Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T05:29:21.742Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Investment in the Shadow of Conflict: Globalization, Capital Control, and State Repression

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 August 2019

MEHDI SHADMEHR*
Affiliation:
University of Chicago and University of Calgary
*
*Mehdi Shadmehr, Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago, and Department of Economics, University of Calgary, [email protected].

Abstract

In conflict-prone societies, the fear of expropriation that accompanies a regime change reduces capital investment. These reductions in investments, in turn, harm the economy, amplifying the likelihood of regime change. This article studies the implications of these feedback channels on the interactions between globalization, capital control, state repression, and regime change. I show that processes that facilitate capital movements (e.g., globalization, economic modernization, and technologies that reduce transportation costs) amplify the likelihood of regime change in conflict-prone societies and strengthen the elite’s demand for a strong coercive state. In particular, to limit their collective action problem and manage the political risk of regime change, capitalists support a state that imposes capital control. We identify two conflicting forces, the Boix Effect and the Marx Effect, which determine when capital control and state repression become complements (Nazi Germany) or substitutes (Latin American military regimes) in right-wing regimes.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I am grateful for comments of Dan Bernhardt, Raphael Boleslavsky, Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, Roberto Chang, Georgy Egorov, Soroush Ghazi, Alex Horenstein, Stephen Morris, David Myatt, Ronny Razin, Jesse Shapiro, Konstantin Sonin, Scott Tyson, Manuel Santos, seminar participants at 2017 APSA, 2018 EEA-ESEM, 2019 Econometric Society Winter Meeting, Princeton University, Northwestern Kellogg, University of Miami, University of Calgary, Drexel University, University of Warwick, LSE, University of Chicago Political Science, University of Chicago Harris School of Public Policy, and Indiana University Kelley School of Business. I have received excellent research assistance from Sina Ferdowsi. This research was supported by the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada and the Institute for Advanced Study at Princeton.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, Robinson, James A., and Yared, Pierre. 2008. “Income and Democracy.” The American Economic Review 98: 808–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Restrepo, Pascual. 2018a. “The Race between Machine and Man: Implications of Technology for Growth, Factor Shares and Employment.” The American Economic Review 108: 1488–542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Restrepo, Pascual. 2018b. “‘Modeling Automation.’ American Economic Association.” Papers and Proceedings . 108: 48–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2001. “A Theory of Political Transition.” The American Economic Review 91: 938–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2006a. Economic Origins of Democracy and Dictatorship. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2006b. “Economic Backwardness in Political Perspective.” American Political Science Review 100: 115–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Tabellini, Guido. 1989. “External Debt, Capital Flight and Political Risk.” Journal of International Economics 27: 199–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alfaro, Laura, Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem, and Volosovych, Vadym. 2008. “Why Doesn’t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries? An Empirical Investigation.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 90: 347–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angeletos, George-Marios, and Lian, Chen. 2016. “Incomplete Information in Macroeconomics: Accommodating Frictions in Coordination.” In Handbook of Macroeconomics. Vol. 2, eds. John B. Taylor, Harald Uhlig. Amsterdam: Elsevier 1065–240.Google Scholar
Athey, Susan. 2001. “Single Crossing Properties and the Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria in Games of Incomplete Information.” Econometrica 69: 861–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barbera, Salvador, and Jackson, Matthew O.. 2016. “A Model of Protests, Revolution, and Information.” Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartolini, Leonardo, and Drazen, Allan. 1997. “Capital-Account Liberalization as a Signal.” The American Economic Review 87: 138–54.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy, and Persson, Torsten. 2011. “The Logic of Political Violence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126: 1411–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blattman, Christopher, and Miguel, Edward. 2010. “Civil War.” Journal of Economic Literature 48: 3–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyce, James. 1993. The Philippines: The Political Economy of Growth and Impoverishment in the Marcos Era . Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan. 2010. “Regime Change and Revolutionary Entrepreneurs.” American Political Science Review 104: 446–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan. 2013. “Rebel Tactics.” Journal of Political Economy 121: 323–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burger, Martijn, Ianchovichina, Elena, and Rijkers, Bob. 2016. “Risky Business: Political Instability and Sectoral Greenfield Foreign Direct Investment in the Arab World.” The World Bank Economic Review 30: 306–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, Hans, and van Damme, Eric. 1993. “Global Games and Equilibrium Selection.” Econometrica 61: 989–1018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, Roberto. 2010. “Elections, Capital Flows, and Politico-Economic Equilibria.” The American Economic Review 100: 1759–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Heng, Lu, Yang K., and Suen, Wing. 2016. “The Power of Whispers: A Theory of Rumor, Communication and Revolution.” International Economic Review 57: 89–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Heng, and Suen, Wing. 2016. “Falling Dominoes: A Theory of Rare Events and Crisis Contagion.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 8: 1–29.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul, Hoeffler, Anke, and Pattillo, Catherine. 