Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T12:41:26.609Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Comment on Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc.: An Antitrust Analysis of Blue Shield's Reimbursement Schemes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 February 2021

Abstract

In Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., the First Circuit held that Blue Shield's reimbursement practice known as the “ban on balance billing” did not constitute an unlawful restraint of trade in violation of the antitrust laws. Underlying the First Circuit's decision was deference to what it viewed as efforts by Blue Shield and by the Commonwealth to promote cost containment.

This Comment argues that, to the contrary, under an appropriate analysis of antitrust law, the practices employed by Blue Shield did constitute unreasonable restraints of trade on the physicians' service industry in Massachusetts, given Blue Shield's market dominance in the Commonwealth. The Comment also argues that such inhibition of the competitive functioning of this industry is unwise, and that costs should instead be contained by effectuating the antitrust laws and encouraging the development of competitive forces within this industry.

Type
Notes and Comments
Copyright
Copyright © American Society of Law, Medicine and Ethics and Boston University 1985

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See Heitler, & Adler, , Blue Cross and Blue Shield Plan Contracts with Providers: Cost Containment Objectives Amid Conflicting Legislative Schemes, 2 J. LEGAL MED. 265, 266 (1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; J. K. MINTEL, INSURANCE RATE LITIGATION 6 (1983).

2 See infra notes 8-9.

3 See infra notes 24-29 and accompanying text. As of 1978, approximately two-thirds of the Blue Shield plans imposed a ban on balance billing. Skyrocketing Health Care Costs: The Role of Blue Shield, Hearings Before the Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations of the Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 95th Cong., 2d. Sess. 651 (1978) (testimony of Hon. Michael Pertchuk, Chairman, Federal Trade Commission) [hereinafter cited as 1978 hearings].

4 Other restrictions would include a Blue Shield plan which denies reimbursement for any services provided by a non-participating physician (as occurs in Massachusetts).

5 See infra notes 46-97 and accompanying text.

6 749 F.2d 922 (1st Cir. 1984).

7 As of 1983, 173.1 million people in the United States had physician expense protection type insurance. 62.8 million subscribed to Blue Shield corporations, 36.3% of the market, as compared with all other group, individual, self-insured plans, and HMOs. INSURANCE ASSOC. OF AMER., SOURCE BOOK OF HEALTH INSURANCE DATA 1984-1985 13, Table 1.4; see also Batavia, Blue CrossBlue Shield Payment Policies: Antitrust Aspects and Implications for the Health Care and Insurance Industries, 1983 F.I.C. Q. 173, \Tb\see also Kallstrom, Health Care Cost Control by Third Party Payors: Fee Schedules and the Sherman Act, 1978 DUKE L. J. 645, 649 n.14. (“The Blues collectively cover about 40% of the insured population.“).

8 “This Blue Cross-Blue Shield network is by far the largest private underwriter of health coverage in the Nation, and its impact on our health care system is very great indeed.” 1978 Hearings, supra note 3, at 5; see also Batavia, supra note 7, at 177; D. I. KASS & P. A. PAUTLER, FTC STAFF REPORT ON PHYSICIAN CONTROL OF BLUE SHIELD PLANS OF THE BUREAU OF ECONOMICS TO THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION 1-3 (1979) (not adopted formally by the FTC) [hereinafter cited as FTC Staff Report].

9 See FTC Staff Report, supra note 8, at 4-6 & Table 1; Kallstrom, supra note 7, at 651.

10 Medical service corporations are organized as nonprofit tax-exempt organizations which contract directly with providers to deliver medical services to subscribers. The physician is reimbursed directly by the insurer in accordance with a predetermined system. See, e.g., MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. chs. 176B, §§ 1, 14 and 176C, §§ 1, 14 (West 1958 & Supp. 1986); see also Kallstrom, supra note 7, at 649; Note, The American Medical Association: Power, Purpose, and Politics in Organized Medicine, 63 YALE L. J. 937, 983 (1954).CrossRefGoogle Scholar [hereinafter cited as Note, YALE L. J.]

11 See, e.g., MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B, § 14; see abo H. M. SOMERS & A. R. SOMERS, DOCTORS, PATIENTS, AND HEALTH INSURANCE 322 (1961).

12 Many of the plans “originated as creations of state medical societies in response to the hardships of the Depression … .” Batavia, supra note 7, at 178; see also H.M. SOMERS & A.R. SOMERS, supra note 11, at 318-22.

13 This in itself has generated considerable antitrust scrutiny regarding maximum fee setting by Blue Shield. “Although provider control has become attenuated, it still exists in some plans.” Kallstrom, supra note 7, at 650 and n.17. See also Lynk, , Regulatory Control of the Membership of Corporate Boards of Directors: The Blue Shield Case, 24 J. L. & ECON. 159 (1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; 1978 Hearings, supra note 3, at 5.

14 This is most aptly evidenced by the testimony of the executive vice president of the Massachusetts Medical Society before the Massachusetts House of Representatives, urging the Legislature to vote against passage of a bill which would legislatively command the ban on balance billing: “Health care costs in Massachusetts are higher than in any other state in the nation.… Why are our costs so high? Certainly not because of doctor's fees.… Massachusetts doctors charge 20 percent less than the national average… . A big chunk of [the] responsibility belongs to the giant corporation that controls almost every aspect of health care in our state — Massachusetts Blue Cross and Blue Shield.” Testimony by the Massachusetts Medical Society in opposition to H5624, An Act Relative to Medical Service Corporations before the Massachusetts Legislature (April 25, 1984) at 2 (statement by William B. Munier, M.D., Executive Vice President) [hereinafter cited as MMA Testimony].

