Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T04:39:47.449Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Challenger Entry and Voter Learning

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 May 2007

SANFORD C. GORDON
Affiliation:
New York University
GREGORY A. HUBER
Affiliation:
Yale University
DIMITRI LANDA
Affiliation:
New York University

Abstract

We develop a model of strategic interaction between voters and potential electoral challengers to sitting incumbents, in which the very fact of a costly challenge conveys relevant information to voters. Given incumbent failure in office, challenger entry is more likely, but the threat of entry by inferior challengers creates an incentive for citizens to become more politically informed. At the same time, challenges to incumbents who perform well can neutralize a voter's positive assessment of incumbent qualifications. How a voter becomes politically informed can in turn deter challengers of different levels of competence from running, depending on the electoral environment. The model permits us to sharpen our understanding of retrospective voting, the incumbency advantage, and the relationship between electoral competition and voter welfare, while pointing to new interpretations of, and future avenues for, empirical research on elections.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2007 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramowitz Alan I. 1991. “Incumbency, Campaign Spending, and the Decline of Competition in U.S. House Elections.” Journal of Politics 53 (February): 3456.Google Scholar
Akerlof George A. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (August): 488500.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere Stephen, and James Snyder. 2002. “The Incumbency Advantage in U.S. Elections.” Election Law Journal 1 (September): 31538.Google Scholar
Ashworth Scott. 2005. “Reputational Dynamics and Political Careers.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 21 (October): 44166.Google Scholar
Ashworth Scott, and Ethan Bueno de Mesquita. 2005. “Electoral Selection and the Incumbency Advantage.” Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Mimeo.
Austen-Smith David, and Timothy Feddersen. 2005. “Deliberation and Voting Rules.” In Social Choice and Strategic Decisions, ed. David Austen-Smith and John Duggan. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 269316.
Bagnoli Mark, and Ted Bergstrom. 2005. “Log-Concave Probability and its Applications.” Economic Theory 26 (August): 44569.Google Scholar
Banks Jeffrey S., and D. Roderick Kiewiet. 1989. “Explaining Patterns of Candidate Competition in Congressional Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (November): 9971015.Google Scholar
Banks Jeffrey S., and Rangarajan K. Sundaram. 1993. “Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard in a Repeated Elections Model.” In Political Economy: Institutions, Information, Competition, and Representation, ed. William A. Barnett et al. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 295312.
Besley Timothy, and Stephen Coate. 1997. “An Economic Model of Representative Democracy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (February): 85114.Google Scholar
Canon David T. 1993. “Sacrificial Lambs or Strategic Politicians?American Journal of Political Science 37 (November): 111941.Google Scholar
Cho In-Koo, and David M. Kreps. 1987. “Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (May): 179221.Google Scholar
Cox Gary W. 1987. “Electoral Equilibria Under Alternative Voting Institutions.” American Journal of Political Science 31 (February): 82108.Google Scholar
Cox Gary W., and Jonathan N. Katz. 1996. “Why Did the Incumbency Advantage in U.S. House Elections Grow?American Journal of Political Science 40 (May): 47897.Google Scholar
Ebeid Michael, and Jonathan Rodden. 2006. “Economic Geography and Economic Voting.” British Journal of Political Science 36 (July): 5274.Google Scholar
Epstein David, and Peter Zemsky. 1995. “Money Talks.” American Political Science Review 89 (June): 295308.Google Scholar
Ferejohn John. 1986. “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.” Public Choice 50 (January): 525.Google Scholar
Fiorina Morris P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Gerber Alan. 1996. “Rational Voters, Candidate Spending, and Incomplete Information: A Theoretical Analysis with Implications for Campaign Finance Reform.” Yale University Institution for Social and Policy Studies working paper 96-01.1.Google Scholar
Goodliffe Jay. 2005. “When are War Chests Informative?Provo, UT: Brigham Young University Mimeo.
Green Donald P., and Jonathan S. Krasno. 1988. “Salvation for the Spendthrift Incumbent.” American Journal of Political Science 32 (November): 884907.Google Scholar
Groseclose Tim. 2001. “A Model of Candidate Location When One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (October): 86286.Google Scholar
Hölmstrom Bengt. 1999. “Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (January): 16982.Google Scholar
Jacobson Gary. 1989. “Strategic Politicians and the Dynamics of U.S. House Elections, 1946–1986. American Political Science Review 83 (September): 77393.Google Scholar
Jacobson Gary, and Samuel Kernell. 1983. Strategy and Choice in Congressional Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Key V. O. 1966. The Responsible Electorate. New York: Vintage.
Kiewiet D. Roderick, and Langche Zeng. 1993. “An Analysis of Congressional Career Decisions, 1947–1986.” American Political Science Review 87 (December): 92841.Google Scholar
Kramer Gerald. 1971. “Short-term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964.” American Political Science Review 65 (March): 13143.Google Scholar
Krasno Jonathan S., and Donald P. Green. 1988. “Preempting Quality Challengers in House Elections.” Journal of Politics 50 (November): 92036.Google Scholar
Levitt Steven D., and Catherine D. Wolfram. 1997. “Decomposing the Sources of Incumbency Advantage in the U. S. House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 22 (February): 4560.Google Scholar
Martinelli César. 2006. “Would Rational Voters Acquire Costly Information?Journal of Economic Theory 129 (July): 22551.Google Scholar
Moore Michael K., and John R. Hibbing. 1992. “Is Serving in Congress Fun Again?American Journal of Political Science 36 (August): 82428.Google Scholar
Myerson Roger B. 1999. “Theoretical Comparisons of Electoral Systems.” European Economic Review 43 (April): 67197.Google Scholar
Osborne Martin J., and Al Slivinski. 1996. “A Model of Political Competition with Citizen-Candidates.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (February): 6596.Google Scholar
Peltzman Sam. 1987. “Economic Conditions and Gubernatorial Elections.” American Economic Review 77 (May): 293970.Google Scholar
Persson Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Rogoff Kenneth, and Anne Sibert. 1988. “Elections and Macroeconomic Policy Cycles.” Review of Economic Studies 55 (January): 116.Google Scholar
Rohde David W. 1979. “Risk-Bearing and Progressive Ambition.” American Journal of Political Science 23 (February): 126.Google Scholar
Stokes Donald. E. 1963. “Spatial Models of Party Competition.” American Political Science Review 57 (June): 36877.Google Scholar
Stone Walter J., L. Sandy Maisel, and Cherie D. Maestas. 2004. “Quality Counts.” American Journal of Political Science 48 (July): 47995.Google Scholar
Zaller John. 1998. “Politicians as Prize Fighters.” In Politicians and Party Politics, ed. John G. Geer. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 12585.
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.