Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-qxsvm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-12T09:48:47.474Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An Interorganizational Analysis of Power, Conflict, and Settlements in Public Sector Collective Bargaining

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

James L. Perry
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
Charles H. Levine
Affiliation:
Syracuse University

Abstract

Despite increased interest in public sector collective bargaining, a survey of recent attempts to build theory about the dynamics and outcomes of union-management negotiations in public organizations reveals that little progress has been made. One approach that appears fruitful is interorganizational analysis. In an interorganizational context, organizations interact with other autonomous organizations to make joint decisions that have implications for both parties and for the larger system. This study focuses on five interorganizational variables that are useful for understanding the collective bargaining process in the public sector: (1) goal divergence; (2) stability of the relationship; (3) organizational dependence; (4) conflictual behavior; (5) contractual change.

From these theoretical concepts, five propositions are derived which serve as the basis for the research hypotheses. The hypotheses were tested on a sample of 60 cases drawn from a population of 535 collective bargaining negotiations in New York City from 1968 through 1972. The test of the research hypotheses resulted in these conclusions: (1) a substantial amount of the conflictual behavior in public sector collective bargaining is explained by goal divergence, stability of the relationship, and asymmetry of relative dependence favoring one of the organizations; and (2) contractual change is explained by goal divergence, conflictual behavior, and asymmetry of relative dependence favoring one of the organizations.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1976

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 One observer notes that in 1955 “the subject of labor relations in public employment could not have meant less to more people, both in and out of government.” See Klaus, Ida, “The Emerging Relationship,” Collective Bargaining in the Public Service, ed. Kruger, D. H. and Schmidt, Charles F. Jr. (New York: Random House, 1969), p. 11Google Scholar. Within 15 years, 2.3 million government employees held union membership and an additional 1.7 million government employees were members of associations, often functioning indistinguishably from unions. Municipal employees are represented for bargaining purposes by unions or associations in more than 1,300 communities. For statistics on the extent of public employee unionization and strike activities, see Tax Foundation, New York, Union and Government Employment (New York: Tax Foundation, May 1972), Tables 1 and 2, pp. 89Google Scholar, and Table 10, p. 29, and Nelson, Richard H. and Doster, James L., “City Employee Representation and Bargaining Policies,” Monthly Labor Review, 95 (November, 1972), 4350Google Scholar. For a comparison of union and association behavior in the field of public education, consult Muir, J. Douglas, “The Strike as a Professional Sanction: The Changing Attitude of the National Education Association,” Labor Law Journal, 19 (October, 1968), 615627Google Scholar.

2 Scholars have adopted a number of approaches in their efforts to describe and explain conflict and outcomes in public sector collective bargaining. Liston, for example, attempts to explain the causes of public employee strikes merely by asserting that government workers in the lower classifications want higher salaries. See Liston, Robert A., The Limits of Defiance: Strikes, Rights and Government (New York: Franklin Watts, 1971)Google Scholar. Wellington, and Winter, , in The Unions and the Cities (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1971)Google Scholar, Chapter 1, employ a conceptual framework which assumes “a municipality with an elected city council and an elected mayor who bargains with unions representing the employees of the city.” The conceptual framework is for the most part undefined and unaccompanied by indicators or constructs for its operationalization. Drotning, Lipsky, and Foster take a broad positivist approach to public sector collective bargaining. The outcome of interest to Drotning et al. is the mode of conflict resolution — mediation, fact-finding or conciliation. Although the authors fail to operationalize their approach, a more fundamental problem is the absence of any formal explication of the theoretical relationships underlying the variables. See Drotning, John, Lipsky, David, and Foster, Howard, “The Analysis of Impasse Procedures in Public Sector Negotiations,” Management of Personnel Quarterly, 9 (Summer, 1971), 2130Google Scholar. For one of the more promising recent attempts to explain conflict see Kochan, Thomas A., “A Theory of Multilateral Collective Bargaining in City Governments,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 27 (July, 1974), 525542CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Cyert, Richard M. and March, James G., A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1963), p. 27Google Scholar.

4 Cyert, and March, , A Behavioral Theory of the Firm, p. 27Google Scholar.

5 Warren, Roland L., “The Concerting of Decisions as a Variable in Organizational Interaction,” Interorganizational Decision Making, ed. Tuite, Matthew, Chisolm, Roger, and Radnor, Michael (Chicago: Aldine, 1972), p. 21Google Scholar.

6 Equilibrium theory is presented and discussed in Barnard, Chester I., The Functions of the Executive (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1938)Google Scholar, and March, James G. and Simon, Herbert A., Organizations (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1958)Google Scholar.

7 Thompson, James D., Organizations in Action (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967), p. 106Google Scholar.

