Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:05:47.123Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Cabinet Terminations and Critical Events

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 September 2000

Daniel Diermeier
Affiliation:
Northwestern University
Randolph T. Stevenson
Affiliation:
Rice University

Abstract

We present an empirical assessment of Lupia and Strøm's noncooperative bargaining model of cabinet terminations. We construct a stochastic version of the model and derive several testable implications. As the next mandatory election approaches: (1) the probability of an early election increases; (2) a cabinet's risks of being replaced without an intermediate election may be flat or even decrease; and (3) the overall chance that a cabinet falls (for whatever reason) increases. Using nonparametric duration analysis on a 15-country data set, we find qualified support for the Lupia and Strøm model. We conclude that the strategic approach is more promising than the nonstrategic alternative, but a more fully dynamic strategic model will be required to account for the dynamics of cabinet stability.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Alt, James, and King, Gary. 1994. “Transfers of Governmental Power: The Meaning of Time Dependence.” Comparative Political Studies 27 (2): 190210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browne, Eric C., Fendreis, John P., and Gleiber, Dennis W.. 1984. “An ‘Events’ Approach to the Problem of Cabinet Stability.” Comparative Political Studies 17 (1): 167–97.10.1177/0010414084017002003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browne, Eric C., Frendreis, John P., and Gleiber, Dennis W.. 1986. “The Process of Cabinet Dissolution: An Exponential Model of Duration and Stability in Western Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 30 (3): 628–50.10.2307/2111093CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalbfleisch, J. D., and Prentice, R. L.. 1980. The Statistical Analysis of Failure Time Data. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Alt, James, Burns, Nancy, and Laver, Michael. 1990. “A Unified Model of Cabinet Dissolution in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (3): 846–71.10.2307/2111401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lupia, Arthur, and Strøm, Kaare. 1995. “Coalition Termination and the Strategic Timing of Parliamentary Elections.” American Political Science Review 89 (September): 648–69.10.2307/2082980CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, Bruce D. 1990. “Unemployment Insurance and Unemployment Spells.” Econometrica 58 (4): 757–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, Kaare. 1985. “Party Goals and Government Performance in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science Review 79 (September): 738–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warwick, Paul. 1992. “Rising Hazards: An Underlying Dynamic of Parliamentary Government.” American Journal of Political Science 36 (4): 857–76.10.2307/2111351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warwick, Paul. 1994. Government Survival in Parliamentary Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Warwick, Paul, and Easton, Stephen T.. 1992. “The Cabinet Stability Controversy: New Perspectives on a Classic Problem.” American Journal of Political Science 36 (1): 122–46.10.2307/2111427CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.