Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-01T10:04:21.611Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Governance and Prison Gangs

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 October 2011

DAVID SKARBEK*
Affiliation:
Duke University
*
David Skarbek is Searle Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, Duke University, 326 Perkins Library, Box 90204, Durham, NC 27708 ([email protected]).

Abstract

How can people who lack access to effective government institutions establish property rights and facilitate exchange? The illegal narcotics trade in Los Angeles has flourished despite its inability to rely on state-based formal institutions of governance. An alternative system of governance has emerged from an unexpected source—behind bars. The Mexican Mafia prison gang can extort drug dealers on the street because they wield substantial control over inmates in the county jail system and because drug dealers anticipate future incarceration. The gang's ability to extract resources creates incentives for them to provide governance institutions that mitigate market failures among Hispanic drug-dealing street gangs, including enforcing deals, protecting property rights, and adjudicating disputes. Evidence collected from federal indictments and other legal documents related to the Mexican Mafia prison gang and numerous street gangs supports this claim.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Adolphson, Mikael, and Ramseyer, J. Mark. 2009. “The Competitive Enforcement of Property Rights in Medieval Japan: The Role of Temples and Monasteries.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 71 (3): 660–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexeev, Michael, Janeba, Eckhard, and Osborne, Stefan. 2004. “Taxation and Evasion in the Presence of Extortion by Organized Crime.” Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (3): 375–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
American Public Media. 2008. “Transcript.” Gangster Confidential. American RadioWorks.Google Scholar
Anderson, Terry L., and Hill, Peter J.. 2004. The Not So Wild Wild West: Property Rights on the Frontier. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert, Greif, Avner, and Singh, Smita. 2002. “Organizing Violence.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (5): 599628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayer, Patrick, Hjalmarsson, Randi, and Posen, David. 2009. “Building Criminal Capital Behind Bars: Peer Effects in Juvenile Corrections.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (1): 105–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bandiera, Oriana. 2003. “Land Reform, the Market for Protection, and the Origins of the Sicilian Mafia: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 19 (1): 218–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, Bruce. 1989. “The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law.” Southern Economics Journal 55 (3): 644–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Eli. 2000. “Sect, Subsidy, and Sacrifice: An Economist's View of Ultra-Orthodox Jews.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3): 905–53.Google Scholar
Berman, Eli. 2009. Radical, Religious, and Violent: The New Economics of Terrorism. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Eli, and Laitin, David. 2005. “Hard Targets: Theory and Evidence on Suicide Attacks.” NBER Working Paper No. W11740.Google Scholar
Berman, Eli, and Laitin, David. 2008. “Religion, Terrorism, and Public Goods: Testing the Club Model.” Journal of Public Economics 92: 1942–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa. 1992. “Opting out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry.” Journal of Legal Studies 21 (1): 115–57.Google Scholar
Blatchford, Chris. 2008. The Black Hand. New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1973. “A Defense of Organized Crime?” In The Economics of Crime and Punishment, ed. Simon, Rottenberg. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, 119–32.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan. 2005. “The Quality of Terror.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 515–30.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan, and Dickson, Eric. 2007. “The Propaganda of the Deed: Terrorism, Counterterrorism, and Mobilization.” American Journal of Political Science 51 (2): 364–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coyne, Christopher J. 2007. After War: The Political Economy of Exporting Democracy. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Cornes, Richard, and Sandler, Todd. 1996. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
D'Amico, Daniel J. 2010. “The Prison in Economics: Private and Public Incarceration in Ancient Greece.” Public Choice 145 (3/4): 461–82.Google Scholar
Davidson, R. Theodore. 1974. Chicano Prisoners: The Key to San Quentin. Prospect Heights, IL: Waveland.Google Scholar
Davis, Darren W., and Silver, Brian D.. 2004. “Civil Liberties v. Security: Public Opinion in the Context of the Terrorist Attacks on America.” American Journal of Political Science 48 (1): 2846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1972. “When Does the Rule of Liability Matter?” Journal of Legal Studies 1 (1): 1328.Google Scholar
Dick, Andrew R. 1995. “When Does Organized Crime Pay? A Transaction Cost Analysis.” International Review of Law and Economics 15: 2545.Google Scholar
Ellickson, Robert. 1991. Order without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Federal Bureau of Investigation. 2008. Freedom of Information and Privacy Acts Subject File: Nuestra Familia.Google Scholar
Federal Bureau of Investigation. 2009a. Freedom of Information and Privacy Acts Subject File: Mexican Mafia (File 1).Google Scholar
Federal Bureau of Investigation. 2009b. Freedom of Information and Privacy Acts Subject File: Mexican Mafia (File 2).Google Scholar
