Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T21:25:16.588Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Political Manipulation of Macroeconomic Policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

John T. Williams*
Affiliation:
Indiana University

Abstract

Conventional wisdom and some research indicate that macroeconomic policies follow cycles corresponding to political, as well as economic, forces. Using vector autoregression analysis, I test three models of monetary policy determination for the United States, 1953–1984: the electoral cycle model (that reelection motivations on the part of presidents create a policy cycle), the party differences model (that policy changes reflect revolving presidential party administrations), and the referendum model (that changes in presidential approval create, in effect, a continuing referendum, allowing presidents to monitor their success and change macroeconomic policies when necessary). Analysis shows that monetary policies, as measured by the monetary base and short-term interest rates, respond to the election cycle and presidential approval (although the effect on macroeconomic outcomes is ambiguous). Party differences are found in real income but are not very significant in other variables.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1990

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alesina, Alberto. 1988. “Macroeconomics and Politics.Macroeconomics Annual 3:1352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1989. “Partisan Cycles in Congressional Elections and the Macroeconomy.American Political Science Review 83:373–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Sachs, Jeffrey. 1988. “Political Parties and the Business Cycle in the United States, 1948–1984.Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20:6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Stuart. 1986. “The Federal Reserve and the Electoral Cycle.Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 18:6266.Google Scholar
Alt, James, and Chrystal, K. Alec. 1983. Political Economics. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Aranson, Peter, and Ordeshook, Peter. 1985. “Public Interest, Private Interest, and the Democratic Polity.” In The Democratic State, ed. Benjamin, Roger and Elkin, Stephan. Lawrence: Kansas University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth. 1963. Social Choice and Individual Values. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert. 1977. “Unanticipated Money Growth in the United States.American Economic Review 67:101–15.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel. 1982a. “Presidential Influence on the Federal Reserve in the 1970s.American Journal of Political Science 26:415–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel. 1982b. “Parties, Administrations, and American Macroeconomic Outcomes.American Political Science Review 76:8393.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel. 1984. “Domestic Political Sources of American Monetary Policy, 1955–1982.Journal of Politics 46:787815.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel. 1987. “Elections and the Fed: Is There a Political Monetary Cycle?American Journal of Political Science 31:194216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chappell, Henry, and Keech, William. 1983. “Welfare Consequences of a Six-Year Presidential Term Evaluated in the Context of a Model of the U.S. Economy.American Political Science Review 77:7591.Google Scholar
Chappell, Henry, and Keech, William. 1986. “Policy Motivation and Party Differences in a Dynamic Spatial Model of Party Competition.American Political Science Review 80:881900.Google Scholar
Chappell, Henry, and Keech, William. 1988a. “The Unemployment Rate Consequences of Partisan Monetary Policies.Southern Economic Journal 55:107–21.Google Scholar
Chappell, Henry, and Keech, William. 1988b. “Choice and Circumstance: The Consequences of Partisan Macroeconomic Policies.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington.Google Scholar
Chow, Gregory. 1984. Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Fama, Eugene. 1970. “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Some Empirical Work.Journal of Finance 25:159–73.Google Scholar
Freeman, John. 1983. “Granger Causality and the Time Series Analysis of Political Relationships.American Journal of Political Science 27:337–58.Google Scholar
Freeman, JohnWilliams, John T., and Lin, Tse-min. 1989. “Vector Autoregression and the Study of Politics.American Journal of Political Science 33:842–77.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno, Pommerehne, Werner, Schneider, Friedrich, and Gilbert, Guy. 1984. “Consensus and Dissension among Economists: An Empirical Inquiry.American Economic Review 74:986–94.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno, and Schneider, Friedrich. 1978a. “A Political Study of Politico-Economic Interaction in the U.S.Review of Economics and Statistics 60:174–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno, and Schneider, Friedrich. 1978b. “A Political-Economic Model for the United Kingdom.Economic Journal 88:243–53.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno, and Schneider, Friedrich. 1979. “An Economic Model with an Endogenous Government Sector.Public Choice 34:2943.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno, and Schneider, Friedrich. 1981. “Central Bank Behavior: A Positive Political Analysis.Journal of Monetary Economics 7:291315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Benjamin. 1975. Economic Stabilization Policy: Methods of Optimization. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Golden, David, and Poterba, John. 1980. “The Price of Popularity: The Political Business Cycle Reexamined.American Journal of Political Science 24:696714.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grier, Kevin. 1987. “Presidential Elections and Federal Reserve Policy: An Empirical Test.Southem Economic Journal 54:475–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grier, Kevin. 1989. “On the Existence of a Political Monetary Cycle.American Journal of Political Science 33:376–89.Google Scholar
