Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T21:34:29.175Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Autocrat's Credibility Problem and Foundations of the Constitutional State

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 February 2008

ROGER B. MYERSON*
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
*
Roger B. Myerson is Professor, Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 1126 East 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 ([email protected]).

Abstract

A political leader's temptation to deny costly debts to past supporters is a central moral-hazard problem in politics. This paper develops a game-theoretic model to probe the consequences of this moral-hazard problem for leaders who compete to establish political regimes. In contests for power, absolute leaders who are not subject to third-party judgments can credibly recruit only limited support. A leader can do better by organizing supporters into a court which could cause his downfall. In global negotiation-proof equilibria, leaders cannot recruit any supporters without such constitutional checks. Egalitarian norms make recruiting costlier in oligarchies, which become weaker than monarchies. The ruler's power and limitations on entry of new leaders are derived from focal-point effects in games with multiple equilibria. The relationships of trust between leaders and their supporters are personal constitutions which underlie all other political constitutions.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Basu, Kaushik. 2000. Prelude to Political Economy. Oxford, UK: Oxford U Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baye, Michael R., Kovenock, Dan, and de Vries, Casper G.. 1994. “The solutions to the Tullock rent-seeking game when R > 2: mixed-strategy equilibria and mean dissipation rates.Public Choice 81 (December): 363–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary, and Stigler, George. 1974. “Law enforcement, malfeasance, and compensation of enforcers.J. Legal Studies 3 (January): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bol, Peter. 1998. “Government, society, and state: on the political visions of Ssu-ma Kuang and Wang An-shih.” In Ordering the World: Approaches to State and Society in Sung Dynasty China, ed. Hymes, R. and Schirokauer, C.. Berkeley, CA: U. California Press, 128–92.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Smith, Alastair, Siverson, Randolph M., and Morrow, James D.. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2005. “The killing game: reputation and knowledge in the politics of succession.” CEPR discussion paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2006. “Dictators and their viziers: endogenizing the loyalty-competence trade-off.” CEPR discussion paper.Google Scholar
Finer, Samuel E. 1997. The History of Government from the Earliest Times. Oxford, UK: Oxford U Press.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1989. “Why a Constitution.” In The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism, ed. Grofman, B. and Wittman, D.. New York: Agathon Press, 100–20.Google Scholar
Hume, David. 1748. “Of the Original Contract.” Reprinted in Political Essays, ed. Haakonssen, K.. Cambridge U. Press (1994), 186201.Google Scholar
Jouvenel, Bertrand de. 1948. On Power, trans. Huntington, J. F.. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger. 2004. “Justice, institutions, and multiple equilibria.Chicago Journal of International Law 5 (Summer): 91107.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger. 2006. “Federalism and incentives for success of democracy.Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1 (January): 323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, Roger. 2007. “Leadership, trust, and power.” University of Chicago paper.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1993. “Institutions and credible commitment.Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149 (March): 1123.Google Scholar
Ray, Debraj, and Ghosh, Parikshit. 1996. “Cooperation in community interaction without information flows.Review of Economic Studies 63 (July): 491519.Google Scholar
Root, Hilton. 1989. “Tying the king's hands.Rationality and Society 1 (October): 240–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth. 1991. “Discretion, institutions, and the problem of government commitment.” In Social Theory for a Changing Society, ed. Bordieu, P. and Coleman, J.. New York: Russell Sage, 245–63.Google Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios. 1990. “Contest success functions.Economic Theory 7 (June): 283–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svolik, Milan. 2006. “A theory of government dynamics in authoritarian regimes.” University of Illinois working paper.Google Scholar
Tacitus, Cornelius. 1970. “The Germania.” In The Agricola and the Germania, Trans. Mattingly, H., London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Warren, W. L. 1973. Henry II. Berkeley, CA: U. California Press.Google Scholar
Xenophon, . 2001. The Education of Cyrus, Trans. Ambler, Wayne, Ithaca, NY: Cornell U Press.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.