15 See generally R. H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 92-98 (1978) (discussion of model of competitive market); T.R. MARMOR & J.B. CHRISTIANSON, HEALTH CARE POLICY: A POLITICAL ECONOMY APPROACH 29-36 (1982).

16 Under a competitive market model, consumers must have sufficient information to make rational choices in determining whether and what to purchase. In the physicians’ service market, patients do not possess this information and instead rely on the physician providers to make purchase decisions for them. While many scholars have noted that this impairs the competitive functioning in this market, some have even gone so far as to imply that because of this, we should abandon any attempt to restore competitive forces and should instead try to compensate for the problem by more tightly regulating pricing and output decisions. See generally Blumstein & Sloan, Redefining Government's Role in Health Care: Is a Dose of Competition What the Doctor Should Order?, 34 VAND. L. REV. 849, 854-59, 867-70 (1981); Boubjerg, , Competition Versus Regulation in Medical Care: An Overdrawn Dichotomy, 34 VAND. L. REV. 965 (1981)Google Scholar; Rosenblatt, , Health Care, Markets, and Democratic Values, 34 VAND. L. REV. 1067 (1981)Google Scholar; M. V. Pauly, Economic Aspects of Consumer Use in HEALTH CARE CONSUMERS, PROFESSIONALS, AND ORGANIZATIONS 56 (1981).

17 Straight indemnity insurance plans reimburse the patient up to a predetermined amount for physician services. They have no bearing, however, on physicians’ fees for those services, for there is no direct contract between the insurer and provider. See generally HEALTH INSURANCE ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA, SOURCE BOOK OF HEALTH INSURANCE DATA 1984-1985; Note, YALE L. J., supra note 10, at 983.

18 See generally]. K. MINTEL, INSURANCE RATE LITIGATION 6 (1983); Delbanco, Meyers & Segal, Paying the Physician's Fee: Blue Shield and the Reasonable Charge, 301 NEW ENC. J. MED. 1314(1979); 1978 Hearings, supra note 3, at 15,29-31,651; FTC Staff Report, supra note 8, at 4.

19 “Fifty-nine of 69 plans have participating-physician agreements, and several more have modifications of such agreements.” Delbanco, Meyers & Segal, supra note 18, at 1315; see also 1978 Hearings, supra note 3, at 651. Certain plans now include other health care providers such as chiropractors and optometrists in the definition of participating providers. See, e.g., MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B, § 1.

20 See, e.g., MASS. GEN. LAWS. ANN. ch. 176B, § 7.

21 See infra notes 27-28 and accompanying text.

22 See Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734, 740-41 (D. Mass. 1984), rev'd, 749 F.2d 922 (1984), cert, denied, 105 S.Ct. 2040 (1985); Delbanco, supra note 18, at 1316-18; Kallstrom, supra note 7, at 650; Holahan, Physician Reimbursement in NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE; CONFLICTING GOALS AND POLICY CHOICES 73, 81-83 (1980); Yett, Ernst, Der & Hay, A Model of Physician Pricing, Output, and Health Insurance Reimbursement: Findings from a Study of Two Blue Shield Plans’ Claims Data in ECONOMICS OF HEALTH CARE 197, 201-02 (1982).

23 See, e.g., MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B, § 4; Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 740; Brief for Plaintiff/Appellees, Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734 on appeal to the U.S. Ct. of Appeals for the First Circuit [hereinafter cited as Plaintiffs’ Brief) at 15.

24 Approximately two-thirds of the states have Blue Shield plans which proscribe balance billing. See 1978 Hearings, supra note 3, at 651.

25 Such is the case in Massachusetts where 74 percent of the privately insured are Blue Shield subscribers. Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 741; see also Plaintiffs’ Brief, supra note 23, at 20: [T]he effect of the ban on balance billing is to produce homogeneous prices. Patients are insulated from any concern whatsoever with the relative costs and values … ‘the price to them is zero, regardless of who they go to. So as regarding those customers, it completely eliminates any possibility of price competition.’ “ (citations omitted).

26 Plaintiffs’ Brief, supra note 23, at 16 n.15: “So far as has been determined [except for Massachusetts] only two small plans in the state of Washington refuse to cover the services of doctors who do not agree to forego balance billing. All others cover nonparticipating physicians’ services up to Blue Shield's allowable amount.” See also 1978 Hearings, supra note 3, at 30.

According to Blue Shield representatives in the three largest service areas in the state of Washington, Blue Shield typically does not cover any services provided by non-participating physicians (M.D.s) except in emergency situations. It will neither pay the non-participating physician directly for services rendered to a Blue Shield subscriber, nor reimburse the subscriber for payment made to a non-participating medical doctor. Certain large group contracts may contain provisions for such coverage, although this is the exception rather than the rule. In all three areas, it was indicated that at least 95 percent of physicians (M.D.s) were participating providers. Telephone interviews with Waultraut Lehmann, Supervisor, Product Information Department of King County Medical Blue Shield; Roger E. Armstrong, Manager, Legal Affairs, Medical Service Corporation of Eastern Washington; and Julie Pisto, Manager of Corporate Communications, Pierce County Medical Blue Shield (December 8, 1986).

Although non-coverage for services rendered by non-participating medical doctors appears to be the prevailing practice in the state of Washington, its legislature has provided for payment mechanisms if Blue Shield chooses to reimburse for such services. WASH. REV. CODE § 48.44.026, amended by 1984 Wash. Laws ch. 283, § 1, provides that:

Checks in payment for claims… for health care services provided by persons licensed or regulated under chapters … 18.71 [physicians] … where the provider is not a participant under a contract with the health care service contractor, shall be made out to both the provider and the insured, jointly, to receive endorsement by each: Provided, that payment shall be made in the single name of the insured if the insured as part of his or her claim furnishes evidence of prepayment to the health care service provider: And provided further, that nothing in this section shall preclude a health care service contractor from voluntarily issuing payment in the single name of the provider.