Fong, Robert S., and Buentello, Salvador. 1991. “The Detection of Prison Gang Development: An Empirical Assessment.” Federal Probation 55 (1): 6669.Google Scholar
Fuentes, Nina. 2006. The Rise and Fall of the Nuestra Familia. Jefferson, WI: Know Gangs.Google Scholar
Gambetta, Diego. 1993. The Sicilian Mafia: The Business of Private Protection. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gambetta, Diego. 2009. Codes of the Underworld: How Criminals Communicate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1989. “Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders.” Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 857–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, Herschel I. 1995. “Rival Kleptocrats: The Mafia versus the State.” In The Economics of Organised Crime, eds. Fiorentini, Gianluca and Peltzman, Sam. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 143–60.Google Scholar
Hagerdorn, John H. 1998. “Gang Violence in the Postindustrial Era.” Crime and Justice 24: 365419.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry. 1988. “Ownership of the Firm.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4 (2): 267304.Google Scholar
Hill, Peter B. 2006. The Japanese Mafia: Yakuza, Law and the State. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Loyalty, and Voice: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet, and Marks, Gary. 2003. “Unraveling the Central State, but How? Types of Multi-level Governance.” American Political Science Review 97 (2): 233–43.Google Scholar
Huddy, Leonie, Feldman, Stanley, Taber, Charles, and Lahav, Gallya. 2005. “Threat, Anxiety, and Support of Antiterrorism Policy.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 593608.Google Scholar
Hutson, H. Range, Anglin, Deirdre, Kyriacou, Demetrios N., Hart, Joel, and Spears, Kevin. 1995. “The Epidemic of Gang-related Homicides in Los Angeles County from 1979 through 1994.” Journal of the American Medical Association 274 (13): 1031–36.Google Scholar
Iannaconne, Laurence. 1992. “Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-riding in Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives.” Journal of Political Economy 100 (2): 271–91.Google Scholar
Irwin, John. 1980. Prisons in Turmoil. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Jankowski, Martin. 1991. Islands in the Street: Gangs and American Urban Society. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, Joe. 2011. “No Longer Calling the Shots.” Hanford Sentinel, 7 May.Google Scholar
Johnson v. California. 2005. 543 U.S. 499.Google Scholar
Kaminski, Marek. 2004. Games Prisoners Play: The Tragicomic Worlds of Polish Prisons. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kleiman, Mark. 2009. When Brute Force Fails: How to Have Less Crime and Less Punishment. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Landa, Janet T. 1981. “A Theory of the Ethnically Homogeneous Middleman Group: An Institutional Alternative to Contract Law.” Journal of Legal Studies 10 (2): 349–62.Google Scholar
Langan, Patrick A., and Levin, David J.. 2002. “Recidivism of Prisoners Released in 1994.” Bureau of Justice Statistics Special Report.Google Scholar
Leeson, Peter. 2007a. “An-arrgh-chy: The Law and Economics of Pirate Organization.” Journal of Political Economy 115 (6): 1049–94.Google Scholar
Leeson, Peter. 2007b. “Trading with Bandits.” Journal of Law and Economics 50 (2): 471503.Google Scholar
Leeson, Peter. 2008. “Social Distance and Self-enforcing Exchange.” Journal of Legal Studies 37 (1): 161–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, Peter. 2009. “The Laws of Lawlessness.” Journal of Legal Studies 38 (2): 471503.Google Scholar
Leeson, Peter, and Rogers, Douglass. N.d. “Organizing Crime.” Supreme Court Economic Review. Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Leeson, Peter, and Skarbek, David. 2010. “Criminal Constitutions.” Global Crime 11 (3): 279–98.Google Scholar
Leeson, Peter, and Williamson, Claudia. 2009. “Anarchy and Development: An Application of the Theory of Second Best.” Law and Development Review 2 (1): 7696.Google Scholar
Lessing, Benjamin. 2010. “The Danger of Dungeons: Gangs and Armed Groups in Prison.” In Small Arms Survey 2010, ed. Berman, Eric G.. New York: Cambridge University Press, 157–83.Google Scholar
Levitt, Steven D., and Venkatesh, Sudhir A.. 2000. “An Economic Analysis of a Drug-selling Gang's Finances.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3): 755–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Los Angeles Police Department. 2006. Citywide Gang Crime Summary, July.Google Scholar
McGuire, Martin C., and Olson, Mancur. 1996. “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force.” Journal of Economic Literature 34 (1): 7296.Google Scholar
Melde, Chris, Taylor, Terrance J., and Esbensen, Finn-Aage. 2009. “‘I Got Your Back’: An Examination of the Protective Function of Gang Membership in Adolescence.” Criminology 47 (2): 565–94.Google Scholar
Mendoza, Ramon A. 2005. Mexican Mafia: From Altar Boy to Hitman. Corona, CA: Ken Whitley.Google Scholar
Milhaupt, Curtis J., and West, Mark D.. 2000. “The Dark Side of Private Ordering: An Institutional and Empirical Analysis of Organized Crime.” University of Chicago Law Review 67 (1): 4198.Google Scholar
Miron, Jeffrey A. 1999. “Violence and U.S. Prohibitions of Drugs and Alcohol.” American Law and Economics Review 1 (1): 7114.Google Scholar
Morrill, Robert. 2005. The Mexican Mafia: The Story. Denver, CO.: Security Threat Intelligence Network Group.Google Scholar
Morales, Gabriel C. 2008. La Familia—The Family: Prison Gangs in America. San Antonio, TX: Mungia.Google Scholar
Munger, Michael. 2006. “Preference Modification vs. Incentive Manipulation as Tools of Terrorist Recruitment: The Role of Culture.” Public Choice 128: 131–46.Google Scholar