8 March, and Simon, , Organizations, p. 83Google Scholar.

9 Thompson, , Organizations in Action, p. 106Google Scholar.

10 Ibid., p. 109.

11 Ibid., p. 106.

12 Ibid., p. 107.

13 Ibid., p. 110.

14 See March, and Simon, , Organizations, p. 91Google Scholar.

15 Olson, Mancur Jr., The Logic of Collective Action (New York: Schocken Books, 1968), p. 79Google Scholar.

16 Although March and Simon indicate the trade union occupies an ambiguous position, they do classify it as an extraorganizational group. March, and Simon, , Organizations, p. 72Google Scholar.

17 Coleman, James S., “Foundations for a Theory of Collective Decisions,” American Journal of Sociology, 71 (May, 1966), 615627CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed, at 616.

18 Thompson, , Organizations in Action, p. 128Google Scholar.

19 Levine, Sol and White, Paul E., “Exchange as a Conceptual Framework for the Study of Interorganizational Relationships,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 5 (March, 1961), 583601CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Thompson, , Organizations in Action, p. 26Google Scholar.

20 Thompson, , Organizations in Action, p. 128Google Scholar.

21 Cyert, and March, , A Behavioral Theory of the Firm, p. 115Google Scholar.

22 Pugh, D. S., Hickson, D. J., Hinings, C. R., and Turner, C., “The Context of Organization Structures,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 14 (March, 1969), 91114CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

23 William R., Dill, “Environment as an Influence on Managerial Autonomy,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 2 (March, 1958), 409443Google Scholar, at 410. “Organization set” is a term analogous to “task environment” employed by Evan, William M. in “The Organization-Set: Toward a Theory of Interorganizational Relations,” Approaches to Organizational Design, ed. Thompson, James D. (Pittsburgh, Pa.: The University of Pittsburgh Press, 1966), pp. 173191Google Scholar.

24 Walton, Richard E. and McKersie, Robert B., A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1965), chapter 6Google Scholar.

25 Walton, Richard E., “Theory of Conflict in Lateral Organizational Relations,” ed. Lawrence, J. R., Operational Research in the Social Sciences (London: Tavistock Publications, 1966), pp. 409426Google Scholar.

26 Walton, “Theory of Conflict in Lateral Organizational Relations”; see also Walton and McKersie, A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations.

27 Pondy, Louis R., “Organizational Conflict: Concepts and Models,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 12 (September, 1967), 296–320, at 312CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 See Coser, Lewis A., The Functions of Social Conflict (Glencoe, Ill.: The Free Press, 1956)Google Scholar, and Kriesberg, Louis, The Sociology of Social Conflicts (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1973)Google Scholar.

29 See Walton, and McKersie, , A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations, pp. 5657Google Scholar for an extended discussion of this point.

30 Robert Axelrod's investigation of a series of situations in politics confirmed his hypothesis that the greater the conflict of interest in a strategic interaction, the greater the conflictual behavior. See Axelrod, Robert. Conflict of Interest (Chicago: Markham Publishing, 1970)Google Scholar; see also Bell, Inge Powell, CORE and the Strategy of Non-Violence (New York: Random House, 1968), p. 59Google Scholar; and Deutsch, Morton and Kraus, Robert M., “The Effects of Threat Upon Interpersonal Bargaining,” Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 61 (September, 1960), 210225CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Schelling, Thomas C., The Strategy of Conflict (New York: Oxford University Press, 1960)Google Scholar.

32 Walton, “Theory of Conflict in Lateral Organizational Relations.”

33 Newcomb, T. M., “An Approach to the Study of Communicative Acts,” Psychological Review, 60 November, 1953), 393404CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Loomis, J. L., “Communication, the Development of Trust and Cooperative Behavior,” Human Relations, 12 (November, 1959), 305315CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bixenstine, V. E., Levitt, C. A., and Wilson, K. V., “Collaboration Among Six Persons in a Prisoner's Dilemma Game,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 10 (December, 1966), 488496CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hammond, K. R., Todd, F. J., Wilkins, M., and Mitchell, T. O., “Cognitive Conflict Between Persons: Application of the Lens-Model Paradigm,” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 2 (October, 1966), 343360CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

34 Lincoln, Albert A., “The New York City Transit Strike: An Explanatory Approach,” Public Policy, 16 (1967), 271292Google Scholar.