27 Id.

28 See infra notes 31-32, 37-40 and accompanying text.

29 See infra notes 46-48 and accompanying text.

30 MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B, § 7.

31 See supra note 26.

32 MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B, § 7; Plaintiffs’ Brief, supra note 23, at 16 n.15.

33 MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B.

34 H. 5808 enacted by the Senate and House of Representatives in General Court as Chapter 192 of the Acts of 1984, amending Section 7 of the General Laws.

35 582 F. Supp. 734 (D. Mass. 1984).

36 1979-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) II 62,480 (D. Mass. 1978), 592 F.2d 1191 (1st Cir. 1979), remanded, 384 Mass. 409, 425 N.E.2d 313 (1981), 542 F. Supp. 782 (D. Mass. 1982), 687 F.2d 543 (1st Cir. 1982), appeal dismissed, 582 F. Supp. 734 (D. Mass. 1984), rev'dinparl, affdin part, 749 F.2d 922 (1st Cir. 1984), cert, denied, 105 S. Ct. 2040 (1985).

37 See MMA Testimony, supra note 14.

38 See Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 740-41.

39 See, e. g., Kartell, 582 Supp. at 740-41: “Blue Shield payments for most services on the fee schedules has not been raised since 1952… . By 1967-68 Blue Shield payments were on the average 30% below the fees usually charged by doctors.” Under the 1977 Amended Schedule, giving Blue Shield the sole discretion to determine percentage increases and the reporting periods, Blue Shield now “bases its usual and customary payment levels on actual charges that are between 6 and 30 months old;” see also Brief of Intervenor-Plaintiffs/Cross Appellants, Grant v. Rodkey, Henry Brown, Massachusetts Medical Society, Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., on appeal to the U.S. Ct. of Appeals for the First Circuit [hereinafter cited as Intervenor-Plaintiffs’ Brief] at 10.

40 See Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 740-41, 748-53.

41 This practice was found by the Massachusetts Supreme Judicial Court to have been legislatively commanded in MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B, § 7, Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 384 Mass. 409, 425 N.E.2d 313 (1981), and by the United States District Court for the District of Massachusetts to be immunized by the state action doctrine. Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 542 F. Supp. 782 (D. Mass. 1982).

42 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 741.

43 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 739.

44 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 739.

45 Despite the fact that Massachusetts has the highest health care costs in the nation (Unpublished report - Massachusetts Medical Society testimony In Opposition to Amendment by W.B. Munier, Executive Vice President [hereinafter cited as Mass. Med. Soc. Testimony] at 2 (1984)), Massachusetts physicians’ rates have been lower than in other states. (Intervenor Plaintiffs’ Brief, supra note 39, at 11. “Massachusetts doctors charge 20% less than the national average“; Mass. Med. Soc. Testimony at 2. “Blue Shield reimbursement rates are approximately 25-30% less than physicians’ charges.” (Intervenor-Plaintiffs’ Brief, supra note 39, at 11 and 14 n.4.). As one example of this, the American Medical News reports that “[a] review of customary fee allowances for 10 selected procedures comparing the Massachusetts Blue Shield allowance and that of Northern and Southern California Blue Shield shows that Massachusetts fees are approximately 60% to 75% of the fees allowed in California.” American Medical News, April 6, 1984, at 22, col. 4.

46 This is the most generally accepted objective of the antitrust laws. ABA ANTITRUST SECTION, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 18 (2d ed. 1984) [hereinafter cited as ABA] (citing Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488 (1977)); Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962). Others have also recognized that protection of consumers and small businesses is important. United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 429 (2d Cir. 1945) (stating goal to “preserve … organization of industry in small units which can effectively compete with each other.“); Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962) (goal to protect small producers). These are but several of the many goals noted by courts and commentators. Cf. R.H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 51 (1978) “[t]he only legitimate goal of American antitrust law is the maximization of consumer welfare“; ABA ANTITRUST SECTION, MONOGRAPH NO. 2, VERTICAL RESTRICTIONS LIMITING INTRABRAND COMPETITION 77 (1977): “[T]he general economic objective is to promote free and open competition and to proscribe restraints which raise or stabilize prices, limit production, and reduce product quality to the detriment of the American consumer … . [Social purposes of the laws are recognized to include obtaining] the desired economic objective of free and open competition [by] the preservation of the freedom of economic units to act according to their own choice and discretion … [and] the preservation of a large number of small business units and the avoidance of economic concentration.” [hereinafter cited as ABA MONOGRAPH]; cf. also R.A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE 18-22 (1976).

47 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2 (1982).

48 See id.

49 “Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal.” 15 U.S.C. § 1.

50 In Standard Oil of New Jersey v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 58-60 (1911), the Court indicated that Section 1 was intended to condemn only those activities which posed an unreasonable or undue restraint of trade.

51 Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1918); see also Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734 (D. Mass. 1984).

52 246 U.S. 231 (1918).

53 Id. at 238.

54 The court stated:

To determine that question the court must ordinarily consider the facts peculiar to the business to which the restraint is applied, its condition before and after the restraint was imposed: the nature of the restraint and its effect, actual or probable. The history of the restraint, the evil believed to exist, the reason for adopting the particular remedy, the purpose or end sought to be attained, are all relevant facts. This is not because a good intention will save an otherwise objectionable regulation or the reverse; but because knowledge of intent may help the court to interpret facts and to predict consequences.

