. and Ordeshook, P. 1970. Plurality maximization vs. vote maximization: a spatial analysis with variable participation. American Political Science Review 64:772–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. J.; Ledyard, J. D.; and Ordeshook, P. 1972. Nonvoting and the existence of equilibrium under majority rule. Journal of Economic Theory 4: 144–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotelling, H. 1929. Stability in competition. The Economic Journal 39:4157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keech, W. 1980. Elections and macroeconomic policy optimization. American Journal of Political Science 24:345–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kostroski, W. 1973. Party and incumbency in post-war senate elections: trends, patterns and models. American Political Science Review 67:1213–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kramer, G. 1977. A dynamical model of political equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory 16: 310–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuklinski, J. 1977. District competitiveness and legislative roll-call behavior: a reassessment of the marginality hypothesis. American Journal of Political Science 21:627–738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuklinski, J. 1978. Representativeness and elections: a policy analysis. American Political Science Review 72: 165–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuklinski, J. and Elling, R. C. 1977. Representational role constituency opinion and legislative roll-call behavior. American Journal of Political Science 21: 135–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lau, L., and Frey, B. 1971. Ideology, public approval and government behavior. Public Choice 10:2040.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mann, T., and Wolfinger, R. 1980. Candidates and parties in congressional elections. American Political Science Review 74:617–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, D. 1971. Congress, the electoral connection. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, D. 1974. Congressional elections: the case of the vanishing marginals. Polity 6:295317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, B. 1978. Choice and echoes in presidential elections: rational man in electoral democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Payne, J. 1979. Inflation, unemployment, and left-wing political parties: a reanalysis. American Political Science Review 73:181–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petry, F. 1980. Candidates with or without policy preferences. Paper presented at the Public Choice Society meeting, Florence, Italy.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. 1976. A theory of party competition. London: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Rothenberg, J. 1965. A model of economic and political decision making. In The public economy of urban communities, ed. J. Margolis. New York: AMS Press.Google Scholar
Schlesinger, J. 1975. The primary goals of political parties: a clarification of positive theory. American Political Science Review 69:840–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. 1950. Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers.Google Scholar
Smithies, A. 1941. Optimum location in spatial competition. The Journal of Political Economy 49: 423–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, J., and Uslaner, E. 1978. Congressional behavior and electoral marginality. American Journal of Political Science 22:536–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tufte, E. 1978. Political control of the economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tufte, E. 1973. The relationship between seats and votes in two-party systems. American Political Science Review 67:540–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, D. A. 1977. Candidates with policy preferences: a dynamic model. Journal of Economic Theory 14:180–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, D. A. 1973. Parties as utility maximizers. American Political Science Review 67:490–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.