2001. “Flight Capital as a Portfolio Choice.” The World Bank Economic Review 15: 55–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donaldson, Dave. 2015. “The Gains from Market Integration.” Annual Review of Economics 7: 619–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edmond, Chris. 2013. “Information Manipulation, Coordination and Regime Change.” The Review of Economic Studies 80: 1422–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, Guriev, Sergei, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2009. “Why Resource-Poor Dictators Allow Freer Media: A Theory and Evidence from Panel Data.” American Political Science Review 103: 645–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2017. “Elections in Non-Democracies.” Mimeo.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. 2003. Capital Flow and Crises . Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Evans, Peter. 1979. Dependent Development: The Alliance of Multinational, State, and Local Capital in Brazil . Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, David, Morris, Stephen, and Pauzner, Ady. 2003. “Equilibrium Selection in Global Games with Strategic Complementarities.” Journal of Economic Theory 108: 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkel, Michelle, Skaperdas, Stergios, and Syropoulos, Constantinos. 2008. “Globalization and Domestic Conflict.” Journal of International Economics 76: 296–308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Laitin, David. 2004. “A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change.” American Political Science Review 98: 633–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 1994. “Protection for Sale.” The American Economic Review 84: 833–50.Google Scholar
Guimaraes, Bernardo, and Morris, Stephen. 2007. Risk and Wealth in a Model of Self-Fulfilling Currency Attacks.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54: 2205–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guriev, Sergei, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2009. “Dictators and Oligarchs: A Dynamic Theory of Contested Property Rights.” Journal of Public Economics 93: 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guriev, Sergei, and Treisman, Daniel. 2015. “How Modern Dictators Survive: An Informational Theory of the New Authoritarianism.” Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellwig, Christian. 2002. “Public Information, Private Information, and the Multiplicity of Equilibria in Coordination Games.” Journal of Economic Theory 107: 191–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlin, Samuel. 1968. Total Positivity. Vol. I. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Kennedy, David M. 1999. Freedom from Fear: The American People in Depression and War, 1929–1945. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Le, Quan Vu, and Zak, Paul J.. 2006. “Political Risk and Capital Flight.” Journal of International Money and Finance 25: 308–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipnowski, Elliot, and Sadler, Evan. 2019. “Peer-Confirming Equilibrium.” Econometrica 87 (2): 567–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, Andrew. 2012. “Elections, Fraud, and Election Monitoring in the Shadow of Revolution.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 7: 249–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loeper, Antoine, Steiner, Jakub, and Stewart, Colin. 2014. “Influential Opinion Leaders.” Economic Journal 124: 1147–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lou, Zhaotian, and Rozenas, Arturas. 2018. “Strategies of Election Rigging: Trade-Offs, Determinants, and Consequences.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 13. 1–28.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shadmehr, Mehdi. 2017. “Inspiring Regime Change.” Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 1998. “Unique Equilibrium in a Model of Self-Fulfilling Currency Attacks.” The American Economic Review 88: 587–97.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 2003. “Global Games: Theory and Application.” In Advances in Economics and Econometrics, Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress. Vol. I, eds. Dewatripont, Mathias, Hansen, Lars Peter, and Turnovsky, Stephen J.. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ndikumana, Lonce, and Boyce, James K.. 2012. Capital Flight from North African Countries. Amherst: Political Economy Research Institute, University of Massachusetts.Google Scholar
Overy, Richard. 1996. The Nazi Economic Recovery: 1932–1938, 2nd edition. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Padro i Miquel, Padro. 2007. “The Control of Politicians in Divided Societies: The Politics of Fear.” The Review of Economic Studies 74: 1259–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papaioannou, Elias. 2009. “What Drives International Financial Flows? Politics, Institutions and Other Determinants.” Journal of Development Economics 88: 269–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsa, Misagh. 2000. Sates, Ideologies, & Social Revolutions: A Comparative Study of Iran, Nicaragua, and the Philippines. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. 2009. “Democratic Capital: The Nexus of Political and Economic Change.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1: 88–126.Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the 21st Century . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schulze, Gunther G. 2000. The Political Economy of Capital Controls . New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shadmehr, Mehdi, and Bernhardt, Dan. 2011. “Collective Action with Uncertain Payoffs: Coordination, Public Signals, and Punishment Dilemmas.” American Political Science Review 105: 829–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shadmehr, Mehdi, and Bernhardt, Dan. 2015. “State Censorship.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 7: 280–307.Google Scholar
Shadmehr, Mehdi, and Bernhardt, Dan. 2019. “Vanguards in Revolution.” Games and Economic Behavior 115: 146–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shirer, William L. 1960. The Rise and Fall of the Third Reich: A History of Nazi Germany. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Tyson, Scott, and Smith, Alastair. 2018. “Dual-Layered Coordination and Political Instability: Repression, Cooptation, and the Role of Information.” The Journal of Politics 80: 44–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, Elisabeth J. 2003. Insurgent Collective Action and Civil War in El Salvador . New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Shadmehr supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Shadmehr supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 295.3 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.