Id.

55 435 U.S. 679(1978).

56 Id. at 691.

57 Id. at 688.

58 Id. at 696.

59 Id. at 692.

60 Id. at 695.

61 See Professional Engineers, 435 U.S. at 690; ABA MONOGRAPH, supra note 46, at 17.

62 ABA MONOGRAPH, supra note 46, at 17 and n.116.

63 Id. at 18 & nn.l 19-20.

64 Id. at 22.

65 Others include tying arrangments, boycotts and refusals to deal, and division of markets. See, e.g., United States v. Topco Associates, Inc., 405 U.S. 596 (1972) (horizontal market division per se unlawful); United States v. General Motors Corp., 384 U.S. 127 (1966) (reaffirming that certain boycotts are per se unlawful); Northern Pacific Ry. Co. v. U.S., 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958) (tying arrangement per se unlawful). See generally M.J. THOMPSON, ANTITRUST AND THE HEALTH CARE PROVIDER 2-10 (1979).

66 “The aim and result of every price-fixing agreement, if effective, is the elimination of one form of competition. The power to fix prices, whether reasonably exercised or not, involves power to control the market and to fix arbitrary and unreasonable prices. The reasonable price fixed today may through economic and business changes become the unreasonable price of tomorrow. Once established, it may be maintained unchanged because of the absence of competition … .”

United States v. Trenton Potteries, Co., 273 U.S. 392,397 (1927); see also United States v. Joint Traffic Ass'n, 171 U.S. 505 (1898); United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940).

67 ABA, supra note 46, at 22-23; see also Kentucky Fried Chicken Corp. v. Diversified Packaging Corp., 549 F.2d 368, 374-75 (5th Cir. 1977); H. HALPER & J. MILES, ANTITRUST GUIDE FOR HEALTH CARE COALITIONS 99-100 (1983).

68 See R.A. POSNER & F.H. EASTERBROOK, ANTITRUST CASES, ECONOMIC NOTES, AND OTHER MATERIALS 597 (1980); Comment, The Middleman as Price Fixer: Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc. v. American Society of Composers, Authors 6? Publishers, 91 HARV. L. REV. 488, 488 (1977).CrossRefGoogle Scholar Compare P. MARCUS, ANTITRUST LAW & PRACTICE § 133 at 177 & n. 46 (1980).

69 The extent to which consumers will pay more than they otherwise would have is a function of the price elasticity of the product—that is, how much consumer demand will lessen as the price increases. See generally R.L. HEILBRONER & L.C. THUROW, UNDERSTANDING MICROECONOMICS 122-129 (6th ed. 1984); R.H. BORK, supra note 46, at 90-115; R.A. POSNER, supra note 46.

70 See R.H. BORK, supra note 46, at 57-72.

71 Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211 (1951). In Kiefer- Stewart, the Court for the first time condemned maximum resale prices imposed on a retailer. This occurred, however, in the context of a horizontal conspiracy between two manufacturers.

72 Kiefer-Stewart Co., 340 U.S. at 213: “For such agreements, no less than those to fix minimum prices, cripple the freedom of traders and thereby restrain their ability to sell in accordance with their own judgment.“

73 Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1968). Because Kiefer-Stewart occurred in the context of a horizontal conspiracy between manufacturers, it did not, however, provide direct precedent for Albrecht's holding that the per se rule applies to vertical maximum price-fixing arrangements.

74 Id. at 152-53.

75 Although no cases subsequent to Albrecht have condemned vertical maximum price-fixing under the per se rule, the Court has adhered to the per se rule regarding vertical price restraints. See Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 761, 763 (1984); Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332, 345-48 (1982); see also ABA MONOGRAPH, supra note 46, at 71-97 (1977); Note, Prepaid Prescription Drug Plans Under Antitrust Scrutiny: A Stem Challenge to Health Care Cost Containment, 75 Nw. U.L. REV. 506, 513 (1980)Google Scholar [hereinafter cited as Note, Nw. U.L. REV.].

The Court has considered the legality oinon-price restraints such as location clauses, and has determined that in this context the rule of reason is the more appropriate standard for review. Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977), overruling United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967) (Schwinn had held the perse standard applied to vertical territory restrictions). Although the Court in Sylvania held that a vertical location restriction should not be judged under aperse standard, it indicated that this did not apply to vertical price restrictions, which had long been established asperse illegal. Sylvania, 433 U.S. at 51 n.18. See ABA, supra note 46, at 19. Cf. text discussing ancillary restraints and accompanying notes 85-96.

76 ABA, supra note 46, at 23-24 & nn.167-68, 173. See also Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 761, 763 (1984) (The Court reasserted the distinction between concerted action to set prices, which requires the use of the per se rule, and concerted action on non-price restraints, which warrants use of the rule of reason).

77 ABA, supra note 46, at 57 & n.392, 64-65 & nn.443 and 444. A territorial restraint which in form only resembled resale price maintenance was evaluated under a rule of reason standard in the First Circuit. See Eastern Scientific Co. v. Wild Heerbrugg Instruments, Inc., 572 F.2d 883 (1st Cir. 1977), cert, denied, 439 U.S. 833 (1978).

78 It has been argued that the decision in Albrecht was not actually premised on applying the per se rule to vertical price fixing.

