Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T08:25:01.993Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Limited Obstruction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 September 2017

CHRISTIAN FONG*
Affiliation:
Stanford University
KEITH KREHBIEL*
Affiliation:
Stanford University
*
Christian Fong is a Ph.D. Candidate, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Knight Management Center, 655 Knight Way, Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305 ([email protected])
Keith Krehbiel is Edward B. Rust Professor of Political Science, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Knight Management Center, 655 Knight Way, Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305. ([email protected]).

Abstract

Many institutions—including American federal bureaucracies and legislatures world-wide—are characterized by one set of actors who possess the right to determine which policies will be enacted and an opposing set of actors who possess the right to delay the enactment of those policies. However, this interaction is not well understood. We provide a model that shows that a modest procedural right to delay but not veto the enactment of policies affords considerable influence over the policy agenda, so long as policymaking is time-consuming and time is scarce. In an application to the US Senate, our model exhibits properties that are consistent with common empirical claims about partisanship, polarization, and gridlock. It also justifies the considerable variation in the amount of delay imposed on the passage of various bills and the historic reluctance of the Senate to adopt reforms that would expedite the tedious cloture process.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We thank Gary Cox, Greg Koger, Nate Monroe, Sara Krehbiel, Bruce Oppenheimer, Eric Schickler, and seminar participants from the Stanford GSB Political Economy Theory Lunch, the Princeton Quantitative Social Science Colloquium, the University of Richmond Math and Computer Science Colloquium, and the George Mason University Public Choice Seminar for their helpful comments and suggestions.

References

Ainsworth, Scott, and Flathman, Marcus. 1995. “Unanimous Consent Agreements as Leadership Tools.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 20 (2): 177–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austin, Jan, ed. 2011. “Landmark Health Care Law and Late Flurry of Bills Mark Session.” CQ Almanac. Online edition. https://library.cqpress.com/cqalmanac/document.php?id=cqal10-1278-70355-2371424&type=hitlist&num=8l Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah A., Lawrence, Eric D., and Smith, Steven S.. 2002. “Tracking the Filibuster, 1917 to 1996.” American Politics Research 30 (4): 406–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binder, Sarah A., and Smith, Steven S.. 1997. Politics or Principle?: Filibustering in the United States Senate. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Black, Ryan C., Madonna, Anthony J., and Owens, Ryan J.. 2011. “Obstructing Agenda-Setting: Examining Blue Slip Behavior in the Senate.” The Forum. 9 (4): 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bücker, Joseph. 1989. “Report on the Obstruction of Parliamentary Proceedings.” Constitutional and Parliamentary Information 158: 243–64.Google Scholar
Clark, Jennifer. 2015. Minority Parties in US Legislatures: Conditions of Influence. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Matthew D.. 2007. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Matthew D.. 2011. “Managing Plenary Time: The U.S. Congress in Comparative Context.” In The Oxford Handbook of the American Congress, eds. Edwards, Lee Frances E., George, C. and Schickler, Eric. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Döring, Herbert. 1995. “Time as a Scarce Resource: Government Control of the Agenda.” In Parliaments and Majority Rule in Western Europe, ed Doring, Herbert. New York: St. Martin's Press, 223–46.Google Scholar
Green, Matthew N. 2015. Underdog Politics: The Minority Party in the U.S. House of Representatives. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heclo, Hugh. 1977. A Government of Strangers: Executive Politics in Washington. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, Benjamin, and Lewis, Garrett Darl. 2017. “Dynamic Committee Decision-Making.” Unpublished Manuscript.Google Scholar
Koger, Gregory. 2006. “Cloture Reform and Party Government in the Senate, 1918–1925.” Journal of Politics 68 (3): 708–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koger, Gregory. 2013. “Filibustering and Parties in the Modern Senate.” In Congress Reconsidered, eds. Dodd, Lawrence C. and Oppenheimer, Bruce I.. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Loomis, Burdette A. 2012. “The Senate Goes On - Changing the Slow Institution, 1960–2010.” In The U.S. Senate: from Deliberation to Dysfunction, ed. Loomis, Burdette A. Washington, DC: CQ Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mann, Thomas E., and Ornstein, Norman J.. 2016. It’s Even Worse Than It Looks: How the American Constitutional System Collided with the New Politics of Extremism. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Oppenheimer, Bruce I. 1985. “Changing Time Constraints on Congress: Historical Perspectives on the Use of Cloture.” In Congress Reconsidered. Vol. 343. Washington, DC: CQ Press Washington.Google Scholar
Overby, L. Marvin, and Bell, Lauren C.. 2004. “Rational Behavior or the Norm of Cooperation? Filibustering Among Retiring Senators.” Journal of Politics 66 (3): 906–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patty, John W. 2016. “Signaling through Obstruction.” American Journal of Political Science 60 (1): 175–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Geddes W. 1914. “Some Aspects of Parliamentary Obstruction.” The Sewanee Review 22 (2): 166–80.Google Scholar
Sinclair, Barbara. 2013. “The New World of U.S. Senators.” In Congress Reconsidered, eds. Dodd, Lawrence C. and Oppenheimer, Bruce I.. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Stephen S. 2012. “The Senate Syndrome.” In The U.S. Senate: from Deliberation to Dysfunction, ed. Smith, Stephen S.. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George, and Money, Jeannette. 1997. Bicameralism. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wawro, Gregory J., and Schickler, Eric. 2004. “Where’s the Pivot? Obstruction and Lawmaking in the Pre-cloture Senate.” American Journal of Political Science 48 (4): 758–74.Google Scholar
Wawro, Gregory J., and Schickler, Eric. 2006. Filibuster: Obstruction and Lawmaking in the U.S. Senate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wolfe, Eugene L. 2004. “Creating Democracy’s Good Losers: The Rise, Fall and Return of Parliamentary Disorder in Post-war Japan.” Government and Opposition 39 (1): 5579.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woon, Jonathan, and Anderson, Sarah. 2012. “Political Bargaining and the Timing of Congressional Appropriations.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 37 (4): 409–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Fong and Krehbiel supplementary material 1

Appendix

Download Fong and Krehbiel supplementary material 1(PDF)
PDF 203.4 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.