35 Pruitt, Dean G., “Stability and Sudden Change in Interpersonal and and International Affairs,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 13 (March, 1969), 1838CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36 Terhune, Kenneth, “Motives, Situation, and Interpersonal Conflict Within Prisoner's Dilemma,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 8 (March, 1968), 124CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kerr, Clark and Siegel, Abraham, “The Interindustry Propensity to Strike — An International Comparison,” Industrial Conflict, ed. Kornhauser, Arthur, Dubin, Robert, and Ross, Arthur M. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1954), pp. 189212Google Scholar; and Zinnes, Dina A., “An Analytical Study of the Balance of Power Theories,” Journal of Peace Research, 4 (1967), 270288CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

37 Berelson, Bernard and Steiner, Gary A., Human Behavior; An Inventory of Scientific Findings (New York: Harcourt, Brace, and World, 1964), pp. 619620Google Scholar.

38 Schelling, The Strategy of Conflict, and Siegel, Sidney and Fouraker, Lawrence E., Bargaining and Group Decision Making (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1960)Google Scholar.

39 Mickler, Robert Arnold, “A Study of the Effect of Impasse During Collective Bargaining on Negotiated Salaries of Teachers” (Ph.D. dissertation, Maxwell School, Syracuse University, 1972)Google Scholar.

40 Gamson, William A., Power and Discontent (Homewood, Ill.: The Dorsey Press, 1968)Google Scholar.

41 Rapoport, Anatol and Orwant, Carol, “Experimental Games: A Review,” Behavioral Science, 7 (January, 1962), 137CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.

42 Lammers, Cornelius J., “Strikes and Mutinies: A Comparative Study of Organizational Conflicts Between Rulers and Ruled,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 14 (December, 1969), 558572CrossRefGoogle Scholar. A laboratory simulation of interparty exchange during labor negotiations tested the effects of varying the level of social cues during negotiations on the outcome of bargaining. Increases in the level of social cues favorable to the union positively influenced the level of contractual change; social cues favorable to management led to a reverse outcome. See Morley, Ian R. and Stephenson, Geoffrey M., “Interpersonal and Interparty Exchange: A Laboratory Simulation of an Industrial Negotiation at the Plant Level,” British Journal of Psychology, 60 (November, 1969), 543545CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43 For an exploration of feedback processes in labor relations systems see Allen, A. Dale Jr., “A Systems View of Labor Negotiations,” Personnel Journal, 50 (February, 1971), 103114Google Scholar; and Dunlop, John T., Industrial Relations Systems (New York: Henry Holt, 1958)Google Scholar.

44 New York City, Office of the Mayor, Executive Order No. 49, March 31, 1958.

45 Horton, Raymond D., Municipal Labor Relations in New York City (New York: Praeger, 1973), p. 30Google Scholar.

46 New York City, Office of the Mayor, Executive Order No. 52, September 29, 1967. See Horton, Municipal Labor Relations in New York City for an extended discussion of the evolution of New York City's collective bargaining law.

47 New York State Sessions Laws (1967), Chapter 392.

48 These procedures are spelled out in the New York City Collective Bargaining Law, New York City, Administrative Code, chapter 54. For the establishment of the Office of Collective Bargaining, see: New York City Charter, chapter 54, section 1173.

49 Sayre, Wallace and Kaufman, Herbert, Governing New York City: Politics in the Metropolis, 2nd ed. (New York: W. W. Norton, 1965), p. 710Google Scholar.

50 Horton, , Municipal Labor Relations in New York City, p. 12Google Scholar.

52 The Office of Labor Relations was created by Mayor Lindsay in 1966. Its primary function is to represent the City government and units within its jurisdiction in collective bargaining. For an inside view of its operations see Russo, Anthony C., “Management View of the New York City Experience,” Unionization of Municipal Employees, ed. Connery, Robert H. and Farr, William V., (New York: The Academy of Political Science, Columbia University, 1971, pp. 8093Google Scholar.

53 Sayre, and Kaufman, , Governing New York City, p. 710Google Scholar.

54 Horton, , Municipal Labor Relations in New York City, pp. 7779Google Scholar.

55 New York City, Office of Collective Bargaining, Annual Reports, 1970–1971, pp. 6–7.

57 Sayre, and Kaufman, , Governing New York City, p. 709Google Scholar, characterize New York City as “imperial” among American cities.

58 On this point, compare the 1971 and 1973 versions of the following publications: U.S. Department of Labor, Labor Management Services Administration, Division of Public Employee Labor Relations, Summary of State Policy Regulations for Public Sector Labor Relations: Statutes, Attorney General's Opinions, and Selected Court Decisions (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, November, 1971 and February, 1973)Google Scholar. For a general discussion of the diffusion of similar institutional innovations, see Walker, Jack L., “The Diffusion of Innovation Among the American States,” American Political Science Review, 63 (September, 1969), 880889CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For an analysis of public employment bargaining laws see Kochan, Thomas A., “Correlates of State Public Employee Bargaining Laws,” Industrial Relations, 12 (October, 1973), 322337Google Scholar.