The majority [in Albrecht] found, rather unconvincingly, that Kiefer-Stewart controlled the outcome of the case. It did not characterize that decision, however, as setting forth a per se rule, but instead … concluded that the challenged price restraint, “without more,” violated the Sherman Act. Some writers have determined that Kiefer-Stewart and Albrecht should not be read to denounce maximum RPM [resale price maintenance] under the per se rule. Unlike normal per se cases, these decisions were not the culmination of a long series of rulings establishing that the challenged practice can rarely, if ever, be justified and that die usual evidentiary inquiry into purpose, power and effect would be wasteful, (citations omitted)

Kallstrom, supra note 7, at 666; see also Harrison, Price Fixing, the Professions, and Ancillary Restraints: Coping with Maricopa County, 1982 U. Ill. L. REV. 925. “[T]he per se standard seems most vulnerable to reconsideration in the area of setting maximum prices. Powerful arguments founded in price theory can be made that both vertical restraints on maximum resale prices and horizontal maximum price fixing may be in the interest of consumers and should, therefore, be reviewed on a rule of reason basis giving complete consideration to competitive impact.” (citations omitted) Id. at 926. The author nonetheless recognized that “[i]n light of the apparent inflexibility of per se rules, a statutory approach to relaxing the prohibition on maximum price fixing may be in order.” Id. at 927.

79 “Interbrand” competition is therefore increased—a desirable result, while “intrabrand” competition (which occurs within different components of a single corporation) is retarded. See Justice Harlan's dissent in Albrecht, 390 U.S. at 157-58; see also R.H. BORK, supra note 46, at 290; Blair, & Fesmire, , Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986)Google Scholar (denouncing the Albrecht rule).

Unlike the issue in Albrecht, the issue in Kartell is not the effect on intrabrand competition. In this case, Blue Shield (as well as commentators) has characterized itself as the buyer. Following Blue Shield's characterization, the buyer must then be seen as acting upon individual sellers, the contracting physicians, thereby hindering interbrand competition—an even more highly anticompetitive scenario than that posed in Albrecht. Blue Shield, having argued that it is a buyer of physicians’ services, must presumably then also be a seller of prepaid insured physicians’ services to its subscribers, and one component of the product/service it sells is the favorable selling point of assured maximum prices.

It is important to note that the imposition of fixed maximum prices by Blue Shield on physicians cannot be characterized as resale price maintenance which was at issue in Albrecht. Nonetheless, the scrutiny of resale price maintenance law is relevant. It encompasses maximum price setting in a vertical relationship, and the unique interplay between the health insurance market and the physicians’ services market may be seen to resemble such a vertical arrangement, as demonstrated above. Courts assessing health insurance schemes may refer to the law established in these cases in their attempts to properly characterize the arrangement. See Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc, 457 U.S. 332, 347 (1982) (the Court referred to Albrecht even though Maricopa's maximum price fixing scheme took place in a horizontal arrangement—recognized as consistently anticompetitive); Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 749 F.2d 922, 930 (1st Cir. 1984). But see Medical Arts Pharmacy of Stamford, Inc. v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Connecticut, Inc., 675 F.2d 502, 505-06 (2d Cir. 1982) (The court stated that the “prescription drug plan differs significantly from the vertical arrangements to restrict resale prices that were invalidated in Albrecht and Kiefer-Stewart.“). One author has commented that prepaid pharmacy insurance plans are too dissimilar from a typical resale price maintenance scheme to warrant the same judicial treatment. See Note, Nw. U.L. REV., supra note 71 at 513-14.

80 Ball Memorial Hospital, Inc. v. Mutual Hospital Insurance, Inc., 784 F.2d 1325 (7th Cir. 1986) (affirmed denial of hospital's motion to enjoin implementation of a preferred provider organization); Brillhart v. Mutual Medical Insurance, Inc., 768 F.2d 196 (7th Cir. 1985) (provider agreement between insurers and doctors not illegal vertical price fixing); Pennsylvania Dental Ass'n v. Medical Service Ass'n of Pennsylvania, 745 F.2d 248 (3d Cir. 1984), cert, denied, 105 S. Ct. 2021 (1985) (prepaid dental service not engaged in illegal price fixing or boycott of non-participating dentists); Glen Eden Hospital, Inc. v. Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Michigan, 740 F.2d 423 (6th Cir. 1984) (hospital failed to show insurer possessed and abused monopoly power); Medical Arts Pharmacy of Stamford, Inc. v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Connecticut, Inc., 675 F.2d 502 (2d Cir. 1982) (reimbursement agreements between insurer and pharmacies are not anticompetitive restraints); Feldman v. Health Care Service Corp., 562 F. Supp. 941 (N. D. 111. 1982) (insurer's prepaid prescription drug plans which included a ban on balance billing type provision not per se illegal); Quality Auto Body, Inc. v. Allstate Insurance Co., 660 F. 2d 1195 (5th Cir. 1981), cert, denied, 455 U.S. 1020 (1982) (insurance agreements restricting payment to participating shops but which did not include a ban on balance billing type arrangement not an illegal restraint); Sausalito Pharmacy, Inc. v. Blue Shield of California, 544 F. Supp. 230 (N.D. Calif. 1981), aff'd per curiam, 677 F.2d 47 (9th Cir.), cert, denied, 459 U.S. 1016 (1982) (agreements including ban on balance billing arrangement which did reimburse participating providers not illegal restraints).

81 Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1982).

82 Id. at 339-41 & n.ll.

83 Id. at 351.

84 Id. at 352., n.26, 353, n.28, & 356, n.33.

85 See Justice Harlan's dissent in Albrecht, 390 U.S. at 156-59; R.H. BORK, supra note 46, at 281-98.

86 The concept behind the doctrine was first enunciated in Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. v. United States, 175 U.S. 211 (1899), used sparingly throughout the years, and recently applied in a key case, Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979). See ABA MONOGRAPH, supra note 46, at 29-30.