North, Douglass. 1987. “Institutions, Transaction Costs, and Economic Growth.” Economic Inquiry 25 (3): 419–28.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., Wallis, John J., and Weingast, Barry R.. 2009. Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, David, Dooley, Brendan, and Kane, Candice. 2004. “Research Bulletin: The Relationship between Gang Membership and Inmate Recidivism.” Criminal Justice Information Authority 2 (12): 112.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Political Science Review 87 (3): 567–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 2000. Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor, Walker, James, and Gardner, Roy. 1992. “Covenants With and Without a Sword: Self-governance Is Possible.” American Political Science Review 86 (2): 404–17.Google Scholar
Pape, Robert A. 2003. “The Strategic Logic of Suicide Terrorism.” American Political Science Review 97 (3): 343–61.Google Scholar
People v. Moreno. 2010. No. B215203. (Cal. Ct. App. 2nd Dist. Filed Aug. 19).Google Scholar
People v. Parraz. 2008. No. SCS187166, slip op. (Cal. Ct. App. 4th Dist. Filed Sept. 10).Google Scholar
People v. Torres. 2009. No. B204007. (Cal. Ct. App. 2nd Dist. Filed Jan. 8).Google Scholar
Benjamin, Powell, and Stringham, Edward. 2009. “Public Choice and the Economic Analysis of Anarchy: A Survey.” Public Choice 140 (3/4): 503–38.Google Scholar
Rafael, Tony. 2007. The Mexican Mafia. New York: Encounter Books.Google Scholar
Schaeffer, Emily C. 2008. “Remittances and Reputation in Hawala Money Transfer Systems: Self-enforcing Exchange on an International Scale.” Journal of Private Enterprise 24 (1): 95117.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1971. “What Is the Business of Organized Crime?” Journal of Public Law 20 (1): 7184.Google Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios. 2001. “The Political Economy of Organized Crime: Providing Protection When the State Does Not.” Economics of Governance 2 (3): 173202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios, and Syropoulos, Constantinos. 1995. “Gangs as Primitive States.” In The Economics of Organised Crime, eds. Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 6182.Google Scholar
Skarbek, David B. 2010. “Putting the ‘Con’ into Constitutions: The Economics of Prison Gangs.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 26 (2): 183211.Google Scholar
Sobel, Russell, and Osoba, Brian. 2009. “Youth Gangs as Pseudo-governments: Implications for Violent Crime.” Southern Economics Journal 75 (4): 9961018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stringham, Edward (ed.). 2007. Anarchy and the Law: The Political Economy of Choice. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.Google Scholar
Sykes, Gresham M. [1958] 2007. The Society of Captives: A Study of a Maximum Security Prison. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1985. “War Making and State Making as Organized Crime.” In Bringing the State Back In, eds. Evans, P., Rueschemeyer, D., and Skocpol, T.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Trulson, Chad R., Marquart, James W., Hemmens, Craig, and Carroll, Leo. 2008. “Racial Desegregation in Prisons.” The Prison Journal 88 (2): 270–99.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. [1974] 2005. The Social Dilemma. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
United States v. Aguirre et al. 1994. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, June.Google Scholar
United States v. Aguirre et al. 2009. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, June.Google Scholar
United States v. Alfaro et al. 2008. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, OctoberGoogle Scholar
United States v. Barajas et al. 2008. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, June.Google Scholar
United States v. Barajas et al. 2009. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, October.Google Scholar
United States v. Cavazos et al. 2008. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, February.Google Scholar
United States v. Eastside Rivas. 2010. Criminal Complaint. Federal District Court, Central District of California.Google Scholar
United States v. Fernandez et al. 2004. 388 F. 3d 1199—Court of Appeals, 9th Circuit.Google Scholar
United States v. Flores et al. 2008. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, June.Google Scholar
United States v. Henley et al. 2008. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, June.Google Scholar
United States v. Hernandez et al. 2009. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, February.Google Scholar
United States v. Ojeda et al. 2010. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, Southern Division, September.Google Scholar
United States v. Pantoja et al. 2007. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, June.Google Scholar
United States v. Shryock et al. 2003. 342 F. 3d 948—Court of Appeals, 9th Circuit.Google Scholar
United States v. Sotelo et al. 2008. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, June.Google Scholar
United States v. Vasquez et al. 2007. Indictment. Federal District Court, Central District of California, February.Google Scholar
Varese, Federico. 2005. The Russian Mafia: Private Protection in a New Market Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Varese, Federico. 2006. “How Mafias Migrate: The Case of the `Ndrangheta in Northern Italy.” Law and Society Review 40 (2): 411–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varese, Federico. 2011. Mafias on the Move: How Organized Crime Conquers New Territories. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1995. “The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-preserving Federalism and Economic Development.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11 (1): 131.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Wintrobe, Ronald. 1990. “The Tinpot and the Totalitarian: An Economic Theory of Dictatorship.” American Journal of Political Science 83 (3): 849–72.Google Scholar
Wintrobe, Ronald. 1998. The Political Economy of Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.