59 New York City, Office of Labor Relations, Collective Bargaining Settlements by the Office of Labor Relations, 1968–1972 (mimeographed).

60 New York City, Office of Collective Bargaining, Annual Report — 1972, pp. 23–24; New York State Public Employment Relations Board, Detailed Listing of Public Employee Work Stoppages, New York State, 1968–1972. (Mimeographed); Economic Development Council of New York City, New York City's Public Sector Collective Bargaining, Looking Ahead in New York City, No. 4 (New York: Economic Development Council of New York City, 1973), pp. 101103Google Scholar.

61 New York City, Office of Collective Bargaining, Annual Report — 1972; New York State Public Employment Relations Board, Detailed Listing of Public Employee Work Stoppages; and Economic Development Council of New York City, New York City's Public Sector Collective Bargaining.

62 New York City, Office of Collective Bargaining, Annual Report — 1968–1972. The bulk of information was contained in these reports. Additional information on impasses was retrieved from other unpublished documents within the Office of Collective Bargaining.

63 An appendix containing the cases analyzed, the affiliations of the employee groups, and the year in which negotiations were conducted is available upon request from the authors.

64 Communication from John T. Burnell, Director, Office of Labor Relations, March 23, 1974. The initial number of union demands was also supplied by the OLR.

65 The content of the demands would have been extremely useful for further analysis, but the lack of uniformity in maintaining these as records within organizations and the often sensitive nature of their content militated against obtaining them.

66 Hammermesh, Daniel S., “Who Wins in Wage Bargaining,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 26 (July, 1973), 11461149Google Scholar, at 1147.

68 D. S. Pugh, D. J. Hickson, C. R. Hinings, and C. Turner, “The Context of Organizational Structures.”

69 Ibid., p. 106.

70 Ibid., p. 107.

71 The number of employees in the bargaining unit was contained on the master lists used in sample selection. Most of the information on grievance arbitrations filed was obtained from internal records of the OCB.

72 New York City, Office of the Mayor, Executive Order No. 52, p. 19.

73 Derber, Milton, Chalmers, W. Ellison, and Stagner, Ross, The Local Union-Management Relationship (Urbana, Ill.: Institute of Labor and Industrial Relations, 1960)Google Scholar.

74 Dubin, Robert, “A Theory of Conflict and Power in Union-Management Relations,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 13 (July, 1960), 501508CrossRefGoogle Scholar, at 501.

76 Feierabend, Ivo K. and Feierabend, Rosalind L., “Aggressive Behaviors Within Politics, 1948–62: A Cross-National Study,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, (September, 1966), 249271CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

77 The coding scheme employed here was constructed from a contract analysis instrument originally developed by Kochan, Thomas A. and Wheeler, Hoyt N.. See Contract Analysis of Fire Fighter Labor Agreements (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Labor, Labor Management Services Administration, Division of Public Employee Relations, Contract No. L-72-157, February, 1973)Google Scholar. Some additions and modifications were made in their original instrument to reflect provisions across employee groups and categories peculiar to New York City contracts. An appendix containing the clauses which were coded and the values assigned to the clauses is available upon request from the authors.

78 These categories correspond to the frequently used empirical distinctions among wages, fringe benefits, and other terms and conditions of employment. Different terminology is used here to reflect more clearly the inclusion criteria for each category. Those provisions other than wages and salaries which either entailed a direct fiscal outlay or for which cost calculations could be made were placed in the nonsalary cost category. Items such as tuition reimbursement, uniform allowances, and meal allowances were included in this category. Among the items included in the noncost category were provisions covering contracting out, transfers, physical working conditions, and posting of vacancies.

79 Downing, Thomas G., “Strategy and Tactics at the Bargaining Table,” Personnel, 37 (January/February, 1963), 4445Google Scholar.

80 Stevens, Carl M., Strategy and Collective Bargaining Negotiations (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1963), pp. 4445Google Scholar.

81 Kochan, Thomas A., City Employee Bargaining With a Divided Management (Madison, Wis.: Industrial Relations Research Institute, 1971), p. 68Google Scholar.

82 For a discussion of some of the contextual differences between collective bargaining in the public and private sectors, see Hildebrand, George H., “The Public Sector,” Frontiers of Collective Bargaining, ed. Dunlop, John and Chamberlain, Neil (New York: Harper and Row, 1967, pp. 125154Google Scholar; Stanley, David T., Managing Local Government Under Union Pressure (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institute, 1972)Google Scholar; Harry Wellington and Ralph K. Winter, Jr., The Unions and the Cities; and Pops, Gerald M., “A Decisional Analysis of Grievance Arbitration in the Public Sector” (Ph.D. dissertation, Maxwell School, Syracuse University, 1974)Google Scholar.

Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.