87 One formulation would find a restraint lawful under the rule of reason if it “(1) is reasonably necessary to the legitimate primary purpose of the arrangement, and of no broader scope than reasonably necessary; (2) does not unreasonably affect competition in the marketplace; and (3) is not imposed by a party or parties with monopoly power.” Kallstrom, supra note 7, at 659; see also Note, Nw. U.L. REV., supra note 71, at 517.

88 See, e.g., National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984); Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979); United States v. Studiengesellschaft Kohle, 670 F.2d 1122, 1130-31 (D.C. Cir. 1981); see also AhA, supra note 46, at 30.

89 “[T]he circumstances in which the rule of reason will be applied are limited and the per se rule remains the principal mode of analysis for restraints that have the purpose or effect of limiting price competition.” ABA, supra note 46, at 30 & nn. 211 & 213. See, e.g., Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1982); Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643 (1980).

90 See Medical Arts Pharmacy of Stamford, Inc. v. Blue Cross of Connecticut, Inc., 675 F.2d 502 (2d. Cir. 1982); Sausalito Pharmacy, Inc. v. Blue Shield of California, 544 F. Supp. 230 (N. D. Cal. 1981), aff'dper curiam, 677 F.2d 47 (9th Cir. 1982), cert, denied, 459 U.S. 1016 (1982).

91 Medical Arts Pharmacy, 675 F.2d at 503; Sausalito Pharmacy, 544 F. Supp. at 232.

92 Medical Arts Pharmacy, 675 F.2d at 503; Sausalito Pharmacy, 544 F. Supp. at 232.

93 Medical Arts Pharmacy, 675 F.2d at 507; Sausalito Pharmacy, 544 F. Supp. at 241-42.

94 Subsequent challenges to similar insurance plans in districts within the 3d, 6th and 7th circuits have also been unsuccessful in proving violations of Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act. Sec, e.g., Brillhart v. Mutual Medical Insurance, Inc., 768 F.2d 196 (7th Cir. 1985); Ball Memorial Hospital, Inc. v. Mutual Hospital Insurance, Inc., 603 F. Supp. 1077 (S. D. Ind. 1985); Pennsylvania Dental Ass'n v. Medical Service Ass'n of Pennsylvania, 745 F.2d 248 (3d Cir. 1984) reh'gand reh'gen bane denied 1984; Glen Eden Hospital, Inc., v. Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Michigan, 555 F. Supp. 337 (E. D. Mich. 1983); Feldman v. Health Care Service Corp., 562 F.2d 940 (N. D. 111. 1982).

95 Sausalito Pharmacy, 544 F. Supp. at 237.

96 Id.

97 Medical Arts Pharmacy, 675 F.2d at 505-06.

98 Id. at 503, 505-06.

99 15 U.S.C. § 2 (1982).

100 Sec BLACK's LAW DICTIONARY 908 (5th ed. 1979).

101 See id.

102 SeeL. A. SULLIVAN, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW OF ANTI TRUST 21 (1977). See generally R. H. POSNER, supra note 69, at 8-22.

103 See generally R. H. POSNER, supra note 69, at 8-22.

104 See Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 272-73 (1979) (citing United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416,427 (2d Cir. 1945)); United States v. United Shoe Machinery Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295, 345 (D. Mass. 1953), aff'd. per curiam, 347 U.S. 521 (1954).

105 United States v. Grinnel Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966).

106 United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956).

107 This is only an approximation. Federal circuit courts have found 60 percent in the relevant market to constitute monopoly in two separate cases, despite the fact that the Supreme Court had held that no monopoly existed where the defendant possessed 64% of the market (in United States v. International Harvester, 274 U.S. 693 (1977)). See L.A. SULLIVAN, supra note 100, at 75-76.

108 See Grinnel, 384 U.S. at 571. See generally L.A. SULLIVAN, supra note 100, at 94-105.

109 15 U.S.C. §§ 12-27 (1982).

110 15 U.S.C. § 15 (treble damages) and 15 U.S.C. § 26 (injunctive relief).

111 E.W. KINTNER, 2 FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAW § 39.3 (1980).

112 Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v. American Crystal Sugar Co., 334 U.S. 219, 236 (1948).

113 Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 733-36 (1977).

114 See Blue Shield of Virginia v. McCready, 457 U.S. 465, 478 (1982); Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977); see also E. W. KINTNER, supra note 108, at § 39.5.

115 Brunswick, 429 U.S. at 489.

116 457 U.S. 465 (1982).

117 Id. at 484.

118 Id. at 479. ∼

119 Id.

120 Id. at 480-81 (quoting In Re Multidistrict Vehicle Air Pollution M.D.L. No. 31, 481 F.2d 122, 129 (9th Cir. 1973)).

121 459 U.S. 519 (1983).

122 Id. at 536-47.

123 Amey, Inc. v. Gulf Abstract & Title, Inc., 758 F.2d 1486, 1495 (11th Cir. 1985).

“To date, the First, Fourth, Seventh, and Tenth Circuits have not addressed the standing question in light of these two Supreme Court decisions. The Second Circuit follows Blue Shield. The Third Circuit has adhered to its policy balancing approach. The Sixth and Eighth Circuits have adopted the Associated General factors for determining standing, and the Ninth Circuit has addressed the standing question, but with no clear resolution.” Id. “The First Circuit has yet to harmonize Blue Shield and Associated General Contractors. The only treatment of those two cases has been in the context of standing to sue for injunctive relief [where the district court in Kartell applied the Associated General factors].” Id. at 1495 n.4.