Hatanaka, Michio. 1975. “On the Global Identification of the Dynamic Simultaneous Equation Model with Stationary Disturbances.International Economic Review 16:545–54.Google Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas. 1977. “Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy.American Political Science Review 71:1467–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas. 1987a. The American Political Economy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas. 1987b. The Political Economy of Industrial Democracies. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiewiet, D. Roderick, and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 1985. “Congressional Appropriations and the Electoral Connection.Journal of Politics 47:5982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kramer, Gerald. 1971. “Short-term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964,American Political Science Review 65:131–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Litterman, Robert. 1984. “Forecasting and Policy Analysis with Bayesian Vector Autoregression Models.Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 8:3041.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert. 1977. “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique.” In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, ed. Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert. 1981. Studies in Business-Cycle Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Maisel, Sherman. 1973. Monaging the Dollar. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Meiselman, David. 1986. “Is There a Political Monetary Cycle?Ceto Journal 6:563–80.Google Scholar
Minford, Patrick, and Peel, David. 1982. “The Political Theory of the Business Cycle.European Economic Review 17:253–70.Google Scholar
Mueller, John. 1970. “Presidential Popularity from Truman to Johnson.American Political Science Review 64:1834.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William. 1975. “The Political Business Cycle.Review of Economics and Statistics 42:169–90.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Charles, and Simon, Dennis. 1985. “Promise and Performance: A Dynamic Model of Presidential Popularity.American Political Science Review 79:334–58.Google Scholar
Riker, William. 1982. Liberalism against Populism. San Francisco: Freeman.Google Scholar
Rogoff, Kenneth, and Sibert, Anne. 1988. “Elections and Macroeconomic Policy Cycles.Review of Economic Studies 55:116.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas. 1981. “Interpreting Economic Time Series.Journal of Political Economy 89:213–43.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas. 1987. Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Shamir, Michal. 1983. “Investigating Causal Relationships.' A New Time-Series Methodology and a Political Application.Political Methodology 9:171200.Google Scholar
Sims, Christopher. 1977. “Exogeneity and Causal Ordering in Econometric Models.” In New Methods of Business Cycle Research, ed. Sims, Christopher. Minneapolis: Minneapolis Federal Reserve.Google Scholar
Sims, Christopher. 1980. “Macroeconomics and Reality.Econometrica 48:148.Google Scholar
Sims, Christopher. 1982. “Policy Analysis with Econometric Models.Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:107–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sims, Christopher. 1986a. “Are Forecasting Models Usable for Policy Analysis?Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 10:216.Google Scholar
Sims, Christopher. 1986b. Review of Specification, Estimation, and Analysis of Macroeconometric Models, by Fair, Ray. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 18:121–26.Google Scholar
Sims, Christopher. 1987. “Comment [on Runkle].Journal of Economics and Business Statistics 5:443–49.Google Scholar
Stimson, James. 1976. “Public Support for American Presidents.Public Opinion Quarterly 40:121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Theil, Henri. 1971. Principles of Econometrics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Tufte, Edward. 1978. Political Control of the Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winters, Richard F., Johnson, Cathy, Nowosadko, Paul, and Rendini, Joseph. 1981. “Political Behavior and American Public Policy: The Case of the Political Business Cycle.” In Handbook of Political Behavior vol. 5, ed. Long, Samuel. New York: Plenum.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald. 1983. “Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternative Theories.American Political Science Review 77:142–57.Google Scholar
Wold, Herman. 1938. The Analysis of Stationary Time Series. Uppsala: Almquist & Wicksell.Google Scholar
Woolley, John. 1984. Monetary Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Woolley, John. 1988. “Partisan Manipulation of the Economy: Another Look at Monetary Policy with Moving Regression.Journal of Politics 50:334–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Gavin. 1974. “The Political Economy of New Deal Spending: An Econometric Analysis.The Review of Economic and Statistics 56:3038.Google Scholar
Zellner, Arnold. 1984. Basic Issues in Econometrics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

A correction has been issued for this article:

Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.