In 1985, the First Circuit in CVD, Inc. v. Raytheon cited Associated General, but applied a Brunswick type standard of whether the injury flowed from the anticompetitive nature of the defendant's acts. 769 F.2d 842, 858 (1985). inKartell, it referred to the indirect standard raised in Associated General. Kartell, 749 F.2d at 933. The United States District Court for the District of Puerto Rico stated that the First Circuit uses a “target area” test, but cited neither McCready or Associated General Contractors. CIA. Petrolera Caribe, Inc. v. Avis Rental Car Corp., 576 F. Supp. 1011, 1017 (1983).

124 See supra text accompanying notes 37-45.

125 Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 1979-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) H 62,480 (D. Mass. Aug. 3, 1978).

126 Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 384 Mass. 409, 410-11, 425 N.E.2d 313, 314 (1981).

Specifically, the plaintiffs allege that a) by refusing to reimburse physicians who have not signed Participating Physician's Agreements with Blue Shield for services to subscribers, except in emergencies or for services rendered outside Massachusetts, and b) by requiring that participating physicians accept Blue Shield's reimbursement as payment in full in most cases, Blue Shield is engaged in unlawful price setting. The plaintiffs further allege that Blue Cross has conspired with Blue Shield … thereby perpetuating Blue Shield's alleged dominance in the market for physicians’ services.

See also Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734, 736 (D. Mass. 1984).

127 Brief for the Defendants-Appellees at 27, Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 749 F.2d 922 (1st Cir. 1984).

128 See Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734, 743, 745-46 (D. Mass. 1984).

129 The district court dismissed the case based on state action immunity. In 1979, the First Circuit vacated the district court judgment, finding that the question of statutory construction should be first decided by the state court. Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 592 F.2d 1191, 1195 (1st Cir. 1979). The district court was ordered to abstain pending a decision then before the Massachusetts Supreme Judicial Court (SJC) in Nelson v. Blue Shield of Mass., Inc., 377 Mass. 746, 387 N.E.2d 589 (1979). When this case was decided, the district court determined it was not on point, and certified to the SJC in essence these two questions: (1) Is Blue Shield compelled to limit reimbursement to physicians who agree to become participating providers?; (2) Is Blue Shield compelled to ban balance billing? Kartell, 384 Mass, at 410, 425 N.E.2d at 314. The SJC held that it was compelled to deny reimbursement to nonparticipating physicians, but that the ban on balance billing was not compulsory.Id. at 427,425 N.E.2d at 323. The case was then heard by the district court and decided in 1984. Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734 (D. Mass. 1984). The Court of Appeals for the First Circuit reversed in 1984. Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 749 F.2d 922 (1st Cir. 1984).

130 Kartell, 749 F.2d at 923.

131 Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734 (D. Mass. 1984), 749 F.2d 922 (1st Cir. 1984), cert, denied, 105 S. Ct. 2040 (1985).

132 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 745-46.

133 Id. at 747.

134 Id. at 746-47.

135 Id. at 747.

136 Id. at 747, 755.

137 Id. at 751-52, 755. This was proven to its satisfaction by evidence presented that several physicians had been forced to use less efficient combinations of treatment modalities due to Blue Shield's usual and customary system combined with the ban on balance billing. See Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 751-53. See generally R.A. POSNER & F.H. EASTERBROOK, ANTITRUST CASES, ECONOMIC NOTES, AND OTHER MATERIALS 501-05 (2d ed. 1981).

138 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 749.

139 Id. at 748.

140 Id. at 747-49.

141 See id.

142 Id. at 754.

143 Id. at 755.

144 Id.

145 Id.

146 Id. at 744 (citing Blue Shield of Virginia v. McCready, 475 U.S. 465 (1982)).

147 See Kartell, 749 F.2d at 932.

148 See generally R.A. POSNER AND F.H. EASTERBROOK, supra note 137, at 353.

149 See Kartell, 749 F.2d at 932-33.

150 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 744. See generally supra text accompanying footnote 116.

151 Id.

152 Id.

153 Kartell, 749 F.2d at 931.

154 Id. at 924-25.

155 Id. at 925.

156 Id. at 927-28.

157 Id. at 927.

158 Id. at 928-29.

159 Id. at 928, 931.

160 Id. at 925.

161 Id. at 925-26.

162 See id. at 929-31; Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 746-47, 751.

163 Kartell, 749 F.2d at 928.

164 Id.

165 Id.

166 Id. at 931.

167 Id. at 928.

168 See, e.g., Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 745-6; M.J. THOMPSON, supra note 65, at 25,33-35. See generally, E. Rayack, The Physicians’ Service Industry in THE STRUCTURE OF AMERICAN INDUSTRY 401-441 (W. Adams ed. 1977); P. STARR, THE SOCIAL TRANSFORMATION OF AMERICAN MEDICINE 225-32 (1982); R. ALFORD, HEALTH CARE POUTICS: IDEOLOGICAL AND INTEREST GROUP BARRIERS TO REFORM 1 (1975).

169 Kartell, 749 F.2d at 928.

170 Id. at 928, 930-31.

171 Id. at 931.

172 The First Circuit itself in 1979 stated “It is, of course, axiomatic that agreements to establish maximum prices stand no better than those to fix minimums.” Kartell, 592 F.2d at 1193 n.2.

173 Kartell, 749 F.2d at 931.

174 Id. at 930, 932.

175 Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332 (1982).

176 Kartell, 749 F.2d at 924.

177 Id. at 931.

178 See supra notes 159 & 165 and accompanying text.

179 Kartell, 749 F.2d at 931.

180 Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 749 F.2d 922,928,930-31 (1st Cir. 1984).

181 The court addressed as particularly significant three concerns: 1) the fact that this arrangement tries to keep prices low by setting a maximum, whereas the Sherman Act is concerned with high prices; 2) the cost of medical services is a complex issue with greater social impact than merely economic considerations; and 3) the price system is regulated by a state commissioner. Kartell, 749 F.2d at 930-31. These are not issues which are to be addressed in an antitrust analysis of price restraints, however. It has been noted that: “the Kartell court made a few holdings that appear to contradict what the Supreme Court said in Markopa. The Kartell court expressed an impression that the judiciary should be reluctant to be involved in health care and stated that Blue Shield's low prices constituted a consumer benefit mitigating in favor of the scheme. The Supreme Court, in Markopa, expressly rejected the argument that it should not overturn the arrangement in question because of the judiciary's inexperience in health care and did overturn maximum fees (not minimum fees), which presumably were a consumer benefit.” K. MAY, MASSACHUSETTS HEALTH LAW 144 (1985).

182 See supra notes 55-57 and accompanying text.

183 See Kartell, 749 F.2d at 927, 929.

184 See id. at 924-25. In contrast, this classification of Blue Shield as a buyer places greater emphasis on form than on substance. While it is true that Blue Shield in fact pays physicians for providing services to its subscribers, the real purchaser of physicians’ services in the market is the patient. The third-party payor's involvement developed as a mechanism for easing the buyer's financial difficulties in purchasing medical services. The third-party payor is better viewed as a financing mechanism, not a representative of the buyer. Blue Shield neither seeks or provides information to its subscribers, nor does it make purchase decisions or recommendations. Despite many courts’ classifications of insurers as buyers of physician services, the United States District Court for the District of Massachusetts would appear to more accurately address the substance of the relationship.

185 Sec supra text accompanying notes 140-41.

196 See supra notes 51-63 and accompanying text.

187 Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734, 746-47, 751 (D. Mass. 1984).

188 Id. at 751, 753.

189 See supra note 66 and accompanying text.

190 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 747.

191 Id. at 755. See also id. at 748-49.

192 See supra notes 71-78 and accompanying text.

193 See Kartell, 582 F. Supp. 748-55.

194 See supra note 72.

195 See supra notes 71-79 and accompanying text.

196 See supra note 80 and accompanying text.

197 Quality Auto Body, Inc. v. Allstate Insurance Co., 660 F.2d 1195 (7th Cir. 1981).

198 Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 384 Mass. 409, 425 N.E. 2d 313 (1981).

199 See supra notes 145-154 and accompanying text.

200 Kartell, 582 F. Supp. at 744; see also Amey, Inc. v. Gulf Abstract & Title, Inc., 758 F.2d 1486, 1495 & n.4 (11th Cir. 1985).

201 Blue Shield of Virginia v. McCready, 451 U.S. 465, 480-81 (1982).

202 Kartel, 749 F.2d at 932-33.

203 See Comment, Blue Shield's Ban on Balance Billing and the Sherman Act: Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 19 SUFFOLK U.L. REV. 1001, 1009-11 (1985).

204 See, e.g., Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332, 350 & n. 20 (1982); Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 582 F. Supp. 734, 745-46 (1984); Boubjerg, supra note 16, at 967 (citing E. KENNEDY, IN CRITICAL CONDITION: THE CRISIS IN AMERICA's HEALTH CARE (1972)); Blumstein & Sloan, supra note 16, at 855-59 (general discussion of varying views).

205 See generally F. A. ROZOVSKY, CONSENT TO TREATMENT: A PRACTICAL GUIDE (1984); A. ROSOFF, INFORMED CONSENT (1981).

206 Compare Rosenblatt, supra note 16, at 1081, who suggests that physicians would probably not price compete anyway. He argues that in small communities there may be only one hospital and few practitioners, and claims that even in more populated areas, “more or less conscious professional collusion,” will inhibit price competition. Id. However, independent practitioners no longer operate in an insulated environment. They are indeed experiencing competition as the ranks of doctors swell and as large corporations enter the industry. It is not unlikely that this provides a healthy infusion into the industry which would generate more price conscious behavior by physicians.

207 See Boubjerg, supra note 16, at 969, Rosenblatt, supra note 16, at 1070.

208 Ball Memorial Hosp., Inc. v. Mutual Hosp. Ins., 784 F.2d 1325, 1334 (7th Cir. 1986); Brillhart v. Mutual Medical Insurance, Inc., 768 F.2d 196 (7th Cir. 1985).

209 Brillhart differed horn Kartell, however, in that patients using nonparticipating providers still get reimbursed for services rendered. There also seems to be no discussion of any findings of market power held by Blue Shield, as found in Kartell.

210 Ball, 784 F.2d at 1331 (emphasis added).

211 See supra text accompanying notes 153-186.

212 See supra note 16 and accompanying text; see also Thompson, supra note 65, at 25, 33-36.

213 Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341 (1943).

214 Id. at 350-52.

215 Id.

216 California Retail Liquor Dealers Ass'n v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U.S. 97 (1980).

217 Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105.

218 See L. A. SULLIVAN, ANTITRUST 734 (1977); ABA, supra note 46, at 606-09.

219 Kartell v. Blue Shield of Massachusetts, Inc., 384 Mass. 409,423, 425 N.E.2d 313, 321 (1981).

220 Kartell, 384 Mass, at 414-15, 425 N.E.2d at 316.

221 H. 5624, An Act Relative to Medical Service Corporations, amending MASS. GEN. LAWS ANN. ch. 176B.

222 See Mass. Gen. Laws Ann. c. 176B.

223 The proposed bill, H. 5624, expressly provides that physicians shall be proscribed from balance billing.